GAO
United States Government Accountabilit
y
Office
Report to Congressional Requesters
HOME MORTGAGES
Provisions in a 2007
Mortgage Reform Bill
(H.R. 3915) Would
Strengthen Borrower
Protections, but Views
on Their Long-term
Impact Differ
July 2009
GAO-09-741
What GAO Found
United States Government Accountability Office
Why GAO Did This Study
Highlights
Accountability Integrity Reliability
Jul
y
2009
HOME MORTGAGES
Provisions in a 2007 Mortgage Reform Bill (H.R. 3915)
Would Strengthen Borrower Protections, but Views
on Their Long-term Impact Differ
Highlights of GAO-09-741, a report to
congressional requesters
GAO estimates that almost 75 percent of securitized nonprime mortgages
originated from 2000 through 2007 would not have met H.R. 3915’s safe harbor
requirements, which include, among other things, full documentation of
borrower income and assets, and a prohibition on mortgages for which the
loan principal can increase over time. The extent to which mortgages met
specific safe harbor requirements varied by origination year. For example, the
percentage of nonprime mortgages with less than full documentation rose
from 27 percent in 2000 to almost 60 percent in 2007. Consistent with the
consumer protection purpose of the bill, GAO found that certain variables
associated with the safe harbor requirements influenced the probability of a
loan entering default (i.e., 90 or more da
y
s delinquent or in foreclosure) within
24 months of origination. For example, on the basis of statistical analysis,
GAO estimates that, all other things being equal, less than full documentation
was associated with a 5 percentage point increase in the likelihood of default
for the most common type of nonprime mortgage product. GAO also found
that other variables—such as house price appreciation, borrowers’ credit
scores, and the ratio of the loan amount to the house value—were associated
with default rates.
Research on state and local anti-predatory lending laws and the perspectives
of mortgage industry stakeholders do not provide a consensus view on the
bill’s potential effects on the availability of mortgage credit. Some research
indicates that anti-predatory lending laws can have the intended result of
reducing loans with problematic features without substantially affecting credit
availability. However, it is difficult to generalize these findings to all anti-
predatory lending laws or the potential effect of the bill, in part, because of
differences in the design and coverage of these laws. Mortgage industry and
consumer group representatives with whom GAO spoke disagreed on the bill’s
potential effect on credit availability and consumer protection. For example,
mortgage industry officials generally said that the bill’s safe harbor, securitizer
liability, and other provisions would limit mortgage options and increase the
cost of credit for nonprime borrowers. In contrast, consumer groups generally
stated that these provisions needed to be strengthened to protect consumers
from predatory loan products.
H.R. 3915 (2007), a bill introduced,
but not enacted by the 110th
Congress, was intended to reform
mortgage lending practices to
prevent a recurrence of problems in
the mortgage market, particularly in
the nonprime market segment. The
bill would have set minimum
standards for all mortgages (e.g.,
reasonable ability to repay) and
created a “safe harbor” for loans
that met certain requirements.
Securitizers of safe harbor loans
would be exempt from liability
provisions, while securitizers of
non-safe harbor loans would be
subject to limited liability for loans
that violated the bill’s minimum
standards. In response to a
congressional request, this report
discusses (1) the proportions of
recent nonprime loans that likely
would have met and not met the
bill’s safe harbor requirements and
factors influencing the performance
of these loans, and (2) relevant
research and the views of mortgage
industry stakeholders concerning
the potential impact of key
provisions of the bill on the
availability of mortgage credit. To
do this work, GAO analyzed a
proprietary database of securitized
nonprime loans, reviewed studies of
state and local anti-predatory
lending laws, and met with financial
regulatory agencies and key
mortgage industry stakeholders.
What GAO Recommends
GAO makes no recommendations
in this report.
View GAO-09-741 or key components.
For more information, contact William B.
Shear at (202) 512-8678 or [email protected].
Page i GAO-09-741
Contents
Letter 1
Background 5
Most Recent Nonprime Mortgages Would Not Have Been Safe
Harbor Loans and Certain Variables Associated with the Safe
Harbor Requirements and Other Factors Influenced Defaults 17
Relevant Research and Stakeholder Perspectives Do Not Provide a
Consensus View on the Bill’s Potential Impact 35
Agency Comments and Our Evaluation 43
Appendix I Objectives, Scope, and Methodology 45
Appendix II Description of the Econometric Analysis of
Safe Harbor Requirements 50
Appendix III Comments from the National Credit Union
Administration 62
Appendix IV GAO Contact and Staff Acknowledgments 63
Tables
Table 1: Nontraditional Mortgage Products 6
Table 2: Percentage of Nonprime Mortgages That Were Safe Harbor
and Non-safe Harbor Loans by Racial, Ethnic, and Income
Groupings, 2000-2007 25
Table 3: Percentage of Nonprime Mortgages That Were Safe Harbor
and Non-Safe Harbor Loans by Credit Score Groupings,
2000-2007 26
Table 4: Estimated Probability of Nonprime Purchase Mortgages
Defaulting within 24 months of Origination with and
without Full Documentation, 2000-2006 Loans 29
Table 5: Estimated Probability of Nonprime Purchase Mortgages
Defaulting within 24 months of Origination under Different
Assumptions for the Safe Harbor Spread Requirement,
2000-2006 Loans 30
Impact of Mortgage Reform
Table 6: Estimated Percentage of Nonagency Securitized Subprime
and Alt-A Loans in the LP Database, 2001-2007 46
Table 7: Safe Harbor Requirements and LP Variables Used to
Duplicate the Requirements or Develop Proxies 47
Table 8: Variables Used in the Model 51
Table 9: Mean Values for Short-term Hybrid ARMs with DTI
Information 54
Table 10: Mean Values for Fixed-rate mortgages with DTI
Information 54
Table 11: Mean Values for Longer-term ARMs with DTI information 55
Table 12: Mean Values for Payment-option ARMs with DTI
Information 56
Table 13: Estimation Results for Short-term Hybrid ARMs with DTI
Information 58
Table 14: Estimation Results for Fixed-rate Mortgages with DTI
Information 59
Table 15: Estimation Results for Longer-term ARMs with DTI
Information 60
Table 16: Estimation Results for Payment-option ARMs with DTI
Information 61
Figures
Figure 1: H.R. 3915 Loan Standards 16
Figure 2: Estimated Proportions of Nonprime Mortgages Meeting
and Not Meeting the Safe Harbor Requirements, 2000-2007 18
Figure 3: Estimated Proportions of Nonprime Mortgages Not
Meeting Documentation and Amortization Requirements,
2000-2007 20
Figure 4: Estimated Proportions of Nonprime Mortgages Not
Meeting Interest Rate and Debt Burden Requirements,
2000-2007 22
Figure 5: Estimated Proportions of Nonprime Mortgages Not
Meeting the Fully Indexed Rate Requirement, 2000-2007 24
Figure 6: Estimated Probability of Nonprime Purchase Mortgages
Defaulting within 24 Months under Different House Price
Appreciation, Credit Score, and LTV Ratio Assumptions,
2000-2006 Loans 34
Page ii GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Abbreviations
APR annual percentage rate
ARM adjustable-rate mortgage
DTI debt-service-to-income
FHA Federal Housing Administration
FTC Federal Trade Commission
GSE government-sponsored enterprises
HMDA Home Mortgage Disclosure Act
HOEPA Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act
HPA house price appreciation
HUD Department of Housing and Urban Development
LIBOR London Interbank Offered Rate
LP LoanPerformance
LTV loan-to-value
MBS mortgage-backed securities
MSA metropolitan statistical area
NCUA National Credit Union Administration
OCC Office of the Comptroller of the Currency
OTS Office of Thrift Supervision
RESPA Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act
SEC Securities and Exchange Commission
TILA Truth in Lending Act
VA Department of Veterans Affairs
This is a work of the U.S. government and is not subject to copyright protection in the
United States. The published product may be reproduced and distributed in its entirety
without further permission from GAO. However, because this work may contain
copyrighted images or other material, permission from the copyright holder may be
necessary if you wish to reproduce this material separately.
Page iii GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Page 1 GAO-09-741
United States Government Accountability Office
Washington, DC 20548
July 31, 2009
The Honorable Barney Frank
Chairman
Committee on Financial Services
House of Representatives
The Honorable Adam H. Putnam
House of Representatives
The U.S. housing and mortgage markets are experiencing severe stress,
with over 3.2 million home mortgages 90 or more days delinquent or in the
foreclosure process in the first quarter of 2009. The rise in delinquencies
and foreclosures has been particularly acute in the nonprime segment of
the mortgage market. Nonprime mortgages, which include subprime and
Alt-A loans, grew dramatically in terms of dollar volume and share of the
mortgage market from 2001 through 2006.
1
In 2001, lenders originated
$215 billion in nonprime loans, but by 2006, had increased originations to
$1 trillion. Likewise, the share of the nonprime market as a percentage of
the total mortgage market increased from around 10 percent in 2001 to
almost 34 percent in 2006. Further, investment banks increased the volume
of nonprime loans they bundled into private label mortgage-backed
securities (MBS) over this period.
2
In 2001, they bundled 46 percent of
nonprime loans into private label MBS, but by 2006, were bundling 81
percent of these loans. The market for nonprime mortgages contracted
sharply in mid-2007, as the nation entered a credit crisis and has not
rebounded.
1
The conventional mortgage market (i.e., mortgages not insured or guaranteed by the
federal government) comprises prime loans for the most creditworthy borrowers and
nonprime loans (i.e., subprime and Alt-A loans). The subprime market generally serves
borrowers with blemished credit and features higher interest rates and fees than the prime
market. The Alt-A market generally serves borrowers whose credit histories are close to
prime, but the loans often have one or more higher-risk features, such as limited
documentation of income or assets.
2
Securitization allows lenders to sell loans from their portfolios, transferring credit risk to
investors, and use the proceeds to make more loans. Private label MBS, which are bought
and sold on the secondary market, are backed by mortgages that do not conform to
government-sponsored enterprise (GSE) purchase requirements because they are too large
or do not meet GSE underwriting criteria.
Impact of Mortgage Reform
As we reported in October 2007, an easing of underwriting standards for
nonprime mortgages and wider use of certain loan features associated
with poorer loan performance contributed to increases in mortgage
delinquencies and foreclosures.
3
These features included mortgages with
higher loan-to-value ratios (the amount of the loan divided by the value of
the home), adjustable interest rates, limited or no documentation of
borrower income or assets, and deferred payment of principal or interest.
In some cases, lenders engaged in predatory practices that resulted in
loans with onerous terms and conditions.
4
Often, borrowers could not
repay these loans and found themselves facing foreclosure or bankruptcy.
Some of these predatory practices included providing the borrower with
misleading information, manipulating the borrower through aggressive
sales tactics, or taking unfair advantage of the borrower’s lack of
information about the loan terms and their consequences.
To prevent a recurrence of problems in the mortgage market, the House of
Representatives passed the Mortgage Reform and Anti-Predatory Lending
Act of 2007 (bill) on November 15, 2007 (H.R. 3915). The Senate did not
pass companion legislation by the end of the 110th Congress, so the bill
did not become law.
5
The bill, among other things, would have set
minimum standards for mortgages requiring that consumers had a
“reasonable ability to repay” at the time the loan was made and that they
received a “net tangible benefit” from mortgage refinancings. One of the
key provisions of H.R. 3915 would have been the creation of a “safe
harbor” from potential liability for assignees and securitizers of mortgages
(i.e., entities that purchase or hold mortgages in the secondary market),
provided that the loans met certain requirements.
6
Assignees would have
3
GAO, Information on Recent Default and Foreclosure Trends for Home Mortgages and
Associated Economic and Market Developments, GAO-08-78R (Washington, D.C.: Oct. 16,
2007).
4
While there is no uniformly accepted definition of predatory lending, a number of
practices are widely acknowledged to be predatory. These include, among other things,
charging excessive fees and interest rates, lending without regard to borrowers’ ability to
repay, refinancing borrowers’ loans repeatedly over a short period of time without any
economic gain for the borrower, and committing outright fraud or deception—for example,
falsifying documents or intentionally misinforming borrowers about the terms of a loan.
5
On May 7, 2009, the House of Representatives passed the Mortgage Reform and Anti-
Predatory Lending Act of 2009 (H.R. 1728, 111th Congress), which has a similar purpose to
H.R. 3915.
6
For ease of presentation, we use the term “assignee” to mean either an assignee or a
securitizer.
Page 2 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
been subject to limited liability if they securitized loans that fell outside
the bill’s safe harbor. Language in the bill and the accompanying House
report suggests that the safe harbor and other provisions were intended to
strengthen consumer protections for nonprime mortgage products
associated with higher levels of default and foreclosure. Additionally,
congressional hearings and debate about the bill highlighted, among other
things, the challenge of designing safe harbor requirements that protect
consumers from nonprime mortgage products that put them at high risk of
default and foreclosure, while maintaining broad access to mortgage
credit.
Given the serious problems facing the mortgage market, particularly those
associated with nonprime mortgages, and congressional interest in
protecting consumers and ensuring credit availability, you asked us to
assess the potential impact of the bill were it to become law. Accordingly,
this report (1) assesses the proportion of recent nonprime loans that
would likely have met and not met the bill’s safe harbor requirements, and
how variables associated with those requirements affect loan
performance, and (2) discusses relevant research and the views of
mortgage industry stakeholders concerning the potential impact of key
provisions of the bill on the mortgage market. The scope of our analysis
was limited to nonprime mortgages.
To assess the proportions of recent nonprime loans that would likely have
met and not met H.R. 3915’s safe harbor requirements, we analyzed a
proprietary database of securitized nonprime loans from
LoanPerformance (LP).
7
This database covered about 87 percent of the
subprime and 98 percent of the Alt-A securitized mortgage originations
from January 2001 through July 2007. Nonprime mortgages that were not
securitized (i.e., mortgages that lenders held in portfolio) may have
different characteristics and performance histories than those that were
securitized. In this report, we define subprime loans as mortgages in
subprime securitization pools and Alt-A loans as mortgages in Alt-A
securitization pools. Specifically, we analyzed loans in the LP database
originated from 2000 through 2007. For each year, we estimated the
proportion of mortgages with terms and underwriting characteristics that
were consistent with the safe harbor requirements and those that were not
consistent with such requirements. When the data did not allow us to
duplicate a specific safe harbor requirement, we developed reasonable
7
LoanPerformance is a unit of First American CoreLogic, Inc.
Page 3 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
proxies. Additionally, incorporating data from the Census Bureau, we
examined the proportions of safe harbor and non-safe harbor loans within
different census tract and borrower groupings. Finally, to examine factors
that could explain the performance of nonprime loans, we developed a
statistical model to estimate the relationship between variables associated
with the safe harbor requirements and other variables and the probability
of loan default within 24 months of origination.
We assessed the reliability of the data by interviewing LP representatives
about the methods they use to collect and ensure the integrity of the
information. We also reviewed supporting documentation about the
database, including LP’s estimates of the database’s market coverage. In
addition, we conducted reasonableness checks on the data to identify any
missing, erroneous, or outlying figures. We found the data elements we
used to be sufficiently reliable.
To describe relevant research on the bill’s potential effects on the
nonprime mortgage market, we identified and reviewed empirical studies
on the effects of state and local anti-predatory lending laws on key
nonprime mortgage indicators. The indicators used in these studies
included mortgage originations and the cost of credit. We reviewed the
studies’ overall conclusions concerning the impact of the laws and
identified any limitations in the researchers’ methodologies. We also
interviewed selected authors to ensure that we interpreted their results
correctly. To obtain the views of mortgage industry participants and
stakeholders, we interviewed officials from organizations representing
mortgage lenders, mortgage brokers, securitizers, and consumer interests.
We also interviewed officials from a large mortgage lender and a major
investment bank involved in the securitization of mortgages. Finally, we
interviewed officials from the federal banking regulators, Department of
Housing and Urban Development (HUD), Federal Trade Commission
(FTC), and Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC).
