External author:
Wolf Heinrich REUTER
Benefits and
drawbacks of an
expenditure rule”, as
well as of a "golden
rule", in the EU fiscal
framework
Euro Area Scrutiny
STUDY
Requested by the ECON committee
EN
Economic Governance Support Unit (EGOV)
Directorate-General for Internal Policies
PE 645.732- September 2020
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
2 PE 645.732
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 3
Abstract
Focusing the EU fiscal framework on an expenditure rule could
help to increase transparency, compliance and ownership. In
various other respects, like estimation errors or counter-
cyclicality of prescribed fiscal policy, an expenditure rule is similar
to a structural balance rule.
If the EU decides to go beyond the current focus on fiscal
aggregates, a two-rule system aimed at safeguarding specific
expenditures could be placed at the centre of the EU fiscal
framework. The key challenge is to define and measure the
protected expenditures.
Benefits and
drawbacks of an
expenditure rule”, as
well as of a "golden
rule", in the EU fiscal
framework
Euro Area Scrutiny
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
4 PE 645.732
This document was requested by the European Parliament's Committee on Economic and Monetary
Affairs.
AUTHORS
Wolf Heinrich REUTER
Staff of the German Council of Economic Experts*
* This paper reflects the personal views of the author and not necessarily those of the German Council of
Economic Experts. The author would like to thank Patricia Bucher and Paul Mannschreck for their research
assistance as well as Mustafa Yeter for the very helpful detailed comments on drafts of the paper.
ADMINISTRATOR RESPONSIBLE
Jost ANGERER
EDITORIAL ASSISTANT
Donella BOLDI
LINGUISTIC VERSIONS
Original: EN
ABOUT THE EDITOR
The Economic Governance Support Unit provides inhouse and external expertise to support EP
committees and other parliamentary bodies in shaping legislation and exercising democratic scrutiny
over EU internal policies.
To contact the Economic Governance Support Unit or to subscribe to its newsletter please write to:
Economic Governance Support Unit
European Parliament
B-1047 Brussels
Email: egov@ep.europa.eu
Manuscript completed in August 2020
© European Union, 2020
This document and other supporting analyses are available on the internet at:
http://www.europarl.europa.eu/supporting-analyses
DISCLAIMER AND COPYRIGHT
The opinions expressed in this document are the sole responsibility of the author- and do not necessarily
represent the official position of the European Parliament.
Reproduction and translation for non-commercial purposes are authorised, provided the source is
acknowledged and the European Parliament is given prior notice and sent a copy.
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 5
CONTENTS
LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS 6
LIST OF FIGURES 7
LIST OF TABLES 7
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 8
1. INTRODUCTION 9
2. TYPES OF FISCAL RU LES 9
2.1. Budget Balance, Structural Balance and Expenditure Rules 9
2.1.1. Cyclically-Adjusted Expenditures and Revenues 9
2.1.2. Budget Balance or Deficit Rules 10
2.1.3. Cyclically-Adjusted or Structural Balance Rules 10
2.1.4. Expenditure Rules 11
2.2. Golden Rules and Exceptions 12
2.2.1. Expenditure Categories Worth Protecting 12
2.2.2. Relationship with Fiscal Rules 13
3. EXPERIENCE WITH THE CURRENT EU FISCAL FRAMEWORK 14
3.1. Current Fiscal Rules at the European Level 14
3.2. Forecast and Real-Time Errors 15
3.2.1. Mean Absolute Errors 17
3.2.2. Mean Errors 18
3.2.3. Other Forecast and Estimation Errors 19
3.3. Exceptions and Compliance 19
3.4. Composition of Public Expenditures 21
3.5. Pro-Cyclicality of the Current Framework 22
4. FOCUSING THE EU FRAMEWORK ON AN EXPENDITURE RULE 23
4.1. Proposals for Expenditure Rules 23
4.2. Assessment of Rule Performance Based on Past Data 25
4.3. Calibration 26
5. CONVERTING AN EU FISCAL RULE INTO A GOLDEN RU LE 27
5.1. Proposals for Safeguarding Specific Expenditure Categories 27
5.2. Limits Set by Golden Rules 30
6. CONCLUSIONS 31
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
6 PE 645.732
REFERENCES 32
ANNEX 36
6.1. Formal Description of Cyclically-Adjusted Balance and Expenditure Rules 36
6.2. Additional Details on Composition of Public Expenditures in the EU 36
6.2.1. Development of Specific Expenditure Categories 36
6.2.2. Specific Expenditure Categories during Fiscal Consolidations 40
6.3. Forecast Errors based on AMECO Vintages 41
6.4. Calculation of past growth rates of cyclically-adjusted revenue, potential GDP and
expenditures 42
6.5. Additional results regarding forecast and real-time estimation errors 46
LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS
AMECO
European Commission’s annual macro-economic database
EDP
Excessive deficit procedure
EU
European Union
EU15
15 Member States of the EU (Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany,
Greece, Italy, Ireland, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, United
Kingdom)
GDP
Gross domestic product
IMF
International Monetary Fund
MTO
Medium-term objective
OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
OG
Output gap
R&D
Research and development
SGP
Stability and Growth Pact
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 7
LIST OF FIGURES
Figure 1: Main variables necessary for evaluating compliance with EU fiscal rules 16
Figure 2: Mean (absolute) errors of forecasts and real-time estimates (EU15, 2005-2015) 17
Figure 3: Number and average size of exceptions granted between 2012 and 2018 20
Figure 4: Public investment and education expenditures in the EU15 from 1995 to 2019 21
Figure 5: Comparison of limits set for expenditure growth with observed fiscal policy (EU15) 25
Figure 6: Public investment expenditures in the EU15 from 1995 to 2019 37
Figure 7: Public investment expenditures in EU27 from 1995 to 2019 37
Figure 8: Public education expenditures in EU15 from 1995 to 2018 38
Figure 9: Public education expenditures in EU27 from 1995 to 2018 38
Figure 10: Public basic research and R&D expenditures in the EU15 from 2001 to 2018 39
Figure 11: Public basic research and R&D expenditures in EU25 from 2001 to 2018 39
Figure 12: Comparison of measures of potential GDP growth (forecast, real-time, ex-post) 44
Figure 13: Comparison of growth rates of different measures of public expenditure 45
LIST OF TABLES
Table 1: Differences between types of fiscal rules 12
Table 2: Comparison of expenditure rule proposals 24
Table 3: Comparison of proposals related to a ‘Golden Rule’ in the context of the EU fiscal framework29
Table 4: Fiscal consolidations and specific public expenditure categories 41
Table 5: Mean absolute errors and mean errors of forecasts and real-time estimates 46
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
8 PE 645.732
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
This paper discusses two possible avenues for reforming the EU fiscal framework: focusing the framework
on an expenditure rule to reduce complexity, and introducing a Golden Rule to safeguard specific public
expenditures. An overarching challenge when reforming the EU fiscal framework is to increase
compliance with its fiscal rules. The best-designed rules are no good if they are not complied with or if
the leeway granted by these rules is not used where it would be advisable. A more transparent, more
predictable and less complex fiscal framework could make a significant contribution to enhancing
compliance and the role of fiscal rules. The most important lever is to increase national governments
ownership as well as the visibility of rules for politicians, the general public and the media.
Expenditure Rule
The benefits of expenditure rules are often discussed in comparison to observed fiscal policy, but not in
relation to other possible rules or rule designs. Because fiscal policy is often chosen not purely in line with
the limits set by fiscal rules, however, analysing observed fiscal policy to evaluate the current fiscal
framework might be misleading. For example, expenditure and structural balance rules per se would have
both prescribed a more counter-cyclical fiscal policy in the EU over the past few decades. Under the
current framework it appears to be not the rule design itself but, rather, political decisions outside the
scope of the fiscal rules, non-compliance with these rules, and accompanying regulations like the use of
exceptions that tended to foster pro-cyclical fiscal policy.
Expenditure rules are also similar to structural balance rules in various other respects. Like structural
balance rules, expenditure rules are associated with significant challenges when forecasting and
estimating the variables necessary for their operationalisation. These errors are substantial and biased in
the case of variables required to operationalise structural balance rules. They are smaller, although still
significant, and less biased, in the case of expenditures. However, the operationalisation of expenditure
rules also requires other variables, such as discretionary revenue measures, which involve cumbersome
estimates and are associated with a high degree of uncertainty.
The main advantages of expenditure rules are that the constrained variable is more directly controlled by
governments, it is more transparent and the ceiling set by the rule for fiscal policy is less volatile.