We conducted this performance audit from March 2008 to July 2009, in
accordance with generally accepted government auditing standards. Those
standards require that we plan and perform the audit to obtain sufficient,
appropriate evidence to provide a reasonable basis for our findings and
conclusions based on our audit objectives. We believe that the evidence
obtained provides a reasonable basis for our findings and conclusions
based on our audit objectives. Appendix I explains our objectives, scope,
and methodology in greater detail.
Page 4 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Background
The primary mortgage market features a variety of loan products and
relies, in part, on the process of securitization to provide funds for
mortgage lending. Over the years, a number of federal and state laws and
regulations were implemented to protect mortgage borrowers. In 2007, the
bill was introduced to strengthen consumer protections and included
provisions that would have created a safe harbor for loans that met certain
requirements.
Mortgage Markets and
Securitization
The primary mortgage market has several segments and offers a range of
loan products:
The prime market serves borrowers with strong credit histories and
provides the most attractive interest rates and mortgage terms.
The Alt-A market generally serves borrowers whose credit histories are
close to prime, but the loans often have one or more higher-risk features,
such as limited documentation of income or assets.
The subprime market generally serves borrowers with blemished credit
and features higher interest rates and fees than the prime market.
Finally, the government-insured or -guaranteed market primarily serves
borrowers who may have difficulty qualifying for prime mortgages but
features interest rates competitive with prime loans in return for payment
of insurance premiums or guarantee fees. HUD’s Federal Housing
Administration (FHA) and the Department of Veterans Affairs (VA)
operate the two main federal programs that insure or guarantee
mortgages.
Across all of these market segments, two types of loans are common:
fixed-rate mortgages, which have interest rates that do not change over the
life of the loans and adjustable-rate mortgages (ARM), which have interest
rates that change periodically based on changes in a specified index. Other
more unique loan products, referred to as nontraditional mortgage
products, grew in popularity over the last decade (see table 1). Hybrid
ARMs—which are fixed for a given period and then reset to an adjustable
rate—also became popular in recent years, especially in the subprime
market. In particular, a significant portion of subprime loans originated
from 2003 through 2006 were 2/28 or 3/27 hybrid ARMs—that is, they were
fixed for the first 2 or 3 years before resetting to often much higher
interest rates and correspondingly higher mortgage payments. Other
nontraditional mortgage products included interest-only or payment-
Page 5 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
option loans, which allowed borrowers to defer repayment of principal
and possibly part of the interest for the first few years of the loan.
8
Table 1: Nontraditional Mortgage Products
Adjustable rate loans Initial period Remaining loan period
Hybrid ARMs (2/28s, 3/27s) For an initial period of usually 2 or 3 years, loan is
fixed at an introductory rate.
After the initial fixed period, the rate will eventually
adjust to a “fully indexed” interest rate equal to a
floating index, such as the London Interbank
Offered Rate (LIBOR), plus a fixed margin.
Although reaching the fully indexed rate is often a
gradual process because incremental increases
are capped, even the first increases, which
average approximately 2 percent, can cause
payment shock.
Interest-only mortgages For an initial period, typically the first 3 to 10 years,
borrowers can defer principal payments.
After the initial period, the mortgage is “recast” to
require higher monthly payments that cover
principal as well as interest and to pay off
(amortize) the outstanding balance over the
remaining term of the loan.
Payment-option mortgages For an initial period of typically 5 years or when the
loan balance reaches a specified cap, borrowers
can make minimum payments that do not cover
principal or all accrued interest, thereby, in some
cases, resulting in increased loan balances over
time (negative amortization).
After the initial period, payments are recast to
include an amount that will fully amortize the
outstanding balance over the remaining years of
the loan.
Source: GAO.
A number of loan features also became more common over the past
decade. While these features potentially expanded access to mortgage
credit, they are often associated with higher default rates. These features
included the following:
Low and no-documentation loans. Originally intended for borrowers who
had difficulty documenting income, such as the self-employed, these loans
were made with little or no verification of a borrower’s income or assets.
High loan-to-value (LTV) ratios. As homebuyers made smaller down
payments, the ratio of loan amount to home value increased.
8
GAO, Alternative Mortgage Products: Impact on Defaults Remains Unclear, but
Disclosure of Risks to Borrowers Could Be Improved, GAO-06-1021 (Washington, D.C.:
Sept. 19, 2006).
Page 6 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Prepayment penalties. Some loans contained built-in penalties for
repaying part or all of a loan in advance of the regular schedule.
Many loans were originated with a number of these features, a practice
known as risk layering.
The secondary mortgage market and the process of securitization play
important roles in providing liquidity for mortgage lending. Mortgage
lenders originate and then sell their loans to third parties, freeing up funds
to originate more loans. Securitization, in this context, is the bundling of
mortgage loans into investment products called residential MBS that are
bought and sold by investors. The secondary market consists of (1) Ginnie
Mae-guaranteed MBS, which are backed by cash flows from federally-
insured or -guaranteed mortgages; (2) government-sponsored enterprise
(GSE) MBS, which are backed by mortgages that meet the criteria for
purchase by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac; and (3) private label MBS,
which are backed by mortgages that do not conform to GSE purchase
requirements because they are too large or do not meet GSE underwriting
criteria.
9
Investment banks have traditionally bundled most subprime and
Alt-A loans into private label MBS, although since 2007, the market has
slowed dramatically.
Federal Mortgage Lending
Laws
The Truth in Lending Act (TILA), which was enacted in 1968, and the
Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act of 1994 (HOEPA), which
amended TILA in 1994, are among the primary federal laws governing
mortgage lending.
10
TILA was designed to provide consumers with
accurate information about the cost of credit. Among other things, TILA
requires lenders to disclose information about the terms of loans—
including the amount financed, the finance charge, and the annual
percentage rate (APR)—that can help borrowers understand the overall
costs of their loans. Congress enacted HOEPA to amend TILA, in response
to concerns about predatory lending. HOEPA regulates and restricts the
terms and characteristics of certain kinds of high-cost mortgage loans that
9
The GSEs Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac are private, federally chartered companies created
by Congress to, among other things, provide liquidity to home mortgage markets by
purchasing mortgage loans, thus, enabling lenders to make additional loans. To be eligible
for purchase by the GSEs, loans (and borrowers receiving the loans) must meet specified
requirements. In September 2008, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were placed into federal
government conservatorship.
10
TILA, as amended, is codified at 15 U.S.C. §§ 1601 – 1666j.
Page 7 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
exceed certain thresholds in their APRs or fees (often referred to as “rate
and fee triggers”). The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
(Federal Reserve) implements TILA and HOEPA through Regulation Z,
which was amended in 2001 and 2008 with respect to high-cost lending. As
a result of the most recent rulemaking in 2008, Regulation Z will restrict
mortgage lending in the following ways, as of October 1, 2009:
11
Higher-priced loans: First-lien loans with APRs that equal or exceed an
index of average prime offer rates by 1.5 percentage points above an index
of average prime offer rates—a category meant to include virtually all
loans in the subprime market, but generally exclude loans in the prime
market—are called “higher-priced mortgage loans.”
12
Creditors are
prohibited from making these loans without regard to the borrower’s
ability to repay from income and assets other than the home’s value, and
creditors must verify the income and assets they rely upon to determine a
borrower’s repayment ability. Also, prepayment penalties are prohibited
for these loans if the payment can change in the first 4 years of the loan;
for loans where the payment is fixed for at least the first 4 years,
prepayment penalties are limited to 2 years. In addition, creditors must
establish escrow accounts for this category of loans for property taxes and
homeowners’ insurance.
High-cost HOEPA loans: First-lien loans with APRs that exceed the yield
on Treasury securities of comparable maturity by more than 8 percentage
points or with total points and fees that exceed the greater of 8 percent of
the loan amount or $583, are called “high-cost HOEPA loans.”
13
For these
11
HOEPA imposes substantive restrictions and special pre-closing disclosures on
particularly high-cost refinancings and home equity loans secured by the borrower’s
principal dwelling. These restrictions and disclosures have been in effect since 1995. When
Congress enacted HOEPA in 1994, it authorized the Federal Reserve to adopt new or
expanded restrictions, as needed, to protect consumers from unfairness, deception, or
evasion of HOEPA in connection with mortgage loans. The Federal Reserve is also
authorized to prohibit acts or practices in connection with refinancings that are associated
with abusive lending practices or are otherwise not in the interest of the borrower. In 2008,
the Federal Reserve used this authority to put in place special protections for certain
higher-priced loans secured by the borrower’s principal dwelling, including home purchase
loans, as well as refinancing and home equity loans.
12
Second lien loans are also subject to TILA and HOEPA restrictions, but have higher rate
triggers.
13
HOEPA requires the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System to adjust this
dollar figure, initially set at $400, every year according to changes in the Consumer Price
Index. For loans made in 2009, the adjusted dollar figure is $583. 73 F.R. 46190 (Aug. 8,
2008).
Page 8 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
loans, the law restricts prepayment penalties, prohibits balloon payments
(i.e., a large balance due at maturity of the loan term) for loans with terms
of less than 5 years, prohibits negative amortization, and contains certain
other restrictions on loan terms or payments.
14
General provisions: For all loans, regardless of whether they fall into one
of the above categories, Regulation Z includes a number of basic
disclosure requirements and prohibits certain activities considered to be
unfair, deceptive, misleading, abusive, or otherwise problematic, such as
coercing a real estate appraiser to misstate a home’s value, and abusive
collection practices by loan servicers.
Each federal banking regulator is charged with enforcing TILA and
HOEPA with respect to the depository institutions it regulates, and the
FTC has responsibility for enforcing the statutes for mortgage brokers and
most financial entities other than banks, thrifts, and federal credit
unions.
15
The Federal Reserve has concurrent authority to enforce T
and HOEPA for non-bank subsidiaries of bank holding companie
ILA
s.
In addition to TILA and HOEPA, some other federal laws govern aspects of
mortgage lending. For example, the Real Estate Settlement Procedures Act
(RESPA), passed in 1974, seeks to protect consumers from unnecessarily
high charges in the settlement of residential mortgages by requiring
lenders to disclose details of the costs of settling a loan and by prohibiting
kickbacks (payments made in exchange for referring a settlement service)
and other costs. HUD has primary rule-writing authority and is responsible
14
Prepayment penalties are prohibited on high-cost HOEPA loans unless (a) the monthly
payment will not change during the first 4 years of the loan; (b) the consumer’s total
monthly debts with the mortgage do not exceed 50 percent of the consumer’s monthly
gross income, as verified by the consumer’s signed financial statement, a credit report, and
payment records for employment income; (c) the penalty is limited to 2 years; and (d) the
source of the prepayment funds is not a refinancing by the creditor or an affiliate of the
creditor. Negative amortization occurs when loan payment amounts do not cover the
interest accruing on a loan, resulting in an increasing outstanding principal balance over
time. See 15 U.S.C. § 1639(f).
15
In the context of this report, the term “federal banking regulators” refers to the Federal
Reserve, the federal supervisory agency for state-chartered banks that are members of the
Federal Reserve System; Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, which supervises
national banks and their subsidiaries; Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, the federal
regulator responsible for insured state-chartered banks that are not members of the
Federal Reserve System; Office of Thrift Supervision, the primary federal supervisory
agency for federally insured thrifts and their subsidiaries; and National Credit Union
Administration (NCUA), which supervises federally insured credit unions.
Page 9 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
for enforcing RESPA. HUD coordinates on RESPA issues, as it deems
appropriate, with federal banking regulators and other federal agencies,
such as the FTC and the Department of Justice. In addition, the federal
banking agencies, under section 8 of the Federal Deposit Insurance Act,
examine for and enforce compliance with RESPA’s requirements with
respect to the institutions they supervise.
16
Finally, the Federal Deposit
Insurance Act and Federal Credit Union Act allow federal banking
regulators to use their supervisory and enforcement authorities to ensure
that an institution’s conduct with respect to consumer protection laws
does not affect its safety and soundness or that of an affiliated institution.
17
Banking Regulator
Guidance
In conjunction with enforcing federal statutes, federal banking regulators
have issued guidance to their institutions—including federally-regulated
banks, thrifts, credit unions, holding companies and their subsidiaries—
about nontraditional and subprime lending.
In September 2006, banking regulators issued final guidance clarifying
how institutions can offer nontraditional mortgage products in a safe and
sound manner, and in a way that clearly discloses the risks that borrowers
may assume. The guidance provides specific steps institutions should take
to help ensure that loan terms and underwriting standards are consistent
with prudent lending practices, including considering a borrower’s
repayment capacity; ensuring strong risk management standards,
including capital levels; and ensuring that consumers have sufficient
information to clearly understand loan terms and associated risks.
18
In June 2007, banking regulators issued a final statement on subprime
lending, in response to concerns about certain types of loans that could
result in payment shock to borrowers. The statement warned institutions
about risks associated with subprime loans with adjustable rates with low
16
See 24 C.F.R. § 3500.19(a), “It is the policy of the [HUD] Secretary regarding RESPA
enforcement matters to cooperate with Federal, State, or local agencies having supervisory
powers over lenders or other persons with responsibilities under RESPA. Federal agencies
with supervisory powers over lenders may use their powers to require compliance with
RESPA.”
17
For more information on federal laws and statutes related to mortgage lending, see GAO,
Consumer Protection: Federal and State Agencies Face Challenges in Combating
Predatory Lending, GAO-04-280 (Washington, D.C.: Jan. 30, 2004).
18
71 Fed. Reg. 58609 “Interagency Guidance on Nontraditional Mortgage Product Risks,”
(Oct. 4, 2006).
Page 10 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
initial payments, based on fixed introductory rates that expire after a short
period, limited or no documentation of income, prepayment penalties that
were very high or that extended beyond the initial fixed rate period, and
other product features likely to result in frequent refinancing to maintain
an affordable monthly payment.
19
State Mortgage Lending
Laws
In response to concerns about the growth of predatory lending over the
past decade, many states have enacted laws to restrict the terms or
provisions of certain types of mortgage loans. According to the
Congressional Research Service, at least 30 states and the District of
Columbia had enacted a wide array of such laws, as of November 2008.
20
Many of these state laws are similar to HOEPA in that they regulate and
restrict the terms and characteristics of certain kinds of high-cost
mortgages exceeding certain interest rate or fee thresholds that require
enhanced protections. Like HOEPA, these laws often restrict certain loan
features that can, in certain cases, be abusive—such as prepayment
penalties, balloon payments, negative amortization, and loan flipping—and
many laws also require enhanced disclosures and credit counseling. While
some laws are only minimally different than HOEPA, others are more
comprehensive.
Significant debate has taken place as to the advantages and disadvantages
of state predatory lending laws. In several cases, regulators of federally
supervised financial institutions have determined that federal laws
preempt state predatory lending laws for the institutions they regulate. In
making these determinations, two regulators—the Office of the
Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) and Office of Thrift Supervision
(OTS)—have cited federal law that provides for uniform regulation of
federally chartered institutions and have noted the potential harm that
state predatory lending laws can do to legitimate lending. Many state
officials and consumer advocates are opposed to federal preemption of
state predatory lending laws.
21
They maintain that federal laws related to
19
72 Fed. Reg. 37569 “Statement on Subprime Mortgage Lending,” (Jul. 10, 2007). Banking
regulators have issued other guidance on subprime lending, including Interagency
Guidance on Subprime Lending, Mar. 1, 1999; and Expanded Guidance for Subprime
Lending Programs, Jan. 31, 2001.
20
Congressional Research Service, A Predatory Lending Primer: The Homeownership and
Equity Protection Act (HOEPA), RL34259 (Washington, D.C.: Nov. 2008).
21
A recent Supreme Court case (Cuomo v. The Clearing House Association) allows states to
bring lawsuits against national banks to enforce state fair lending and consumer protection
laws.
Page 11 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
predatory lending are insufficient, and that preemption, therefore,
interferes with their ability to protect consumers in their states.
22
The first state predatory lending law, the North Carolina Anti-Predatory
Lending Law of 1999, has been the subject of particular attention by
researchers and policymakers. The law was more restrictive than HOEPA
was at the time. Among other things, it banned prepayment penalties on all
home loans with a principal amount of $150,000 or less, and prohibited
loan flipping (refinancings of consumer home loans that do not provide a
reasonable, net tangible benefit to the borrower). It included more
restrictions for a category of high-cost loans, which were defined to
include lower points and fee triggers than HOEPA, as well as a third
trigger that included any loan with a prepayment penalty that could be
collected more than 30 months after closing or that was greater than 2
percent of the amount paid.
H.R. 3915
The U.S. House of Representatives passed H.R. 3915—the Mortgage
Reform and Anti-Predatory Lending Act of 2007—on November 15, 2007,
in response to significant increases in mortgage defaults and foreclosures,
especially among subprime borrowers.
23
Although the bill was passed by
the U.S. House of Representatives, it was not enacted into law before the
end of the 110th Congress. The bill would have reformed mortgage lending
by, among other things, setting minimum standards for residential
mortgage loans (see fig. 1). The two standards included:
Reasonable ability to repay. The bill would have created a “reasonable
ability to repay” standard by prohibiting a creditor from making a
residential mortgage loan without making a determination based on
verified and documented information that a consumer was likely to be
able to repay the loan, including all applicable taxes, insurance, and
assessments. Such a determination was to be based on the consumer’s
credit history, current and expected income, obligations, debt-service-to-
22
For more information about preemption, see GAO-04-280; GAO, OCC Preemption
Rulemaking: Opportunities Existed to Enhance the Consultative Efforts and Better
Document the Rulemaking Process, GAO-06-8 (Washington, D.C.: Oct. 17, 2005); and GAO,
OCC Preemption Rules: OCC Should Further Clarify the Applicability of State Consumer
Protection Laws to National Banks, GAO-06-387 (Washington, D.C.: Apr. 28, 2006).
23
H.R. 3915 was one of several bills introduced during the 110th Congress to address
concerns about rising foreclosures and abusive lending practices. See also S. 2452, 110th
Congress (2007), Home Ownership Preservation and Protection Act of 2007.
Page 12 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
income (DTI) ratio, employment status, and financial resources other than
any equity in the real property securing the loan. Additionally, the bill
would have required lenders making ARMs to qualify borrowers at the
fully indexed rate. However, the actual standard was to be prescribed in
regulation by the federal banking agencies, in consultation with the FTC.
Net tangible benefit. The bill would have created a “net tangible benefit”
standard by prohibiting a creditor from refinancing a loan without making
a reasonable good faith determination that the loan would provide a net
tangible benefit to the consumer. The bill stated that a loan would not
meet the standard if the loan’s costs exceeded the amount of newly
advanced principal, without any corresponding changes in the terms of the
refinanced loan that were advantageous to the consumer. However, the
term “net tangible benefit” was to be defined in regulation by the federal
banking agencies.
The specific responsibilities of lenders to meet the standards, and the
rights of consumers to take action against lenders to claim standards had
not been met, depended on the category of the loan. Under the bill, loans
are classified into three basic categories:
Qualified mortgages would have had relatively low APRs, be insured by
FHA, or made or guaranteed by VA. This category was intended to include
most prime loans. Specifically, a loan would have been considered a
qualified loan if either the APR was less than 3 percent above the yield on
comparable Treasury securities, or less than 1.75 percent above the most
recent conventional mortgage rate (a term that would have been more
explicitly defined in regulation). For second-lien loans, the limits were 5
and 3.75 percent, respectively. Qualified mortgages would have been
presumed under the law to meet the “ability to repay” and “net tangible
benefit” standards, and for these loans, the creditor’s presumption could
not be rebutted by borrowers.
Qualified safe harbor mortgages would have fallen outside of the
definition of qualified mortgages (i.e., would not have met this standard),
but would have met certain underwriting requirements. This category was
intended to include subprime loans that did not contain certain high-risk
features. Specifically, these mortgages were required to (1) have full
documentation, (2) be underwritten to the fully indexed rate, (3) not
negatively amortize, and (4) have a fixed rate for at least 5 years, have a
variable rate with an APR less than 3 percentage points over a generally
accepted interest rate index, or meet a DTI ratio to be established in
Page 13 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
regulation.
24
Qualified safe harbor mortgages, like qualified mortgages,
would have been presumed under the law to meet the “ability to repay”
and “net tangible benefit” standards. Unlike borrowers with qualified
mortgages, however, borrowers with these mortgages would have had the
right to challenge a creditor’s presumption that these loans met the “ability
to repay” and “net tangible benefit” standards.
Nonqualified mortgages would have fallen outside of the two definitions
above (i.e., would not have met either standard). This category was
intended to include subprime loans with high-risk features. For these
loans, the law would have required lenders to meet the reasonable ability
to repay and net tangible benefit standards, as well as provide borrowers
with the ability to challenge such determinations by creditors and
assignees.
As shown in figure 1, the bill would also have imposed restrictions on
specific loan terms, depending on the loan category. First, the bill would
have prohibited prepayment penalties for loans that were not qualified
mortgages and would have required the penalties on all qualified
mortgages with an adjustable interest rate to expire 3 months before the
initial interest rate adjustment. Second, negative amortization loans to
first-time borrowers would have been prohibited, unless the creditor made
certain disclosures to the consumer and the consumer had received
homeownership counseling from a HUD-certified organization or
counselor. Finally, single-premium credit insurance and mandatory
arbitration on mortgage loans would have been prohibited for all loans.
25
The bill would have established additional liability for creditors of
qualified safe harbor and nonqualified mortgages (see fig. 1).
26
In addition,
24
The bill provided the federal banking agencies the authority to jointly prescribe
regulations to revise, add to, or subtract from these safe harbor provisions to the extent
necessary and appropriate to meet the purposes intended in the law, to prevent
circumvention or evasion of the provisions, or to facilitate compliance with the provisions.
25
Credit insurance is a loan product that repays the lender should the borrower die or
become disabled. In the case of single-premium credit insurance, the full premium is paid
all at once—by being added to the amount financed in the loan—rather than on a monthly
basis. Because adding the full premium to the amount of the loan unnecessarily raises the
amount of interest borrowers pay, single-premium credit insurance is generally considered
inherently abusive.
26
Under the terms of the bill, the liability of rescission faced by creditors would have been
“[i]n addition to any other liability” under TILA for violating the minimum standards. H.R.
3915, § 204. Those additional liabilities include individual and class action damages. See 12
U.S.C. §1640.
Page 14 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
it would have established limited liability for assignees of nonqualified
mortgages. Borrowers would have been able to bring civil actions against
creditors or assignees if loans violated the “reasonable ability to repay” or
“net tangible benefit” standards. Creditors would have been liable for the
rescission of a loan and the borrower’s cost associated with the rescission
unless they could make the loan conform to minimum standards within 90
days. In addition, assignees would have been liable for the rescission (i.e.,
cancellation) of a loan and for borrower costs associated with the
rescission unless the loan could be made to conform to the minimum
standards within 90 days, or unless the assignee (1) had a policy against
buying loans that were not qualified loans or qualified safe harbor loans,
(2) exercised reasonable due diligence, as defined in regulation by the
federal banking agencies and the SEC, and (3) had agreements with the
seller or assignees of loans requiring that certain standards be met and
certain steps be taken. The bill included additional provisions to resolve
situations in which the parties could not agree on loan changes and set
certain time frames for addressing challenges to these changes. Liability
would not have been extended to pools of loans, including the
securitization vehicles, or investors in pools of loans. According to the
House Committee Report on the bill, it was not intended to apply to
trustees or titleholders who held loans solely for the benefit of the
securitization vehicle.
27
27
Committee Report, 110th Congress, 1st Session, Report 110-441.
Page 15 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Figure 1: H.R. 3915 Loan Standards
APR requirements
and underwriting
standards
Qualified mortgages
Loan categories
Qualified safe harbor mortgages Nonqualified mortgages
Loan terms
and
standards
Liability for
creditors
Liability for
assignees and
securitizers
Presumed to meet minimum lending standards (i.e., reasonable ability to repay and net tangible benefit)
• APR less than three percent above yield on
comparable Treasury securities or less
than 1.75 percent above most recent
conventional mortgage rate (to be defined
in regulation)
Second lien (subordinate loan): APR less
than 5 percent above yield on
comparable Treasury securities or 3.75
percent above most recent conventional
mortgage rate (to be defined in regulation)
• Loan is insured by FHA
• Loan is made or guaranteed by V
A
• Limits on prepayment penalities for first
3 years
• No prepayment penalties after initial fixed
term expires on hybrid-ARM
• No liability for creditors
• No liability for assignees and securitizers
• Potential liability for rescission or cure of
loans (presumption of having met minimum
lending standards is rebuttable if borro
wer
can prove a violation of the miniumum
lending criteria)
a
• Potential liability for rescission or cure of
loans if borrower can prove loan violation
of minimum lending standards
a
• Prohibits prepayment penalties
• Prohibits single premium credit insurance from being financed
• Prohibits requirement of arbitration
Do not meet standards established for
qualified mortgages or qualified safe
harbor mortgages
Mortgages must meet all four underwriting
standards:
(1) Full documentation
(2) No negative amortization
(3) Underwritten to the fully indexed rate
(4) Have ONE of the following features:
-
fixed interest rate for at least 5 years, or
- variable rate mortgage where the
APR has a margin less than 3 percent
over a generally-accepted interest
rate index, or
- meet a DTI ratio to
be established in regulation
Source: GAO.
a
Liability of creditors for rescission would be in addition to other liabilities (e.g., damages) that
currently exist in TILA.
The bill would also have expanded the definition of “high-cost” loans
under HOEPA. Specifically, the bill would have included home purchase
loans in the definition, reduced the points and fees trigger from 8 to 5
percent—the APR trigger would stay at 8—and expanded the definition of
points and fees for high-cost mortgages. The bill would have also added a
third high-cost trigger for loans with prepayment penalties that applied for
more than 3 years or exceeded 2 percent of the prepaid amount. Further,
Page 16 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
the bill would have enhanced existing HOEPA restrictions on lending
without repayment ability by presuming that creditors engaged in a
pattern or practice of making high-cost mortgages without verifying or
documenting consumers’ repayment ability were violating HOEPA.
Finally, the bill would have established a federal duty of care for mortgage
originators; prohibited steering of consumers eligible for qualified
mortgages to nonqualified mortgages; established a licensing and
registration regime for loan originators; established an Office of Housing
Counseling within HUD and imposed additional counseling requirements;
made changes to mortgage servicing and appraisal requirements; and
provided protections for renters in foreclosed properties.
We estimate that almost three-quarters of securitized nonprime mortgages
originated from 2000 through 2007 would not have been safe harbor loans.
The extent to which mortgages would have met the individual safe harbor
requirements varied substantially by origination year, reflecting changes in
market conditions and lending practices over the 8-year period. We also
found that the proportions of safe harbor and non-safe harbor loans varied
across different census tract and borrower groupings. Our statistical
analysis of loan data shows that certain variables associated with the safe
harbor requirements—documentation of borrower income and assets, in
particular—were associated with the probability of a loan default. We
found that other variables, such as house price appreciation and borrower
credit score, were also associated with default rates.
Most Recent
Nonprime Mortgages
Would Not Have Been
Safe Harbor Loans
and Certain Variables
Associated with the
Safe Harbor
Requirements and
Other Factors
Influenced Defaults
Most Recent Nonprime
Loans Would Not Have Met
the Bill’s Safe Harbor
Requirements
To illustrate the potential significance of the safe harbor requirements
under different lending environments and market conditions, we applied
those requirements to nonprime mortgages originated from 2000 through
2007 and calculated the proportions of loans that likely would and would
not have met the requirements. Because of data limitations and
uncertainty about how federal regulators would have interpreted some of
the safe harbor requirements, our analysis includes a number of
assumptions discussed in this section. (See appendix I for details about
our methodology.)
We estimate that almost 75 percent of nonprime mortgages originated
from 2000 through 2007 would not have met the bill’s safe harbor
requirements. More specifically, the estimated proportion of non-safe
harbor loans ranged from a low of 58 percent for 2001 to a high of 84
Page 17 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
percent for 2006 (see fig. 2). The non-safe harbor loans were primarily
ARMs, while the safe harbor loans were largely fixed-rate mortgages. For
all 8 years combined, Alt-A mortgages represented about 37 percent of
non-safe harbor loans, or slightly more than the Alt-A share of the
nonprime market over this period (35 percent). Over this same period,
subprime mortgages comprised about 63 percent of non-safe harbor loans,
or slightly less that their 65 percent share of the nonprime market.
Figure 2: Estimated Proportions of Nonprime Mortgages Meeting and Not Meeting
the Safe Harbor Requirements, 2000-2007
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
20072006200520042003200220012000
Percentage
Year
Safe harbor loans
Non-safe harbor loans
Source: GAO analysis of LP data.
The significance of particular safe harbor requirements varied by
origination year. As previously noted, the safe harbor requirements include
the following:
Documentation and amortization. The mortgage would have to be
underwritten based on full documentation of the borrower’s income and
assets and could not have a negative amortization feature.
Interest rate and debt burden. The mortgage would be required to have
either (1) a fixed interest rate for at least 5 years, (2) a DTI ratio within a
Page 18 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
level to be specified in regulation (we used the 41 percent ratio that serves
as a guideline in underwriting FHA-insured mortgages), or (3) an ARM
with an APR of less than 3 percentage points over a generally accepted
interest rate index.
28
Because the loan data we used did not include APRs,
we instead compared the initial interest rate on each loan to the relevant
interest rate index.
29
Fully indexed rate. The mortgage would have to be underwritten to the
fully indexed interest rate (which the bill defines as the initial interest rate
index, plus the lender’s margin). We could not determine from the data we
used whether a mortgage was underwritten to the fully indexed rate. We
created a proxy by assuming that the mortgage satisfied this requirement if
the fully indexed rate was 1 percentage point or less over the initial
interest rate, indicating a reasonable likelihood that the borrower could
have qualified for a loan underwritten to the fully indexed rate.
30
As shown in figure 3, there was an increasing trend in the proportion of
nonprime loans originated from 2000 through 2007 that would not have
met the safe harbor documentation and amortization requirements. More
specifically, the estimated percentages of nonprime loans without full
documentation ranged from a low of 27 percent in 2000 to a high of almost
60 percent in 2007.
31
Also, from 2004 through 2007, the proportion of
nonprime loans with a negative amortization feature increased steadily.
The growth in these percentages reflects the increased use of low-
documentation mortgages in both the subprime and Alt-A markets and
28
We used the FHA guidelines because FHA primarily serves borrowers with credit
characteristics somewhat similar to those of nonprime borrowers.
29
Because the APR is generally higher than the initial interest rate, our results may
overestimate the number of loans that would meet this requirement. The bill did not specify
particular interest rate indexes, so we used the Treasury 2-year constant maturity rate for
short-term hybrid ARMs (e.g., 2/28 and 3/27 mortgages), the Treasury 5-year constant
maturity rate for longer-term ARMs, and the Treasury 10-year constant maturity rate for
fixed-rate mortgages.
30
One industry and one consumer group representative told us that nonprime lenders often
underwrote loans to less than the fully indexed rate. We based our assumption on the
policy of a major subprime lender, which underwrote its riskiest loans at one percentage
point below the fully indexed rate. To the extent that lenders underwrote loans to more
than one percentage point below that rate, our approach would tend to underestimate the
proportion of loans meeting the fully indexed rate requirement.
31
While our analysis examined the documentation requirement in the context of the bill’s
safe harbor provisions, the bill’s minimum lending standards include a similar requirement,
as discussed in the Background section of this report.