Golden Rule
This paper discusses options for converting a fiscal rule under the EU fiscal framework into a Golden Rule,
which would allow debt issuance to finance specific expenditure categories. There is a concern that needs
to be adressed first, which is that such a rule would go beyond the current focus of the EU fiscal framework
on fiscal aggregates and distinguishes between different expenditures in Member States.
The main challenge when introducing a Golden Rule is to clearly and narrowly define the deductible
expenditures. Ideally, each spending decision involves a cost-benefit analysis and a subsequent decision
to engage irrespective of the category it belongs to. One proposed workaround is to identify expenditure
categories which on average exhibit certain growth effects or future benefits. This identification, however,
can be very difficult in practice. Furthermore, governments need to be prevented from using ‘creative
accounting’ to shift other expenditures into the defined deductible categories.
Addressing the bias of politicians towards too low investment expenditures does not remove the bias
towards excessively high deficits in general. Furthermore, long-term fiscal sustainability still implies that
there is a limit to the amount of annual debt issuance, which, however, might be higher with a Golden
Rule. This suggests that a cap should be set on the amount of expenditures that is deductible, which
would result in a system of two rules: one setting a limit on total expenditures (deductible and non-
deductible) and a second one setting a lower limit on the non-deductible portion of expenditures.
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 9
1. INTRODUCTION
Ever since the European (Monetary) Union was launched, a framework for the surveillance and
coordination of its Member Statesfiscal policies has been in place. The aim behind the various types of
fiscal rules set under this framework is to ensure sustainable public finances of the Member States. This
framework has been reformed and amended in various stages over the years. Among academics,
policymakers and the general public, there has been an ongoing debate about the need for further
reforms to reduce complexity, enhance transparency, increase compliance with the rules, ensure
sustainable public finances, while supporting economic growth and stabilisation, and improve the quality
of public finances. The EU’s economic governance and fiscal framework have been under official review
since the beginning of this year.
Fiscal rules are introduced to counteract the deficit bias of politicians and governments. Empirical and
theoretical studies have shown that various politico-economic incentives tend to encourage
governments to run deficits which are higher than would be optimal (literature surveys e.g. in Feld, 2018;
Wyplosz, 2012). These incentives relate, among other things, to various interest groupsaccess to a
common budgetary resource (common pools´), political budget cycles and asymmetric information.
Spillover effects of high debt ratios also play a role in a monetary union. It has empirically been shown
that, in general, fiscal rules can curb the deficit bias and reduce deficits (e.g. Badinger and Reuter, 2015,
2017; Eyraud et al., 2018b; Heinemann et al., 2018; Caselli and Reynaud, 2020).
Despite having fiscal rules in place, however, fiscal policy in the EU has been pro-cyclical and debt levels
have not sharply decreased across Member States. Furthermore, (net) public investment ratios have not
increased considerably and fiscal rules are not complied with in many years. At the same time the fiscal
framework has become more comprehensive and complex. Against this background, this paper analyses
two prominently discussed reforms. First, the refocusing of the EU fiscal framework on one rule namely
an expenditure rule. Broadly, this rule would set a limit for expenditure growth which is related to
medium-term potential GDP growth. And, second, the conversion of an existing or reformed fiscal rule,
like an expenditure or structural balance rule, into a Golden Rule, which would allow debt issuance
specifically to finance particular expenditures that benefit current and, especially, future generations,
such as investment expenditures or expenditures to mitigate climate change.
Section 2 discusses the differences between various types of fiscal rules and the design of Golden Rules.
The current EU fiscal framework is presented in Section 3, which also investigates the implementation
and challenges associated with it, based on past data. Section 4 compares various proposals for a new
expenditure rule and Section 5 the proposals for Golden Rules. Section 6 concludes, and the Annexes
provide further details on calculations and methodology as well as additional figures and estimates.
2. TYPES OF FISCAL RULES
2.1. Budget Balance, Structural Balance and Expenditure Rules
2.1.1. Cyclically-Adjusted Expenditures and Revenues
To investigate the relationship between different types of fiscal rules, a distinction based on their
properties between different components of public revenues and expenditures is useful. Some sub-
components of public expenditures are directly linked to the position in the economic cycle. For example,
expenditures related to unemployment tend to be higher if the economy is in a downturn, as there are
more people unemployed, and they tend to be lower if the economy is in an upswing. While in some
countries other expenditure categories, such as old-age or other social security expenditures, are also
sensitive to the economic cycle (Christofzik et al., 2018), unemployment-related expenditures (EU28
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
10 PE 645.732
average: 3.1 per cent of total expenditures) are the main cyclical component of public expenditures
(European Commission, 2019a). Thus, the European Commission estimates cyclically-adjusted
expenditures as total public expenditures net of cyclical unemployment-related expenditures, where the
latter would be observed if the output gap were fully closed or, more intuitively, that would on average
materialise over the medium term, i.e. across the economic cycle.