Page 19 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
mortgages with negative amortization features (e.g., payment-option
ARMs) in the Alt-A market. In both cases, these products were originally
intended for a narrow population of borrowers but, ultimately, became
more widespread. For example, as we reported in 2006, payment-option
ARMs were once specialized products for financially sophisticated
borrowers who wanted to minimize mortgage payments to invest funds
elsewhere or borrowers with irregular earnings who could take advantage
of minimum monthly payments during periods of lower income and could
pay down principal when they received an increase in income.
32
However,
according to federal banking regulators and a range of industry
participants, as home prices increased rapidly in some areas of the
country, lenders began marketing payment-option ARMs as affordability
products and made them available to less creditworthy and lower income
borrowers. borrowers.
Figure 3: Estimated Proportions of Nonprime Mortgages Not Meeting Figure 3: Estimated Proportions of Nonprime Mortgages Not Meeting
Documentation and Amortization Requirements, 2000-2007
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
2007
2006200520042003200220012000
Percentage
Source: GAO analysis of LP data.
Year
Documentation requirement
Amortization requirement
32
GAO-06-1021.
Page 20 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Substantial proportions of the nonprime loans made over the 8-year period
we examined also did not meet the safe harbor interest rate and debt
burden requirements, although the proportions varied by year:
The proportion of nonprime originations that did not have a fixed interest
rate for at least 5 years rose from 52 percent in 2000 to 64 percent in 2004
(see fig. 4). This increase can be attributed primarily to a shift in the Alt-A
market away from fixed-rate mortgage products to adjustable-rate
products. For example, in 2000 about 88 percent of Alt-A loans were fixed
rate, but by 2004 this figure had dropped to about 38 percent. Beginning in
2005, the percentage of nonprime originations with adjustable rates began
falling, reaching 37 percent in 2007. The decline was due in large part to a
trend in the Alt-A market toward fixed-rate mortgages.
As figure 4 also shows, the proportion of nonprime originations that did
not have a DTI ratio under 41 percent grew over the 8-year period, rising
from 43 percent in 2000 to 51 percent in 2006, although it fell slightly in
2007. The generally increasing trend is partly a result of house prices
growing faster than borrowers’ incomes over the period and of lenders
allowing borrowers to take out larger mortgages relative to their incomes.
For example, from 2000 through 2006, average home prices grew by 38
percent nationally, while over the same period, average incomes grew by
just 23 percent.
Finally, the proportion of nonprime ARM originations with initial interest
rates not less than 3 percentage points over a generally accepted interest
rate index (3 percent test) ranged from a high of 96 percent in 2002 to a
low of 48 percent in 2007 (see fig. 4). The changing proportions over time
were largely due to movements in the interest rate indexes used to set
ARM interest rates that affected the size of the gap between the initial
rates and the index values. For example, when the 2-year Treasury
constant maturity rate (a common interest rate index) dropped from 2000
through 2002, the proportion of nonprime ARMs that did not meet the 3
percent test rose. But when the 2-year Treasury rate rose from 2004
through 2006, the proportion declined sharply.
The bill’s interest rate and debt burden requirements for safe harbor
mortgages were structured so that a loan would only have to meet one of
the three requirements. As a result, some loans could have met one of the
requirements, but not one or both of the other requirements and still could
have qualified as safe harbor loans. To illustrate, of the safe harbor loans
that met the bill’s safe harbor requirements by having a fixed interest rate
for 5 or more years, almost one-half would not have met the DTI ratio
requirement, assuming the 41 percent ratio we used for our analysis. Some
Page 21 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
of the banking regulators we interviewed said that the DTI ratio was an
important factor in assessing a borrower’s ability to repay a mortgage loan.
They said that all borrowers should be required to meet some DTI ratio in
order for their loans to be eligible for the bill’s safe harbor. Consistent
with this view, H.R. 1728, which was passed by the House earlier this year,
requires borrowers of safe harbor loans to meet a DTI ratio to be
established by regulation.
Figure 4: Estimated Proportions of Nonprime Mortgages Not Meeting Interest Rate
and Debt Burden Requirements, 2000-2007
Note: About 37 percent of the loans in the LP database did not have information on the DTI ratio. We
compared the credit score distribution for loans with DTI data to the distribution for loans without this
information, and found them to be very similar. As a result, we believe that the DTI data we present
are a reasonable reflection of trends in the nonprime market as a whole.
Over the 8-year period we examined, about 38 percent of the nonprime
loans originated would not have met the safe harbor fully indexed rate
0
20
40
60
80
100
2007
2006200520042003200220012000
Percentage
Source: GAO analysis of LP data.
Year
ARM interest rate requirement
Fixed interest rate requirement
DTI requirement
Page 22 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
requirement, although the proportions varied by year (see fig. 5).
33
As
previously noted, we assumed that if the fully indexed rate—that is, the
index rate at origination plus the lender’s margin—was more than 1
percentage point above the initial interest rate, the mortgage did not meet
the requirement. The variation by year largely reflected changes in the
index used to determine the fully indexed rate. More specifically, during
years in which a commonly used index such as the 6-month LIBOR was
relatively high (e.g., 2000 and 2005 through 2006), a larger proportion of
the nonprime loans would not have met the requirement because the fully
indexed rate would have been well above the initial interest rate of the
loan. In contrast, during years in which the index was low (e.g., 2001
through 2004), a greater proportion of loans would have met the
requirement because the fully indexed rate would have been close to the
initial rate. For example, in 2000, when the average 6-month LIBOR was
6.7 percent, the proportion of nonprime loans that did not meet the fully
indexed rate requirement was 47 percent. In 2003, when the average 6-
month LIBOR was 1.2 percent, the proportion was 9 percent. A potential
shortcoming of this requirement is that many ARMs could meet this
requirement when interest rates were low, but the mortgages could
become unaffordable if interest rates were to rise and the borrower’s
payments adjusted upward to reflect the higher rates. However, it may be
difficult to design a more stringent fully indexed rate requirement to
provide protection during low interest rate environments without possibly
reducing the availability of ARMs during high interest rate environments.
33
While our analysis examined the fully indexed rate requirement in the context of the bill’s
safe harbor provisions, the bill’s minimum lending standards include a similar requirement,
as discussed in the Background section of this report.
Page 23 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Figure 5: Estimated Proportions of Nonprime Mortgages Not Meeting the Fully
Indexed Rate Requirement, 2000-2007
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
2007
2006200520042003200220012000
Percentage
Source: GAO analysis of LP data.
Year
The Proportions of Safe
Harbor and Non-Safe
Harbor Loans Differed
across Zip Code and
Borrower Groupings
Prior research has indicated that nonprime lending occurred
disproportionately in areas with higher proportions of minority, low-
income, and credit-impaired residents.
34
Therefore, in contemplating the
potential impact of the Bill, one consideration is the extent to which
nonprime mortgages made to these groups of borrowers would have fallen
inside or outside of the safe harbor. For groups with higher proportions of
non-safe harbor mortgages, the Bill’s impact on the availability of these
loans and consumer protections for them may be particularly important.
Accordingly, we examined the estimated proportions of safe harbor and
non-safe harbor loans within various zip code and borrower groupings.
35
34
GAO, Federal Housing Administration: Decline in the Agency’s Market Share Was
Associated with Product and Process Developments of Other Mortgage Market
Participants, GAO-07-645 (Washington, D.C.: June 29, 2007) and Mayer and Pence,
Subprime Mortgages: What, Where, and to Whom?”, Finance and Economics Discussion
Series 2008-29, Federal Reserve Board (2008).
35
We did not examine the reasons for differences among the various groupings as part of
our analysis.
Page 24 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Specifically, we looked at zip codes grouped by race, ethnicity, and
income characteristics, as well as borrowers grouped by credit score.
36
Our analysis of safe harbor and non-safe harbor loans by race and
ethnicity groupings found that zip codes with higher percentages of
households that Census identified as black or African-American had lower
percentages of non-safe harbor loans than the nonprime borrower
population as a whole. For example, in zip codes where black or African-
American households made up 75 percent or more of the household
population, the proportion of non-safe harbor loans was 68 percent,
compared with 75 percent for all nonprime borrowers (see table 2). In
contrast, in zip codes with higher percentages of households that Census
identified as Hispanic or Latino, the percentages of non-safe harbor loans
were higher than for nonprime borrowers as a whole. For example, in zip
codes where Hispanic or Latino households comprised 75 percent or mor
of the household population, the percentage of non-safe harbor loans was
80 percent, or 5 percentage points higher than for all nonprime
borrowers.
e
n
e as
ime borrower population.
38
37
Our analysis by income groupings found that the proportio
of non-safe harbor loans for each grouping was essentially the sam
that for the entire nonpr
Table 2: Percentage of Nonprime Mortgages That Were Safe Harbor and Non-safe
Harbor Loans by Racial, Ethnic, and Income Groupings, 2000-2007
Zip code population
grouping
Percentage of safe
harbor loans
Percentage of non-safe
harbor loans
All nonprime borrowers 25 75
Black or African-American
Less than 5% 25 75
5% to 24% 26 74
25% to 74% 29 71
75% or greater 32 68
36
We used the Census 2000 data for our analysis.
37
Individuals who classify themselves as Hispanic or Latino include people of different
racial backgrounds.
38
We defined low-, moderate-, and upper-income census tracts as those with median
incomes that were less than 80 percent, at least 80 percent but less than 120 percent, and
120 percent and above, respectively, of the median income for the associated metropolitan
statistical area.
Page 25 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Zip code population
grouping
Percentage of safe
harbor loans
Percentage of non-safe
harbor loans
Hispanic or Latino
Less than 5% 31 69
5% to 24% 24 76
25% to 74% 20 80
75% or greater 20 80
Median income
Low income 26 74
Moderate income 25 75
Upper income 24 76
Source: GAO analysis of LP and Census data.
We also analyzed safe harbor and non-safe harbor loans by credit score
groupings. We used four groupings that ranged from the least creditworthy
borrowers (scores of 599 and less) to the most creditworthy borrowers
(scores of 720 and above). We found that borrowers with scores of 599
and less (the lowest category) had the smallest percentage of non-safe
harbor loans (69 percent), while borrowers with scores of 600 to 719 (the
second highest category) had the largest percentage of non-safe harbor
loans (see table 3).
Table 3: Percentage of Nonprime Mortgages That Were Safe Harbor and Non-Safe
Harbor Loans by Credit Score Groupings, 2000-2007
Credit score
grouping
Percentage of safe harbor
loans
Percentage of non-safe
harbor loans
599 and less 31 69
600-659 25 75
660-719 22 78
720 and above 26 74
Source: GAO analysis of LP and Census data.
Page 26 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Prior research has shown that a number of different loan, borrower, and
economic variables influence the performance of a loan. To see if the bill’s
provisions appear to fulfill their consumer protection purpose, we
developed a statistical model, based on the data available to us, to
examine the relationship between safe harbor requirements, as well as a
subset of other variables known to affect performance, and the probability
of a loan defaulting within the first 24 months of origination.
39
We defined
a loan as being in default if it was delinquent by at least 90 days, in the
foreclosure process (including loans identified as in real-estate-owned
status), paid off after being 90 days delinquent or in foreclosure, or had
already terminated with evidence of a loss.
Some of the Safe Harbor
Requirements and Other
Factors Were Associated
with the Likelihood of
Default
We focused on 24-month performance because a large proportion of
nonprime borrowers—particularly those with hybrid ARMs—prepaid their
loans (e.g., by refinancing) within 2 years. Using a 24-month time frame
allowed us to include these loans in our model. The variables we used in
the model included variables based on the individual safe harbor
requirements, house price appreciation, borrower credit scores, and LTV
ratios.
40
We developed the model using data on nonprime mortgages
originated from 2000 through 2006 (the latest year for which we could
examine 24-month performance). We produced separate estimates for four
types of loan products: (1) short-term hybrid ARMs (i.e., 2/28 or 3/27
mortgages), which accounted for 54 percent of the loans originated during
this period; (2) longer-term ARMs (i.e., ARMs with interest rates that were
fixed for 5, 7, or 10 years before adjusting), which accounted for 10
percent of originations; (3) payment-option ARMs, which represented 6
percent of originations and (4) fixed-rate mortgages, which represented 30
39
As previously discussed, data limitations prevented us from developing variables that
precisely replicated all of the safe harbor requirements. Had we been able to do so, the
results of our statistical analysis might have been different. Additionally, certain variables
associated with the risk of default (e.g., borrower income) were not contained in the data
set we used and, therefore, are not reflected in our model.
40
As an alternative specification for short-term hybrid ARMs, we included a variable
indicating whether each mortgage was a safe harbor or a non-safe harbor loan, in contrast
to including variables for separate safe harbor requirements. We found that this variable
had a small marginal effect, most likely because many non-safe harbor loans met some of
the safe harbor requirements. In particular, a substantial percentage of non-safe harbor
loans had full documentation of borrower income and assets but failed to meet other safe
harbor requirements.
Page 27 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
percent of originations.
41
Appendix II provides additional information
about our model and estimation results.
Consistent with the consumer protection purpose of the bill’s provisions,
we found that two safe harbor variables were associated with the
probability of default. Across all product types, the safe harbor variable
with the largest estimated influence on default probability was
documentation of borrower income and assets. For example, less than full
documentation was associated with a 5.5 percentage point increase in the
estimated probability of default for short-term hybrid ARMs used for home
purchases, all other things being equal (see table 4). The corresponding
increases in estimated default probabilities for longer-term ARMs,
payment-option ARMs, and fixed-rate mortgages were 4.8 percent, 2.0
percent, and 4.6 percent, respectively. The higher default probabilities
associated with no- and low-documentation loans may reflect use of this
feature to overstate the financial resources of some borrowers and qualify
them for larger, potentially unaffordable loans. Our results are generally
consistent with prior research showing an association between a lack of
documentation and higher default probabilities.
42
41
For short-term hybrid ARMs, longer-term ARMs, and fixed-rate mortgages, we present
estimation results for purchase loans in the body of the report, and results for both
purchase and refinance loans in appendix II. In the body of the report and appendix II, the
estimation results we present for payment-option ARMs are for purchase and refinance
loans combined, and reflect mortgages originated from 2003 through 2006. We took this
approach for payment-option ARMs because the proportion of purchase loans was
relatively small and very few of these loans were made prior to 2003.
42
Pennington-Cross and Ho, “The Termination of Subprime Hybrid and Fixed Rate
Mortgages,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series (2006), Sherlund,
“The Past, Present, and Future of Subprime Mortgages,” Finance and Economic
Discussion Series 2008-63, Federal Reserve Board (2008), Demyanyk, “Quick Exits of
Subprime Mortgages,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 91(2): (2009).
Page 28 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Table 4: Estimated Probability of Nonprime Purchase Mortgages Defaulting within
24 months of Origination with and without Full Documentation, 2000-2006 Loans
Estimated probability of default
Product type
Full documentation
Less than full
documentation
Short-term hybrid ARMs 14.0% 19.5%
Longer-term ARMs 3.5 8.3
Payment-option ARMs
a
2.1 4.1
Fixed-rate mortgages 4.7 9.3
Source: GAO analysis of LP data.
Note: The estimated default probabilities we present do not necessarily reflect the ultimate
performance of any product type. For example, many payment-option ARMs do not recast to higher,
fully amortized payments until 5 years after origination. Because we focused on 24-month
performance, our analysis does not capture defaults on payment-option ARMs that may occur due to
future increases in monthly payments.
a
Includes purchase and refinance loans.