Public revenues can also be split into sub-components which are sensitive to the economic cycle and
those which are not. In comparison with expenditures, a much larger portion of public revenues is
sensitive in this way, as tax revenues depend strongly on the level of activity by firms and households.
Thus, when estimating cyclically-adjusted revenues, the European Commission assumes only non-tax
revenues (EU28 average: 11.4 per cent of total revenues) to be independent of the economic cycle
(European Commission, 2019a). Again, cyclically-adjusted revenues correspond to the level of revenues
that would be observed if the output gap were fully closed, i.e. when GDP is at its potential.
2.1.2. Budget Balance or Deficit Rules
One of the most common types of fiscal rules worldwide is a budget balance or deficit rule. It sets a limit
on the gross budget balance, i.e. the difference between public revenues and public expenditures. Many
of the rules introduced at a fairly early stage, e.g. shortly after World War II, were such rules (Eyraud et al.,
2018b), with the 3 per cent deficit rule in the Maastricht Treaty being a prominent example. The
advantage of such a budget balance rule is that it is very simple and the variable constrained by the rule
the budget balance is directly observable. No adjustments or estimates are necessary. This is also why
forecasting the variables and compliance with the rule is typically easier for budget balance rules than for
other types of rule. Apart from the effects of the economic cycle on the cyclical components, governments
usually have fairly direct control over revenue and expenditure aggregates.
The main problem with this type of rule, however, is its pro-cyclicality. Governments often do not apply
the limit set by a budget balance rule as an upper bound, but rather as some kind of target (Reuter, 2015;
Caselli and Wingender, 2018). Rules are not complied with in a significant proportion of years.
Consequently, the constrained budget balance is often right at its limit in many yearseven those in
which economic conditions are benign. This allows no buffers or fiscal headroom for economically
challenging times. Applied in this way, budget balance rules can lead to pro-cyclical fiscal policy.
Downturns are usually accompanied by a cyclical reduction in revenues and a cyclical increase in
unemployment-related expenditures. To comply with such a rule, the government would therefore need
to pro-cyclically increase revenues or cut expenditures during downturns. During upturns, on the other
hand, the limit set by the rule is complied with more easily because revenues and budget balances tend
to increase in such cases. Governments, especially if they perceive rules as targets, are tempted to pro-
cyclically loosen fiscal policy at a time when they could build up fiscal buffers.
2.1.3. Cyclically-Adjusted or Structural Balance Rules
To address the pro-cyclicality, newer second-generationfiscal rules set a limit for the cyclically-adjusted
budget balance or structural balance (Eyraud et al., 2018b). The former represents the difference between
cyclically-adjusted revenues and cyclically-adjusted expenditures. It is the budget balance that would
theoretically be observed if the output gap were fully closed. The structural balance is the cyclically-
adjusted balance net of temporary one-off measures (European Commission, 2019a).
The advantage here is thatcompared with budget balance rulessuch a rule automatically permits
larger deficits in downturns and restricts fiscal policy more strongly during upturns. The portions of
revenues and expenditures that automatically change together with the economic cycle (automatic
stabilisers) are not constrained by the rule and are thus not restricted in supporting the stabilisation of
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 11
the economy. The rule only aims to place constraints on government policy with respect to discretionary
decisions on revenues and expenditures.
The main problem with such a rule is that the cyclically-adjusted budget balance is not directly observable
but, rather, has to be estimated. In addition to the variables necessary to forecast and calculate the budget
balance, the output gap and (semi-)elasticities of various revenue and expenditure categories are needed
for such estimates (plus one-off measures for the structural balance). The errors in forecast and real-time
estimates of the output gap and potential GDP can be quite large (see Section 3.2). As a result, evaluation
of rule compliance is very complex and the rule might prescribe different policy stances at different points
in time, e.g. in real-time compared with ex-post reassessments. Consequently, this causes difficulties in
fiscal planning and the real-time implementation of fiscal policy. In addition, this adversely affects
transparent communication with the general public and policymakers.