A second safe harbor variable that had a significant influence on default
probability was the variable representing the difference between the loan’s
initial interest rate and the relevant interest rate index (the spread). As
previously noted, ARMs with a difference of 3 percentage points or more
over a generally accepted interest rate index would not meet one of the
bill’s safe harbor interest rate and debt burden requirements. To examine
the effect of this variable for each product type, we estimated the default
probability assuming the spread was near the 25th percentile (base
assumption) for that product and compared this with the estimated default
probability assuming the spread was near the 75th percentile (alternative
assumption) for that product. We estimated that for short-term hybrid
ARMs used for home purchases, moving from the lower spread to the
higher one was associated with a 4.0 percentage point increase in default
probability, all other things remaining equal (see table 5). The
corresponding increases in estimated default probabilities for longer-term
ARMs and fixed-rate mortgages were 1.8 percent and 2.6 percent,
respectively. These results were generally consistent with other economic
research showing a positive relationship between higher interest rates and
default probabilities for nonprime mortgages.
43
This relationship may
43
Demyanyk, “Quick Exits of Subprime Mortgages.”
Page 29 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
reflect the higher monthly payments associated with higher interest rates
and difficulties borrowers may face in making these payments, particularly
during times of economic hardship.
Table 5: Estimated Probability of Nonprime Purchase Mortgages Defaulting within
24 months of Origination under Different Assumptions for the Safe Harbor Spread
Requirement, 2000-2006 Loans
Variable
(base assumption)
Estimated
probability of
default
Variable
(alternative
assumption)
Estimated
probability of
default
Short-term hybrid ARMs
Spread of 3 percent 14.1% Spread of 5 percent 18.1%
Longer-term ARMs
Spread of 1.75 percent 5.2% Spread of 2.5 percent 7.0%
Fixed-rate mortgages
Spread of 2 percent 4.8% Spread of 3.75
percent
7.4%
Source: GAO analysis of LP data.
Note: As indicated earlier, the relevant interest rate index we used for short-term hybrid ARMs was
the Treasury 2-year constant maturity rate. For longer-term ARMs we used the Treasury 5-year
constant maturity rate, and for fixed-rate mortgages we used the Treasury 10-year constant maturity
rate.
We also estimated the effect of the DTI ratio at origination and found that
for all product types, this variable did not have a strong influence on the
probability of default within 24 months. This relatively weak association
may be due, in part, to changes in borrower income or indebtedness after
loan origination. For example, a mortgage that is affordable to the
borrower at origination may become less so if the borrower experiences a
decline in income or takes on additional nonmortgage debt.
44
Finally, we estimated the effect of the proxy variable we developed for the
safe harbor requirement that loans be underwritten to the fully indexed
44
For a further discussion of this hypothesis, see Foote and others, Reducing Foreclosures,
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Public Policy Discussion Paper 09-2, (Apr. 2009).
Page 30 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
rate.
45
As previously noted, if the fully indexed rate was 1 percentage point
or less over the initial interest rate, we assumed the loan met this
requirement. For all product types, we found that this variable did not
have a strong influence on the probability of default within 24 months (see
app. II). It is possible that other model specifications—such as examining
default probabilities beyond 24 months—would have yielded different
results. For example, the difference between the initial interest rate and
the fully indexed rate might have been more significant using such an
alternative specification because the initial interest rates for many short-
term hybrid ARMs begin adjusting upward after 24 months.
In examining the influence of safe harbor variables on the probability of
default within 24 months, we controlled for other variables not associated
with the safe harbor requirements, such as house price appreciation,
borrower credit score, and the LTV ratio. Because these variables have
been shown to influence default probabilities, it was important to control
for their effects in order to properly analyze the implications of the safe
harbor provisions. Consistent with other economic research, we found
that house price appreciation, borrower credit score, and the LTV ratio
were strongly associated with default probabilities.
46
The estimated
influence of these variables on default probabilities for each product type
were as follows:
45
We did not estimate the effect of the safe harbor variable representing whether a loan was
fixed for at least 5 years because this feature is only associated with certain mortgage
products. We only estimated the effect of the safe harbor variable representing whether a
loan had a negative amortization feature for longer-term ARMs. We did not include it in the
models for the other mortgage types because the negative amortization feature was,
essentially, never present (in the case of fixed-rate mortgages and short-term hybrid ARMs)
or was, essentially, always present (in the case of payment-option ARMs). The lack of
variation within these mortgage types made estimating the marginal effects of the negative
amortization variable problematic.
46
Danis and Pennington-Cross, “The Delinquency of Subprime Mortgages,” Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis Working Paper 05-022A (2005), and Sherlund, “The Past, Present, and
Future of Subprime Mortgages.”
Page 31 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
House price appreciation.
47
We found that lower rates of house price
appreciation were associated with a higher likelihood of default. For each
product type, we estimated the default probability assuming house price
appreciation near the 75th percentile for that product (base assumption)
and compared this with the estimated default probability assuming house
price appreciation near the 25th percentile for that product (alternative
assumption). For short-term hybrid ARMs used for home purchases,
moving from the higher rate of appreciation to the lower rate was
associated with a 13.5 percentage point increase in estimated default
probability (see fig. 6). The corresponding figures for longer-term ARMs,
payment-option ARMs, and fixed-rate mortgages were 3.7 percent, 1.3
percent, and 3.5 percent, respectively.
Borrower credit score. We found that lower credit scores were associated
with a higher likelihood of default. For each product type, we estimated
the default probability assuming a borrower credit score close to the 75th
percentile for that product (base assumption) and compared this with the
estimated default probability assuming a borrower credit score close to
the 25th percentile for that product (alternative assumption). For short-
term hybrid ARMs used for home purchases, moving from the higher
credit score to the lower one was associated with a 7.3 percentage point
increase in the estimated default probability (see fig. 6). For longer-term
ARMs, payment-option ARMs, and fixed-rate mortgages, the
corresponding figures were 3.3 percent, 2.1 percent, and 5.5 percent,
respectively.
LTV ratio. We found that higher LTV ratios were associated with higher
probabilities of default. For each product type, we estimated the default
probability assuming a LTV ratio close to the 25th percentile for that
product (base assumption) and compared this with the estimated default
probability assuming a LTV ratio close to the 75th percentile for that
product (alternative assumption). For short-term hybrid ARMs used for
home purchases, moving from the lower ratio to the higher ratio was
associated with a 4.4 percentage point increase in the estimated default
47
We used the Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA) house index (HPI), which is a
broad measure of the movement of single-family house prices. The HPI is a measure
designed to capture changes in the value of single-family homes in the U.S. as a whole, in
various regions of the country, and in the individual states and the District of Columbia.
The HPI is published by FHFA using data provided by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. The
Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight (OFHEO), one of FHFA’s predecessor
agencies, began publishing the HPI in the fourth quarter of 1995.
Page 32 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
probability (see fig. 6). The corresponding figures for longer-term ARMs,
payment-option ARMs, and fixed-rate mortgages were 4.7 percent, 6.3
percent, and 3.7 percent, respectively.
Page 33 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Figure 6: Estimated Probability of Nonprime Purchase Mortgages Defaulting within
24 Months under Different House Price Appreciation, Credit Score, and LTV Ratio
Assumptions, 2000-2006 Loans
Source: GAO analysis of LP data.
Short-term
hybrid ARMs
Longer-term
ARMs
Payment -
option
ARMs
a
Fixed-rate
mortgages
Base estimated probability of default
Alternative estimated probability of default
Variable
Base
Assumption:
Alternative
Estimated probability of default
House price apprecia-
tion 24 months after
origination:
Borrower credit score:
LTV ratio:
House price apprecia-
tion 24 months after
origination:
Borrower credit score:
LTV ratio:
House price apprecia-
tion 24 months after
origination:
Borrower credit score:
LTV ratio:
House price apprecia-
tion 24 months after
origination:
Borrower credit score:
LTV ratio:
0%
600
100%
-10%
675
100%
-10%
675
90%
5%
625
100%
25%
675
80%
20%
750
90%
15%
750
75%
25%
725
80%
24.2
20.6
18.0
7.0
7.8
8.1
3.6
4.6
9.0
7.9
9.6
8.4
10.7
13.3
13.6
3.3
4.5
3.4
2.3
2.5
2.7
4.4
4.1
4.7
%
%
a
Includes purchase and refinance loans.
Page 34 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
While some research indicates that anti-predatory lending laws can reduce
originations of problematic loans without overly restricting credit,
research on state and local anti-predatory lending laws and the views of
mortgage industry stakeholders do not provide a consensus view on the
potential effects of the bill. The state and local anti-predatory lending laws
we reviewed are, in some ways, similar to the bill, but the results of the
research on these laws may have limited applicability to the bill for a
number of reasons. Mortgage industry and consumer group
representatives we interviewed disagreed on the bill’s potential effect on
credit availability and consumer protections. For example, mortgage
industry representatives said that the safe harbor and assignee liability
provisions were too stringent and would restrict and raise the cost of
mortgage credit. In contrast, consumer group representatives indicated
that the provisions were not strong enough to prevent predatory lending
and, thereby, protect borrowers.
Relevant Research
and Stakeholder
Perspectives Do Not
Provide a Consensus
View on the Bill’s
Potential Impact
Research Shows That State
and Local Laws Can Affect
Mortgage Lending, but the
Findings Are Difficult to
Apply to the Bill
Several studies have examined the impact of state and local anti-predatory
lending laws on subprime mortgage markets. Our review of eight such
studies found evidence that anti-predatory lending laws can have the
intended effect of reducing loans with problematic features without
substantially affecting credit availability, but also that it is difficult to
generalize these findings to all anti-predatory lending laws or to the
potential effect of the bill.
48
The studies we reviewed fell into two broad
categories: those that focused solely on the North Carolina law and those
that examined laws in multiple states and localities. In general, the
researchers measured the effect of the laws in terms of the volume of
subprime originations, the probability of originating a subprime loan, or
the probability of originating a loan with predatory characteristics.
The three studies on the North Carolina law (which was implemented in
phases beginning in October 1999 and ending in July 2000) concluded that
the law had a dampening effect on subprime originations in that state, but
one found that the drop occurred primarily in the types of loans targeted
by the law. For example, using data from nine subprime lenders and
controlling for a number of demographic and housing market variables,
48
We identified a number of studies examining the impact of state and local anti-predatory
lending laws on subprime mortgage lending. We narrowed our scope to eight studies that
used control groups (e.g., comparison states without anti-predatory lending laws) or
statistical techniques that controlled for factors other than the laws that could affect
lending patterns.
Page 35 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Elliehausen and Staten estimated that subprime originations fell by 14
percent after the law was first implemented.
49
A second study by Quercia,
Stegman, and Davis that used an LP data set with broader coverage and
used neighboring states as a control group, found that subprime
originations declined 3 percent after the law was fully implemented and
that subprime originations in four neighboring states without similar laws
rose over the same period.
50
Importantly, the authors also determined that
90 percent of the decline in subprime originations resulted from a
decrease in refinance loans with one or more “predatory” characteristics,
such as prepayment penalties lasting 3 years or more, balloon payments,
or LTV ratios over 110 percent. Finally, a study by Burnett, Finkel and
Kaul, which used Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) data and also
used neighboring states as a control group, found a 0.2 percent increase in
subprime originations in North Carolina after implementation of the law.
Like the Quercia study, the study by Burnett and others concluded that
subprime refinance loans fell sharply in North Carolina over the period
examined and that states neighboring North Carolina experienced higher
percentage increases in total subprime originations.
51
Additionally, the
study noted that the volume of subprime originations in North Carolina fell
in census tracts that were more than 50 percent minority but rose in other
areas.
The five studies that examined multiple state and local anti-predatory
lending laws found mixed results but provide insights into the importance
of the specific attributes of the laws. For example, using HMDA data, Ho
and Pennington-Cross calculated the percentage change in subprime
originations in 10 states with anti-predatory lending laws over periods that
captured each state’s experience before and after the laws were passed.
52
49
Elliehausen and Staten, “Regulation of Subprime Mortgage Products: An Analysis of North
Carolina’s Predatory Lending Law,” Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 29:
(2004). The study used data covering the period from January 1997 through March 2000.
50
Quercia, Stegman, and Davis, “Assessing the Impact of North Carolina’s Predatory
Lending Law,” Housing Policy Debate 15: (2004). The study compared the volume of
subprime originations in the seven quarters prior to the initial implementation of the law to
the seven quarters after the law’s full implementation.
51
Burnett, Finkel, and Kaul, “Mortgage Lending in North Carolina After the Anti-Predatory
Lending Law,” A Report from Abt Associates to the Mortgage Bankers Association of
America, (Cambridge, MA: 2004). The study used data covering 1997 through 1998 and 2000
through 2002.
52
Ho and Pennington-Cross, “The Varying Effects of Predatory Lending Laws on High-Cost
Mortgage Applications,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 89: (2007). The study
used data covering 1999 through 2004.
Page 36 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
They compared the changes they found with the corresponding changes
during the same periods in a control group of neighboring states without
such laws. They found that in 5 of the 10 states (including North Carolina)
with anti-predatory lending laws, subprime originations increased less
than in the control group, but that in the other 5 states, subprime
originations increased more. In another study, Ho and Pennington-Cross
developed a legal index to measure the coverage and restrictions of anti-
predatory lending laws, and examined how laws in 25 states and 3
localities affected the probability of originating a subprime loan.
53
They
found that, controlling for other factors, anti-predatory lending laws can
increase, decrease, or have no effect on the flow of mortgage credit.
Specifically, they found that:
laws with broader coverage (i.e., those affecting a larger portion of the
market) increased the estimated likelihood of subprime originations;
those with greater restrictions (i.e., those with stricter limits on high-risk
loan features) decreased the estimated likelihood of subprime
originations; and
in some instances, these two effects appeared to cancel each other out.
As a result, they noted that the design of the law can have an important
impact on the availability of credit in the subprime market. For example,
the authors hypothesized that the effect of broader coverage may result
from borrowers being more comfortable applying for a mortgage where
there is a law to protect them from predatory loans.
A study by Bostic and others built on this research by refining the legal
index previously discussed, adding an enforcement dimension to the
index, and examining a larger set of laws.
54
The study confirmed the earlier
findings regarding the impact of the coverage and restriction provisions of
anti-predatory lending laws on the subprime market. Additionally, this
study found that the strength of a law’s enforcement provisions (e.g., the
53
Ho and Pennington-Cross, “The impact of local predatory lending laws on the flow of
subprime credit,” Journal of Urban Economics 60: (2006).
54
Bostic and others, “State and Local Anti-Predatory Lending Laws: The Effect of Legal
Enforcement Mechanisms,” Journal of Economics and Business 60: (2007). The study
examined 44 states with either anti-predatory lending laws or other laws or regulations
regulating prepayment penalties, balloon clauses, or mandatory arbitration clauses in
residential mortgages as of January 1, 2007.
Page 37 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
extent of potential liability for assignees) was not associated with changes
in the estimated likelihood of subprime originations.
Li and Ernst examined anti-predatory lending laws in 33 states and used
LP data on subprime mortgages made from January 1998 through March
2005 to examine the impact of these laws on the origination of loans with
predatory features and the cost of subprime credit.
55
They concluded that
state anti-predatory lending laws that provided greater consumer
protections than HOEPA had the intended effect of reducing subprime
mortgages with predatory features. They also concluded that such laws
did not lead to any systematic increase in costs to consumers. Pennington-
Cross and Ho also examined the impact of predatory lending laws on the
cost of subprime credit by reviewing anti-predatory lending laws in 24
states and analyzing HMDA and LP data from 1998 through 2005.
56
They
concluded that these laws resulted in, at most, a modest increase to
consumers’ cost of borrowing.
Although the bill is, in some ways, similar to the state and local laws
analyzed in these studies, the results of these studies may have limited
applicability to it, for a number of reasons. First, the legal indexes used by
some researchers to assess the impact of state and local laws are based on
an older set of laws that are similar to HOEPA. According to one of these
researchers, the indexes do not take into account a newer generation of
laws that, like the bill, have different thresholds and restrictions and cover
products that were previously not common in the marketplace (e.g., low-
and no-documentation loans). As a result, evaluating the bill, using these
analytical tools, could be problematic. Additionally, the impact of a federal
law could be different than the effects of state and local laws. For
example, lenders or assignees may choose to exit a state or local market
rather than comply with that jurisdiction’s anti-predatory lending law but
still conduct business in other markets. However, under a federal law,
these entities would not have that option. Finally, prior studies examined
the impact of laws during a relatively active period in the subprime lending
market. If a law similar to the bill were to be passed in the near future, it
would be implemented in the wake of a major contraction in the mortgage
55
Li and Ernst, “Do State Predatory Lending Laws Work? A Panel Analysis of Market
Reforms,” Housing Policy Debate 18: (2007).
56
Pennington-Cross and Ho, “Predatory Lending Laws and the Cost of Credit,” Real Estate
Economics, 36: (2008).
Page 38 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
market that would likely affect the response of both the mortgage industry
and consumers to new lending standards.
Views Differed Regarding
the Bill’s Long-Term Effect
on the Mortgage Market
Mortgage industry representatives and consumer groups we interviewed
generally agreed that the bill would have little short-term impact on the
mortgage market because of existing market conditions. However, they
held different views on the long-term impact that key provisions in the bill
would have on consumer access to affordable credit and protection from
predatory lending practices.
Representatives from both groups generally agreed that the bill would
have very little impact on mortgage originations in the current financial
environment because the overall primary market was highly constrained,
with lenders tightening qualifications for all borrowers and the market for
private label MBS virtually nonexistent. In addition, representatives from
mortgage industry groups expected that the Federal Reserve’s revisions to
Regulation Z could lessen the impact of the bill.
57
Specifically, the groups
stated that the revisions to Regulation Z would place lender requirements
on nonprime loans that were similar to the bill’s safe harbor requirements.
For example, both the Regulation Z revisions and the bill’s safe harbor
require that borrowers obtaining loans with APRs over certain thresholds
provide full documentation of income and assets and qualify for ARMs
based on a monthly payment that takes into account scheduled interest
rate increases.
58
Recent Market Conditions and
Regulatory Initiatives
Mortgage industry representatives we interviewed generally viewed the
bill’s safe harbor requirements as overly restrictive and said that these
requirements would reduce mortgage options and increase the cost of
credit for certain borrowers. Some of these representatives said that
lenders would be unwilling to make loans that did not meet the safe
harbor requirements. They cited the experience with HOEPA as an
example of what might take place if the safe harbor requirements were put
in place. Specifically, they noted that since the implementation of HOEPA,
Safe Harbor Requirements
57
The Federal Reserve Board made revisions in 2008 to Regulation Z, which implement the
Truth in Lending Act and HOEPA.
58
The bill’s safe harbor requires lenders to qualify borrowers at the fully indexed rate,
which is defined as the index rate at the time of origination plus the lender’s margin.
Regulation Z requires lenders to qualify borrowers at the highest possible payment in the
first 7 years of the loan for both higher-priced and high-cost HOEPA loans. In addition, both
the Act and Regulation Z limit, or in certain cases prohibit, prepayment penalties.
Page 39 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
very few lenders have been willing to make mortgages considered “high
cost” loans under HOEPA’s provisions because they cannot sell them to
the secondary market. For example, in 2006, less than 1 percent of
mortgages were high cost loans, as defined by HOEPA regulations.
The industry representatives also said that specific safe harbor
requirements would reduce access to credit for certain types of borrowers.
For example, they said that the safe harbor requirement that would
prohibit loans with less than full documentation of income and assets
could restrict access to credit for borrowers with irregular income
streams, such as some small business owners. Some industry
representatives acknowledged that many low- and no-documentation
mortgages should not have been made, but said that some flexibility
should be allowed under this requirement to account for borrowers with
nontraditional sources of income.
In addition, industry representatives said that borrowers who had
responsibly used negative amortization loans in the past could face limited
mortgage options under the bill, as the safe harbor requirement would
prohibit these loans. Some industry representatives acknowledged that
negative amortization products had been used inappropriately in recent
years to allow some borrowers to buy homes that they might not have
been able to afford, but added that prohibiting this feature would
adversely impact borrowers who had used this product responsibly. For
example, some borrowers with irregular income have taken out negative
amortization loans in order to pay minimum amounts when their income
was low and higher amounts when their income increased. One mortgage
industry participant suggested that one way to address concerns that these
loans subject borrowers to payment shock would be to limit the amount
by which the mortgage payments could reset.
In contrast, representatives from consumer groups that we interviewed
generally indicated that the safe harbor requirements would need to be
strengthened and applied to a broader range of loans in order to prevent
predatory lending practices to protect borrowers. For example, some
representatives supported adding more consumer protection features to
the bill, such as prohibiting prepayment penalties, balloon payments, and
Page 40 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
yield spread premiums.
59
They also said that the bill’s safe harbor
requirements should be applied to all mortgages, including FHA-insured
mortgages and loans with relatively low APRs, because these loans could
also contain predatory features.
Most of the consumer group representatives said that strengthening safe
harbor requirements and applying them more broadly would not
significantly affect the cost or availability of credit. For example, in
response to industry concerns that requiring full documentation would
restrict some borrowers’ access to credit, consumer group representatives
noted that full documentation had already become a marketplace
standard. They generally believed that the majority of borrowers, including
self-employed consumers, could provide sufficient documentation using
their income tax records, but some groups supported limited flexibility in
the types of documents that would be accepted. In addition, while industry
groups were concerned that prohibiting loans with a negative amortization
feature under the bill’s safe harbor provisions could restrict credit to some
borrowers, consumer groups supported prohibiting this feature in order to
protect consumers from potential payment shock. Some of these
representatives acknowledged that negative amortization loans could be
suitable for certain borrowers, but they viewed these cases as exceptional
and did not think the potential benefits to a small segment outweighed the
potential costs to the larger portion of the market.
Mortgage industry representatives we interviewed generally said that the
bill’s assignee liability provisions would increase the cost of credit for
borrowers and deter secondary market participants from reentering the
nonprime market. Specifically, these representatives said that the cost of
complying with the bill’s assignee liability provisions, including secondary
market participants’ cost of due diligence procedures, would increase the
cost of credit and cause some secondary market participants to stop
securitizing loans. Some industry representatives stated that mortgage
originators were better positioned to conduct due diligence to ensure that
loans were responsibly underwritten and argued that mortgage reform
legislation should focus on enhancing the primary market’s underwriting
standards.
A
ssignee Liability Provisions
59
A more recent bill with similar purposes, the Mortgage Reform and Anti-Predatory
Lending Act of 2009 (H.R. 1728) bans yield spread premiums for all mortgages. A “yield
spread premium” is a payment a mortgage broker receives from a lender based on the
difference between the actual interest rate on the loan and the rate the lender would have
accepted on the loan given the risks and costs involved.
Page 41 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Mortgage industry representatives also said that lack of certainty in what
assignees could be held liable for under the bill would deter participants
from reentering the secondary market. For example, some representatives
noted that the bill did not clearly define the standards that assignees
would be held to, such as “ability to repay” and “net tangible benefit.” They
cited Georgia’s 2002 anti-predatory lending law as an example of how the
lack of clarity concerning assignee liability could adversely impact the
market. As we have reported, because of the uncertainty surrounding
potential liability under the Georgia law, secondary market participants
withdrew from the mortgage market in Georgia until the provisions were
repealed.
60
In contrast, consumer group representatives generally believed that
enhanced regulation and accountability in the secondary market would
provide consumers with greater protections against predatory lending
practices. These representatives generally supported strengthening the
bill’s assignee liability provisions. For example, some consumer group
representatives said that the bill’s assignee liability provisions should not
allow for any exemptions from liability, such as allowing assignees to cure
a loan (i.e., modify or refinance the loan so that it meets the bill’s
minimum lending standards) to avoid liability. They noted that some
assignees might choose to cure the relatively few loans that violate the
bill’s minimum lending standards, rather than invest the resources in due
diligence policies and procedures that would help prevent predatory
lending practices.
Further, consumer groups said that the bill should not preempt state
assignee liability laws because these laws could potentially provide
consumers with an ability to seek redress if they obtain a predatory loan.
Finally, representatives of consumer groups also said that applying the
assignee liability provisions more broadly, beyond the bill’s nonqualified
mortgages, could also help prevent predatory lending on a wider variety of
mortgages. They contended that stronger and broader assignee liability
provisions would not significantly impact the cost of or access to credit
and would set a standard to which secondary market participants would
eventually adapt.
Mortgage industry representatives preferred that any federal legislation on
mortgage lending preempt all state anti-predatory lending laws, not just
Federal Preemption of State
Anti-Predatory Lending Laws
60
GAO-04-280.
Page 42 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
assignee liability laws, in order to reduce the cost of and increase the
availability of credit. They stated that a uniform set of mortgage standards
for lenders would significantly reduce the cost of doing business and that
these savings could be passed on to consumers. According to one
mortgage industry participant, under the current legal and regulatory
environment, lenders’ costs are higher because lenders are required to
develop systems to track laws and regulations in up to 50 states, monitor
these laws and regulations, and ensure they are in compliance with them.
Some industry representatives stated that federal preemption could also
lower consumer costs by applying uniform standards and supporting
competition between state- and federally licensed mortgage originators.
Mortgage industry representatives also said that full federal preemption
would provide a uniform set of standards that would renew activity in the
secondary market, thereby, allowing lenders to make more credit available
to consumers.
In contrast, consumer group representatives generally believed that
federal legislation should not preempt state laws, because consumers
benefited from states’ abilities to enact stronger consumer protection
laws. For example, some consumer groups said that in the past, states had
responded faster to predatory lending abuses than federal regulators in
enacting anti-predatory lending laws, and expected this to continue if a
federal bill did not preempt state laws. Further, some of these
representatives said that state and federal regulations existed in a
complementary framework in other areas, such as civil rights and the
environment, and generally did not think that compliance costs would be
significant in light of the benefits to consumers and the long-term
sustainability of the mortgage market. They viewed states’
experimentation with mortgage reform as an important source of useful
information on changes in market conditions and industry responses to
different approaches.
We provided a draft of this report to the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Office of the
Comptroller of the Currency, Office of Thrift Supervision, National Credit
Union Administration, Department of Housing and Urban Development,
Federal Trade Commission, and Securities and Exchange Commission. We
received written comments from NCUA, which are summarized below.
Appendix III contains a reprint of NCUA’s letter. The Federal Reserve,
FDIC, OCC, HUD, and FTC provided technical comments, which we
incorporated into this report, where appropriate.
Agency Comments
and Our Evaluation
Page 43 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
In its written comments, NCUA reiterated several of our findings and
noted that the findings supported its view that ensuring borrowers have a
reasonable ability to repay is in the best interest of credit unions and their
members.
We are sending copies of this report to the Ranking Member, House
Financial Services Committee and other interested parties. We will also
send copies to the Federal Reserve, FDIC, OCC, OTS, NCUA, HUD, FTC,
and SEC. The report also will be available at no charge on the GAO Web
site at http://www.gao.gov.
If you or your staff have questions about this report, please contact me at
(202) 512-8678 or [email protected]. Contact points for our Offices of
Congressional Relations and Public Affairs are on the last page of this
report. GAO staff who made major contributions to this report are listed in
appendix IV.
Director, Financial Markets
y Investment
William B. Shear
and Communit
Page 44 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix I:
Methodology
Objectives, Scope, and
Page 45 GAO-09-741
Appendix I: Objectives, Scope, and
Methodology
Our objectives were to (1) assess the proportion of recent nonprime loans
that would likely have met and not met the Mortgage Reform and Anti-
Predatory Lending Act of 2007’s (bill) safe harbor requirements, and how
variables associated with those requirements affect loan performance; and
(2) discuss relevant research and the views of mortgage industry
stakeholders concerning the potential impact of key provisions of the bill
on the mortgage market. The scope of our analysis was limited to the
nonprime mortgages.
Nonprime Loans and the
Safe Harbor Requirements
To assess the proportions of nonprime loans originated from 2000 through
2007 that would likely have met and not met the bill’s safe harbor
requirements, we analyzed data on subprime and Alt-A (nonprime)
mortgages from that period. Specifically, we analyzed information from
LoanPerformance’s (LP) Asset-backed Securities database, which contains
loan-level data on nonagency securitized mortgages in subprime and Alt-A
pools.
1
About three-quarters of subprime mortgages were securitized in
recent years. For purposes of this report, we defined subprime loans as
mortgages in subprime pools and Alt-A loans as mortgages in Alt-A pools.
2
The LP database covers the vast majority of mortgages in nonagency
subprime and Alt-A securitizations. For example, for the period 2001
through July 2007, the LP database contains information covering (in
dollar terms) an estimated 87 percent of securitized subprime loans and 98
percent of securitized Alt-A loans (see table 6). Nonprime mortgages that
were not securitized (i.e., mortgages that lenders held in portfolio) may
have different characteristics and performance histories than those that
were securitized.
1
Nonagency mortgage-backed securities (MBS), also known as private-label MBS, are
backed by nonconforming mortgages securitized primarily by investment banks.
2
We used this approach because the field in the LP database indicating whether a mortgage
was subprime or Alt-A was not well-populated. According to mortgage researchers, some
of the loans in subprime pools may not be subprime loans, and some of the loans in Alt-A
pools may not be Alt-A loans.
Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix I: Objectives, Scope, and
Methodology
Table 6: Estimated Percentage of Nonagency Securitized Subprime and Alt-A Loans in the LP Database, 2001-2007
Year
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
a
Subprime 83% 77% 87% 87% 88% 91% 85%
Alt-A 97 99 99 97 98 98 96
Source: LP.
Note: Percentages are in terms of dollar volume.
a
Percentages reflect loans securitized as of the end of July 2007.
For our analysis, we used a random 2 percent sample of the database that
amounted to almost 300,000 loans for the 2000 through 2007 period. Our
sample included purchase and refinance mortgages and loans to owner-
occupants and investors, and excluded second-lien mortgages.
We assessed the reliability of the data by interviewing LP representatives
about the methods they use to collect and ensure the integrity of the
information. We also reviewed supporting documentation about the
database, including LP’s estimates of the database’s market coverage. In
addition, we conducted reasonableness checks on the data to identify any
missing, erroneous, or outlying figures. We found the data elements we
used to be sufficiently reliable.
To estimate the proportion of loans that likely would have met and not
met the safe harbor requirements, we used variables in the LP database
that directly corresponded with the requirements and developed proxies
when the database did not contain such variables (see table 7).
Page 46 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix I: Objectives, Scope, and
Methodology
Table 7: Safe Harbor Requirements and LP Variables Used to Duplicate the Requirements or Develop Proxies
Safe harbor requirement LP variable used Comments
Loan must have full documentation of
income and financial resources of
borrower.
DOCUMENT: Specifies whether the loan
has full, low, or no documentation.
Loans with full documentation met the
requirement. Loans with low or no
documentation did not meet the requirement.
Loan must be underwritten to the fully
indexed rate. (This requirement only
applies to adjustable rate mortgages
(ARM)).
INDEX_ID: Specifies the type of interest
rate index to which an ARM is tied (e.g.,
London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR))
MARGIN: Specifies the margin for ARMs.
INIT_RATE: Specifies the initial interest
rate as of the loan’s first payment.
The LP data set did not have information on
this safe harbor requirement. As a result, we
developed a proxy by assuming that the
mortgage met the requirement if the fully
indexed rate (the index plus the margin) was 1
percentage point or less over the initial interest
rate, indicating a reasonable likelihood that the
borrower could have qualified at the fully
indexed rate.
Loan must not negatively amortize. NEGAM: Specifies whether the loan had a
negative amortization feature.
Loans with a negative amortization feature did
not meet the requirement. Loans without this
feature met the requirement.
Loans must meet one of the following three requirements
Loan must have a fixed interest rate for
at least 5 years.
PROD_TYPE: Contains an indicator for
fixed-rate mortgages.
FIRST_RATE: Indicates the length of the
initial fixed-rate period (in months) for
ARMs.
For ARMs, if the length of the initial fixed-rate
period was shorter than 60 months, the loan
did not meet the requirement. All other ARMs
and fixed-rate mortgages met the requirement.
Loan meets a debt-service-to-income
(DTI) ratio to be established in
regulation.
UNDER_RAT 1: Represents the borrower’s
total monthly debt service payments
divided by monthly gross income.
For purposes of our analysis, we assumed that
if the DTI ratio was 41 percent or less, the loan
met the requirement. The 41 percent ratio
serves as a guideline in underwriting
mortgages insured by the Federal Housing
Administration (FHA).
Our analysis of this requirement only included
loans for which DTI information was available.
About 37 percent of the loans in the LP data
did not have information on the DTI ratio.
Variable rate loans must have an
Annual Percentage Rate (APR) less
than 3 percentage points over a
generally accepted interest rate index.
INIT_RATE: Initial or original interest rate
as of the loan’s first payment date.
The LP data did not include APRs, so we
developed a proxy that compared the initial
interest rate on the loan to the relevant interest
rate index. For short-term hybrid ARMs (e.g.,
2/28 and 3/27 mortgages), we used the
Treasury 2-year constant maturity rate. For
longer-term ARMs, we used the Treasury 5-
year constant maturity rate.
When the difference between the initial interest
rate and the relevant interest rate index was
less than 3 percentage points, we assumed
that the loan met the requirement.
Source: GAO.
To compare the demographic characteristics (e.g., race, ethnicity, and
income level) of safe harbor and nonsafe harbor loans, we incorporated
Page 47 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix I: Objectives, Scope, and
Methodology
data from the Census Bureau. More specifically, whenever possible, we
linked the zip code for each loan reported in the LP data to an associated
census tract in a metropolitan statistical area (MSA).
3
We grouped the zip
codes according to the percentage of households that Census identified as
black or African-American and Hispanic or Latino. The groupings in our
analysis were: (1) less than 5 percent, (2) 5 to 24 percent, (3) 25 to 74
percent, and (4) 75 percent or greater of household populations. We also
grouped zip codes according to the median income of the MSA of a given
zip code. The specific groupings in our analysis were low-, moderate-, and
upper-income zip codes, defined as those with median incomes that were
less than 80 percent, at least 80 percent but less than 120 percent, and 120
percent and above, respectively, of the median income for the associated
MSA.
To analyze nonsafe harbor loans by borrower credit score, we used the
FICO scores in the LP database. FICO scores, generally based on software
developed Fair, Isaac and Company, are a numerical indicator of a
borrower’s creditworthiness. The scores range from 300 to 850, with
higher scores indicating a better credit history. For our analysis, we used 4
ranges of scores: 599 and below, 600 to 659, 660 to 719, and 720 and above.
To examine factors affecting the performance of nonprime loans, we
developed an econometric model to estimate the relationship between
variables associated with the safe harbor requirements, as well as other
variables, and the probability of a loan defaulting within 24 months of
origination. We developed the model using data on mortgages originated
from 2000 through 2006 (the latest year for which we could examine 24-
month performance). Detailed information about our model and our
estimation results are presented in appendix II.
Research on State and
Local Anti-Predatory
Lending Laws and Views of
Mortgage Industry
Stakeholders
To describe relevant research on the bill’s potential effect on the mortgage
market, we identified and reviewed empirical studies on the impact of
state and local anti-predatory lending laws on key nonprime mortgage
indicators, such as subprime mortgage originations and the cost of credit.
While we identified a number of such studies, we narrowed our scope to
eight studies that used control groups (e.g., comparison states without
3
We used the Census 2000 data for our analysis. We were able to link race and ethnicity
information for about 98 percent of the loans and income information for about 89 percent
of the loans.
Page 48 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix I: Objectives, Scope, and
Methodology
anti-predatory lending laws) or statistical techniques that controlled for
factors other than the laws that could affect lending patterns. The studies
we reviewed fell into two broad categories: three studies that focused
solely on North Carolina’s 1999 anti-predatory lending law and five that
examined laws in multiple states and localities. In general, the researchers
measured the effects of the laws in terms of the volume of subprime
originations, the probability of originating a subprime loan, or the
probability of originating a loan with predatory characteristics. Our review
of these eight studies included an examination of the methodologies used,
the data and time periods used, the limitations of the studies, and the
conclusions. We also interviewed selected authors to ensure that we
interpreted their results correctly and to obtain their views on whether the
results from their studies might apply to the potential impact of the bill on
the mortgage market.
To obtain the views of mortgage industry stakeholders, we reviewed
written statements and congressional testimony about the bill by officials
from the federal banking regulatory agencies and organizations
representing mortgage lenders, mortgage brokers, securitizers, and
consumer interests. We also interviewed officials from a number of these
organizations, including the Mortgage Bankers Association, American
Securitization Forum, American Financial Services Association, American
Bankers Association, Independent Community Bankers of America,
National Association of Mortgage Brokers, Center for Responsible
Lending, National Community Reinvestment Coalition, National Consumer
Law Center, Neighborhood Association of Consumer Advocates, and
Consumer Federation of America. In addition, we interviewed officials
from a large mortgage lender and a major investment bank involved in the
securitization of mortgages. Finally, we interviewed officials from the
federal banking regulatory agencies, the Department of Housing and
Urban Development (HUD), the Federal Trade Commission (FTC), and the
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC).
We conducted this performance audit from March 2008 to July 2009, in
accordance with generally accepted government auditing standards. Those
standards require that we plan and perform the audit to obtain sufficient,
appropriate evidence to provide a reasonable basis for our findings and
conclusions based on our audit objectives. We believe that the evidence
obtained provides a reasonable basis for our findings and conclusions
based on our audit objectives.
Page 49 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix II: Description of the Econometric
Analysis of Safe Harbor Requirements
Appendix II: Description of the Econometric
Analysis of Safe Harbor Requirements
This appendix describes the econometric model we developed to examine
the relationship between variables associated with the bill’s safe harbor
requirements, as well as other variables, and the probability of a loan
entering default. Safe harbor requirements include features related to
documentation of borrower income and assets, limits on debt-service-to–
income (DTI) ratios, the duration before which any interest rate
adjustments may occur, limits on the relationship between a loan’s annual
percentage rate and other prevailing interest rates at origination, and
prohibitions on mortgages that allow negative amortization. The safe
harbor requirements limit features that may increase the risk of default,
but they may also restrict the number and types of mortgages lenders are
willing to originate. Since the requirements were not in effect during the
recent past, we do not know in what ways lenders and securitizers may
have responded to their introduction. Therefore, we characterize our
evaluation as an assessment of whether mortgages with safe harbor
characteristics performed better than those without them, as opposed to
an assessment of the effects of the introduction of a safe harbor. Our
investigation focused on a recent set of nonprime mortgages and
controlled for a variety of loan, borrower, and housing market conditions
that are likely to affect mortgage performance.
To do this work, we analyzed a 2 percent random sample of securitized
nonprime loans originated from 2000 through 2006 from
LoanPerformance’s (LP) Asset-backed Securities database. Our sample
was comprised of the approximately 92 percent of loans for which the
associated property was located in an area covered by the Federal
Housing Finance Agency’s house price indexes for metropolitan areas. The
LP database has been used extensively by regulators and others to
examine the characteristics and performance of nonprime loans. The
database provides information on loan characteristics, from which we
developed variables that indicated or measured relevant safe harbor
requirements. We determined the status of each loan 24 months after the
month of first payment. We used loan performance history through the
end of December 2008. We defined a loan as being in default if it was
delinquent by at least 90 days, in the foreclosure process (including loans
identified as in real-estate-owned status), paid off after being 90-days
delinquent or in foreclosure, or had already terminated with evidence of a
loss.
We categorized loans as follows: short-term hybrid adjustable rate
mortgages (ARM) (essentially 2/28 and 3/27 mortgages), fixed-rate
mortgages, payment-option ARMs, and other longer-term ARMs (i.e.,
ARMs with 5-, 7-, and 10-year fixed-rate periods). We included only first-
Page 50 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix II: Description of the Econometric
Analysis of Safe Harbor Requirements
lien loans for which the borrower is identified as an owner-occupant, and
we estimated default probabilities for purchase money loans separately
from loans for refinancing except for payment-option ARMs, for which we
examined purchase and refinancing loans together. Our primary reason for
examining performance by mortgage type is that borrower incentives and
motivations may vary for loans with different characteristics. For example,
short-term hybrid ARMs provide a strong incentive for a borrower to exit
from a mortgage by the time the interest rate begins to reset.
We estimated separate default models for each mortgage type, although
the general underlying structure of the models was similar. We used a
logistic regression model to explain the probability of loan default, based
on the observed pattern of actual defaults and the values of safe harbor
variables and a subset of other variables known to be associated with loan
performance (see table 8). Many loan and borrower characteristics are
likely to influence the status of a mortgage over time. Some factors
describe conditions at the time of mortgage origination, such as the loan-
to-value (LTV) ratio and the borrower’s credit score. Other important
factors may change over time, sometimes dramatically, without being
observed by a lender, loan servicer, or researcher. For instance, an
individual household’s income may change due to job loss, increasing the
probability of default. Other conditions vary over time in ways that can be
observed, or at least approximated. For example, greater house price
appreciation (HPA) contributes to greater housing equity, thus reducing
the probability that a borrower, if facing financial distress, views
defaulting on a loan as a better option than prepaying. We focused on
whether a loan defaulted within 24 months as our measure of performance
because a large proportion of nonprime borrowers had hybrid ARMs and
prepaid their loans (e.g., by refinancing) within 2 years. Using a 24-month
time frame allowed us to include these loans in our model, as well as loans
originated in 2006, a year in which many nonprime loans were originated.
Table 8: Variables Used in the Model
Variable Variable description
Mortgage default
(dependent variable)
1 if the mortgage was in default by 24 months, 0 otherwise. We defined a loan as in default if it was
delinquent by at least 90 days, in the foreclosure process (including loans identified as in real-estate-
owned status), paid off after being 90-days delinquent or in foreclosure, or had already terminated with
evidence of a loss.
Origination year indicator 1 if the mortgage was originated in 2000, 0 otherwise
1 if the mortgage was originated in 2001, 0 otherwise
1 if the mortgage was originated in 2002, 0 otherwise
Page 51 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix II: Description of the Econometric
Analysis of Safe Harbor Requirements
Variable Variable description
1 if the mortgage was originated in 2003, 0 otherwise
1 if the mortgage was originated in 2005, 0 otherwise
1 if the mortgage was originated in 2006, 0 otherwise
Combined LTV ratio Defined as a continuous variable. Represents the amount of the mortgage and any associated second
lien divided by the house value. The LP data do not capture all second liens. As a result, the combined
LTV ratios are likely understated for some loans.
FICO score Defined as a continuous variable for payment-option ARMs.
For other mortgage types, defined as a set of continuous variables split into low, middle, and high ranges.
Specifically, for short-term hybrid ARMs and fixed-rate mortgages, the low FICO range was either 600 or
the FICO score itself if the FICO score was below 600; the middle range varied between 0 and 60, with a
minimum of 0 if the FICO score was below 600, a maximum of 60 if the FICO score was above 660, and
between 0 and 60 if the FICO was between 600 and 660; and the high range was 0 for FICO scores
below 660 and the difference between the FICO score and 660 for FICO scores above 660. Because Alt-
A borrowers generally had higher credit scores, the range boundaries for longer-term ARMs were 660 and
720, rather than 600 and 660.
House price appreciation Defined using the Federal Housing Finance Agency’s metropolitan house price indexes and split into two
time periods: one measuring appreciation during the first four quarters after origination and the second
measuring appreciation during the second four quarters after origination. We assigned each loan to a
metropolitan area using the property zip code information in the LP database and data that relates zip
codes to Core-based Statistical Areas.
Full documentation of
borrower income and
assets
1 if full documentation, 0 otherwise
Negative amortization
feature
1 if allows negative amortization, 0 otherwise
Meets fully indexed proxy 1 if the fully indexed rate is 1 percentage point or less over the initial rate, 0 otherwise. Only used for
ARMs.
DTI ratio Defined as a continuous variable. Represented the borrower’s total monthly debt service payments
divided by monthly gross income.
Spread over relevant
interest rate index
Defined as a continuous variable. Represented the difference between a loan’s initial interest rate and the
relevant Treasury rate at the time of origination. For short-term hybrid ARMs, we used the 2-year
Treasury constant maturity rate, for fixed-rate mortgages we used the 10-year Treasury constant maturity
rate, and for payment-option and longer-term ARMs, we used the 5-year Treasury constant maturity rate.
Interest-only loan 1 if loan type indicated interest-only feature, 0 otherwise
Source: GAO.
Note: In the case of longer-term ARMs and fixed-rate mortgages, we also included indicator variables
for whether the loan was securitized in a subprime or Alt-A pool because these mortgage types
appear in substantial numbers in both types of pools. In contrast, payment-option ARMs were almost
entirely found in Alt-A pools, and short-term hybrid ARMs were substantially found in subprime pools.
In the case of longer-term ARMs, we included indicator variables for loans with 7- and 10-year fixed-
rate periods. In the case of payment-option ARMs, we included an indicator variable for whether the
loan was a purchase or refinance loan.
For reasons described below, some of the variables associated with the
safe harbor requirements are included in all four models, while others are
only included in certain models:
Page 52 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix II: Description of the Econometric
Analysis of Safe Harbor Requirements
Full documentation of borrower income and assets: This variable is in all
four models.
Negative amortization feature: This variable is only in the model for
longer-term ARMs. We did not include it in the models for the other
mortgage types because the negative amortization feature was essentially
never present (in the case of fixed-rate mortgages and short-term hybrid
ARMs) or was essentially always present (in the case of payment-option
ARMs). The lack of variation within these mortgage types made estimating
the marginal effects of the negative amortization variable problematic.
Fully indexed proxy: This variable is in three of the models, but we do not
include it in the model for fixed-rate mortgages because it is only relevant
to loans with adjustable interest rates.
DTI ratio: In the context of the bill’s safe harbor requirements, this
variable would only apply to short-term hybrid ARMs and payment-option
ARMs. However, we include it in all four models because the DTI ratio is
an important measure of the borrower’s ability to repay.
Spread over relevant interest rate index: In the context of the bill’s safe
harbor requirements, this variable would only apply to short-term hybrid
ARMs.
1
However, we include it in all four models because loans with
higher interest rates may be at greater risk of default due to their higher
monthly payments.
Tables 9 through 12 provide information on the number of loans and mean
values for each of the mortgage types for which we estimated default
probabilities. Short-term hybrid ARMs were the most prevalent type of
mortgage, and refinance loans were more prevalent than purchase loans.
In addition, more loans were originated in the later portion of the time
period we examined than the earlier portion. Default rates were highest
for short-term hybrid ARMs, lower for loans originated in the middle years
of the time period and higher for purchase loans than for refinance loans.
1
As discussed earlier, this variable is one of three requirements in the bill’s interest rate and
debt burden requirements. Under the bill, safe harbor mortgages would only have to meet
one of the three requirements. As a result, the “spread” requirement would not apply to
fixed-rate mortgages and longer-term ARMs because they would meet the requirement that
a loan have a fixed interest rate for at least 5 years. The spread requirement would also not
apply to payment-option ARMs because they typically fail to meet the safe harbor
requirement that loans not contain a negative amortization feature.
Page 53 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix II: Description of the Econometric
Analysis of Safe Harbor Requirements
Table 9: Mean Values for Short-term Hybrid ARMs with DTI Information
Purchase
loans
Refinance
loans
Number of observations 33,985 45,622
Mortgage in default by 24 months 0.208 0.146
Mortgage originated in 2000 0.027 0.029
Mortgage originated in 2001 0.034 0.049
Mortgage originated in 2002 0.051 0.081
Mortgage originated in 2003 0.100 0.142
Mortgage originated in 2005 0.303 0.256
Mortgage originated in 2006 0.257 0.205
Combined LTV ratio 93.008 80.292
DTI ratio 41.358 40.104
FICO score
Low range 592.302 573.569
Middle range 33.245 15.665
High range 13.821 3.654
HPA: First four quarters after origination 1.095 1.098
HPA: Second four quarters after origination 1.033 1.044
Full documentation 0.545 0.658
Meets fully indexed proxy 0.374 0.446
Spread over 2-year Treasury constant maturity rate 4.174 4.663
Interest-only loan 0.254 0.118
Source: GAO analysis of LP data.
Table 10: Mean Values for Fixed-rate mortgages with DTI Information
Purchase
loans
Refinance
loans
Number of observations 7,566 23,858
Mortgage in default by 24 months 0.104 0.074
Mortgage originated in 2000 0.053 0.042
Mortgage originated in 2001 0.069 0.065
Mortgage originated in 2002 0.077 0.092
Mortgage originated in 2003 0.128 0.194
Mortgage originated in 2005 0.221 0.196
Page 54 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix II: Description of the Econometric
Analysis of Safe Harbor Requirements
Purchase
loans
Refinance
loans
Mortgage originated in 2006 0.278 0.202
Mortgage in subprime pool 0.547 0.854
Combined LTV ratio 90.427 75.599
DTI ratio 38.691 38.550
FICO score
Low range 595.235 587.043
Middle range 43.275 30.122
High range 32.693 14.220
HPA: First four quarters after origination 1.085 1.098
HPA: Second four quarters after origination 1.049 1.059
Full documentation 0.567 0.701
Spread over 10-year Treasury constant maturity rate 3.121 3.234
Interest-only loan 0.135 0.045
Source: GAO analysis of LP data.
Table 11: Mean Values for Longer-term ARMs with DTI Information
Purchase
loans
Refinance
loans
Number of observations 5,764 4,211
Mortgage in default by 24 months 0.129 0.082
Mortgage originated in 2000 0.005 0.005
Mortgage originated in 2001 0.005 0.013
Mortgage originated in 2002 0.018 0.035
Mortgage originated in 2003 0.053 0.084
Mortgage originated in 2005 0.317 0.278
Mortgage originated in 2006 0.433 0.427
Mortgage in a subprime pool 0.118 0.256
Initial rate fixed for 7 years 0.090 0.080
Initial rate fixed for 10 years 0.105 0.112
Combined LTV ratio 93.174 78.229
DTI ratio 38.549 37.527
FICO score
Low range 656.300 647.370
Middle range 38.551 28.142
High range 15.246 9.465
HPA: First four quarters after origination 1.074 1.067
Page 55 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix II: Description of the Econometric
Analysis of Safe Harbor Requirements
Purchase
loans
Refinance
loans
HPA: Second four quarters after origination 0.980 0.984
Full documentation 0.371 0.437
Meets fully indexed proxy 0.726 0.615
Spread over 5-year Treasury constant maturity rate 2.131 2.183
Negative amortization feature 0.027 0.059
Interest-only loan 0.797 0.669
Source: GAO analysis of LP data.
Table 12: Mean Values for Payment-option ARMs with DTI Information
Number of observations 6,623
Mortgage in default by 24 months 0.100
Mortgage originated in 2003 0.018
Mortgage originated in 2005 0.368
Mortgage originated in 2006 0.474
Purchase loan 0.262
Combined LTV ratio 78.716
DTI ratio 34.771
FICO score 702.505
HPA: First four quarters after origination 1.062
HPA: Second four quarters after origination 0.941
Full documentation 0.160
Meets fully indexed proxy 0.045
Spread over 5-year Treasury constant maturity rate 2.193
Source: GAO analysis of LP data.
The results of our analysis are presented in tables 13 through 16. We ran
seven regressions: separate purchase loan and refinance loan regressions
for three of the product types (short-term hybrid ARMs, fixed-rate
mortgages, and longer-term ARMs) and a single regression combining
purchase and refinance loans for payment-option ARMs.
2
For this set of
regressions, we only included the 63 percent of loans for which DTI
2
For our analysis of payment-option ARMs, we combined purchase and refinance loans and
limited our analysis to mortgages originated from 2003 through 2006 because the
proportion of purchase loans was relatively small and very few payment-option ARMs were
made prior to 2003.
Page 56 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix II: Description of the Econometric
Analysis of Safe Harbor Requirements
information was available. We also ran a second set of regressions that
used all of the loans for each mortgage type and binary variables
indicating DTI ranges, including categories for missing information. We
found that the results were very similar to those for the first set of
regressions. We presented coefficient estimates, as well as a
transformation of the coefficients into a form that can be interpreted as
the marginal effect of each variable on the estimated probability of default.
This marginal effect is the calculation of the change in the estimated
probability of default that would result if a variable’s standard deviation
were added to that variable’s mean value, while all other variables are held
at their mean values. This permits a comparison of the impact of different
variables within and across mortgage types. In general, combined LTV
ratio, HPA, and FICO score had substantial marginal effects across
different mortgage types and loan purposes. Specifically, higher LTV
ratios, lower HPA, and lower FICO scores were associated with higher
likelihoods of default. The observed effects for DTI ratio were relatively
small. Among safe harbor characteristics, documentation of borrower
income and assets and a loan’s spread over the applicable Treasury rate
had substantial marginal effects. Less than full documentation and higher
spreads were associated with higher default probabilities.
Our results for full documentation of borrower income and assets were
not sensitive to alternative specifications. Including the loan amount as an
additional variable, adding or substituting different interest rates, and
changing the form in which house price appreciation or FICO scores
entered the model all had no effect on our general conclusion that the
presence of full documentation was strongly associated with lowering the
probability of default. Our conclusion concerning high cost loans—that
larger spreads over specified Treasury rates at the time of origination are
associated with increased default probability—is somewhat more
nuanced. In some respects, the spread variable is capturing something
about the effect of higher interest rates generally. For example, alternative
specifications which substituted the initial interest rate or the Treasury
rate for the spread variable yielded similar results. However, when the
Treasury rate and the spread variables are included in the model, both
variables are significant and have large marginal effects.
As an alternative specification for short-term hybrid ARMs, we included a
variable indicating whether each mortgage was a safe harbor or a non-safe
harbor loan, in contrast to including variables for separate safe harbor
requirements. We found that this variable had a small marginal effect,
most likely because many non-safe harbor loans met some of the safe
harbor requirements. In particular, a substantial percentage of non-safe
Page 57 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix II: Description of the Econometric
Analysis of Safe Harbor Requirements
harbor loans had full documentation of borrower income and assets but
failed to meet other safe harbor requirements.
3
Table 13: Estimation Results for Short-term Hybrid ARMs with DTI Information
Purchase loans Refinance loans
Number of observations 39,985 45,622
Coefficient Significance
Marginal
effect Coefficient Significance
Marginal
effect
Intercept 7.74 *** 3.83 ***
Mortgage originated in
2000 0.57 *** 1.32 1.10 *** 2.00
2001 0.27 *** 0.67 0.50 *** 1.11
2002 -0.05 -0.16 -0.01 -0.03
2003 0.18 * 0.75 -0.08 -0.29
2005 0.27 *** 1.75 0.25 *** 1.12
2006 0.75 *** 4.96 0.81 *** 3.71
Combined LTV 0.02 *** 2.27 0.03 *** 4.24
FICO Low range -0.01 *** -1.21 -0.01 *** -1.18
FICO Middle range -0.01 *** -2.37 -0.01 *** -0.83
FICO High range -0.01 *** -2.00 -0.01 *** -0.90
HPA: First four quarters -3.54 *** -4.06 -3.89 *** -3.10
HPA: Second four quarters -4.74 *** -6.05 -3.02 *** -2.92
DTI ratio 0.01 *** 0.94 0.01 *** 1.22
Full documentation -0.39 *** -2.50 -0.44 *** -1.94
Meets fully indexed proxy -0.08 * -0.54 0.01 0.03
Spread over 2-year Treasury
constant maturity rate
0.15 *** 3.09 0.24 *** 4.36
Interest-only loan 0.04 0.24 0.07 0.23
Source: GAO analysis of LP data.
Note: *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels,
respectively.
3
This alternative specification was not well suited for other mortgage types. For payment-
option ARMs, almost no loans were safe harbor loans because of the prevalence of the
negative amortization feature. For fixed-rate mortgages, a safe harbor loan was identical to
a loan that met the full documentation requirement because the fully indexed rate
condition did not apply and these loans were fixed for an initial term of at least 5 years.
Similarly, for longer-term ARMs, initial terms were fixed for at least 5 years, and, as a
practical matter, about two-thirds of these loans met our fully indexed rate proxy, thus,
making a single safe harbor test similar to a full documentation test.
Page 58 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix II: Description of the Econometric
Analysis of Safe Harbor Requirements
Table 14: Estimation Results for Fixed-rate Mortgages with DTI Information
Purchase loans Refinance loans
Number of observations 7,566 23,858
Coefficient Significance
Marginal
effect Coefficient Significance
Marginal
effect
Intercept 3.84 ** 4.57 ***
Mortgage originated in
2000 0.28 0.38 0.77 *** 0.76
2001 0.35 0.54 0.41 *** 0.48
2002 0.22 0.36 0.20 0.27
2003 0.23 0.47 -0.15 -0.27
2005 -0.02 -0.04 0.03 0.05
2006 0.44 *** 1.27 0.35 *** 0.69
Combined LTV 0.03 *** 0.97 -0.04 -0.07
FICO Low range 0.00 * -0.39 -0.01 *** -0.59
FICO Middle range -0.01 *** -1.42 -0.01 *** -0.65
FICO High range -0.01 *** -1.67 -0.01 *** -0.72
HPA: First four quarters -1.88 * -0.87 -3.82 *** -1.33
HPA: Second four quarters -4.92 *** -2.47 -2.55 *** -1.12
DTI ratio 0.01 ** 0.57 0.01 *** 0.61
Full documentation -0.73 *** -1.85 -0.37 *** -0.71
Spread over 10-year
Treasury constant maturity
rate
0.26 *** 2.40 0.25 *** 1.82
Interest-only loan 0.26 ** 0.56 0.27 ** 0.26
Source: GAO analysis of LP data.
Note: *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels,
respectively.
Page 59 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix II: Description of the Econometric
Analysis of Safe Harbor Requirements
Table 15: Estimation Results for Longer-term ARMs with DTI Information
Purchase loans Refinance loans
Number of observations 5,764 4,211
Coefficient Significance
Marginal
effect Coefficient Significance
Marginal
effect
Intercept 1.74 4.51 **
Mortgage originated in
2000 0.97 0.38 1.92 *** 0.48
2001 2.01 *** 0.84 0.79 0.31
2002 -0.63 -0.46 0.22 0.14
2003 1.54 *** 2.28 0.77 * 0.79
2005 0.46 1.32 0.06 0.08
2006 1.23 *** 4.54 0.98 *** 2.02
Mortgage in subprime pool -0.10 -0.18 -0.03 -0.44
Initial rate fixed for 7 years -0.15 -0.24 -0.02 -0.02
Initial rate fixed for 10 years -0.29 * -0.48 -0.46 * -0.45
Combined LTV 0.05 *** 3.31 0.06 *** 4.12
FICO Low range 0.00 -0.34 -0.01 *** -0.75
FICO Middle range 0.00 -0.38 -0.01 *** -0.70
FICO High range -0.01 *** -1.69 -0.01 -0.32
HPA: First four quarters -2.29 ** -1.21 -3.78 ** -1.08
HPA: Second four quarters -4.94 *** -2.69 -3.10 *** -1.13
DTI ratio 0.02 *** 1.10 0.01 0.30
Full documentation -0.92 *** -2.08 -0.86 *** -1.16
Meets fully indexed proxy 0.05 0.13 -0.11 -0.17
Negative amortization feature 0.77 *** 0.74 0.40 * 0.32
Spread over 5-year Treasury
constant maturity rate
0.42 *** 2.28 0.19 *** 0.84
Interest-only loan -0.21 * -0.46 0.15 0.24
Source: GAO analysis of LP data.
Note: *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels,
respectively.
Page 60 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix II: Description of the Econometric
Analysis of Safe Harbor Requirements
Table 16: Estimation Results for Payment-option ARMs with DTI Information
All loans
Number of observations 6,623
Coefficient Significance Marginal effect
Intercept 0.96
Mortgage originated in
2003 1.25 0.64
2005 0.35 0.64
2006 0.86 * 1.87
Purchase loan -0.11 -0.16
Combined LTV 0.08 *** 6.33
FICO score -0.01 *** -1.20
HPA: First four quarters -2.75 ** -0.89
HPA: Second four quarters -3.58 *** -1.22
DTI ratio 0.00 0.05
Full documentation -0.70 *** -0.81
Meets fully indexed proxy -0.06 -0.05
Spread over 5-year Treasury constant maturity rate 0.48 *** 1.97
Source: GAO analysis of LP data.
Note: *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels,
respectively.
Page 61 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix III: Comments from the National
Credit Union Administration
Appendix III: Comments from the National
Credit Union Administration
Page 62 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
Appendix IV: GAO Contact and Staff
Acknowledgments
Appendix IV: GAO Contact and Staff
Acknowledgments
William B. Shear, (202) 512-8678, [email protected]
In addition to the individual named above, Steve Westley, Assistant
Director; Bill Bates; Stephen Brown; Emily Chalmers; Rudy Chatlos;
Randy Fasnacht; Tom McCool; John McGrail; Mark Metcalfe; Rachel
Munn; Susan Offutt; Jasminee Persaud; José R. Peña; Scott Purdy; and Jim
Vitarello made key contributions to this report.
Page 63 GAO-09-741 Impact of Mortgage Reform
GAO Contact
Staff
Acknowledgments
(250399)
GAO’s Mission
The Government Accountability Office, the audit, evaluation, and
investigative arm of Congress, exists to support Congress in meeting its
constitutional responsibilities and to help improve the performance and
accountability of the federal government for the American people. GAO
examines the use of public funds; evaluates federal programs and policies;
and provides analyses, recommendations, and other assistance to help
Congress make informed oversight, policy, and funding decisions. GAO’s
commitment to good government is reflected in its core values of
accountability, integrity, and reliability.
The fastest and easiest way to obtain copies of GAO documents at no cost
is through GAO’s Web site (www.gao.gov). Each weekday afternoon, GAO
posts on its Web site newly released reports, testimony, and
correspondence. To have GAO e-mail you a list of newly posted products,
go to www.gao.gov and select “E-mail Updates.”
Obtaining Copies of
GAO Reports and
Testimony
Order by Phone
The price of each GAO publication reflects GAO’s actual cost of
production and distribution and depends on the number of pages in the
publication and whether the publication is printed in color or black and
white. Pricing and ordering information is posted on GAO’s Web site,
http://www.gao.gov/ordering.htm.
Place orders by calling (202) 512-6000, toll free (866) 801-7077, or
TDD (202) 512-2537.
Orders may be paid for using American Express, Discover Card,
MasterCard, Visa, check, or money order. Call for additional information.
Contact:
Web site: www.gao.gov/fraudnet/fraudnet.htm
Automated answering system: (800) 424-5454 or (202) 512-7470
Ralph Dawn, Managing Director, [email protected], (202) 512-4400
U.S. Government Accountability Office, 441 G Street NW, Room 7125
Washington, DC 20548
To Report Fraud,
Waste, and Abuse in
Federal Programs
Congressional
Relations
Chuck Young, Managing Director, youngc1@gao.gov, (202) 512-4800
U.S. Government Accountability Office, 441 G Street NW, Room 7149
Washington, DC 20548
Public Affairs
Please Print on Recycled Paper