2.1.4. Expenditure Rules
Reforms focusing on expenditure rules are proposed (see Section 4.1) in an attempt to address the
challenges posed by the implementation of cyclically-adjusted budget balance rules. Expenditure rules
are in force in different forms across the world, including the EU’s current Stability and Growth Pact (SGP).
However, the most commonly proposed expenditure rule restricts the growth rate in public expenditures
to some limit related to potential GDP growth, net of some cyclical expenditure components and net of
discretionary changes in revenues. The latter are subtracted so that countries can choose the size of
government in terms of the ratio of expenditures to GDP according to the political preferences of the
electorate. This allows governments to permanently increase (cut) expenditures as a share of GDP if the
change is offset by permanent tax increases (cuts).
The properties of such an expenditure rule are similar to a rule constraining the cyclically-adjusted budget
balance (also discussed e.g. in Cottarelli, 2018). With the latter, aside from the initial starting position,
cyclically-adjusted expenditures are allowed to increase as much as cyclically-adjusted revenues to
comply with the rule. Growth in cyclically-adjusted expenditures is approximately equal to the growth in
expenditures net of (cyclical) unemployment-related expenditures. Because without any discretionary
changes (e.g. in the tax code) – revenues are closely aligned with GDP, cyclically-adjusted revenues are
closely related to potential GDP. Thus, growth in cyclically-adjusted revenues net of discretionary revenue
changes is approximately equal to growth in potential GDP. Taken together, aside from the initial st arting
position, both rule types restrict the growth in expenditures net of cyclical unemployment-related
expenditures and discretionary revenue measures to potential GDP growth. The EU fiscal framework also
recognises the similarity between the two rules, as expenditure rules are used to operationalise
adjustment of the structural balance (see Section 3.1).
As far as pro-cyclicality is concerned, expenditure rules work similarly to structural balance rules because
cyclical revenue shortfalls do not have to be compensated for by expenditure cuts. With structural
balance rules, this is due to the cyclical adjustment of revenues, while in the case of expenditure rules it
is because the constrained variable is only affected by discretionary changes in revenues. A difference
arises where revenues cyclically rise (fall) more sharply than what is mechanically calculated based on
output increases (declines) and elasticities. In that case, a cyclically-adjusted balance rule would restrict
fiscal policy too much in a downturn and an expenditure rule would restrict it too little in an upswing.
Despite the similarities, one reason why expenditure rules are currently preferred in the literature is that
expenditures net of some expenditure items and their growth rate are directly observable and are mostly
directly controlled by the government. Furthermore, the greater part of the constrained variable is easy
to communicate and forecast errors for expenditures tend to be smaller. For expenditure rules as well,
however, some components need to be estimated and they involve complexity and uncertainty: i) growth
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
12 PE 645.732
rate of potential GDP; ii) effects and size of discretionary revenue measures; iii) (for some rule proposals)
cyclical adjustment of (unemployment-related) expenditures.
Table 1: Differences between types of fiscal rules
Budget balance
Cyclically-adjusted (or
structural) balance
Expenditure growth
Pro-cyclicality
Measurement/ estimation
Measurement/ estimation
Dealing with
the economic
cycle
None
Cyclical adjustment of
expenditures and
revenues based on the
output gap
Cyclical revenue changes
not part of rule, (possible)
cyclical adjustment of
expenditures
Variables
necessary to
assess rule
compliance
Revenues, expenditures
Revenues, expenditures,
elasticities, output gap,
potential GDP, (one-off
measures)
Expenditure growth,
discretionary revenue
measures, potential GDP
growth
Source: own illustration
2.2. Golden Rules and Exceptions
2.2.1. Expenditure Categories Worth Protecting
Within the context of reforming fiscal frameworks there is also a debate about the quality of public
finances and how the framework can contribute to improving it. Higher quality is typically associated with
a larger share of expenditures that are more beneficial to economic growth, development and future
generations than others. The European Commission identifies expenditures with growth and value added
for the future in its proposals for a multiannual financial framework and its country-specific
recommendations for the Member States. Among these are expenditures for infrastructure investment
(especially digital infrastructure), public research, research and development (R&D), climate-related
investment, regional policy, investment in education and training, and public employment agencies.
Romp and De Haan (2007) and Bom and Ligthart (2014) survey the extensive literature on the effects of
public investment on output (growth). Although not all studies find a positive effect, there seems to be a
consensus that an increase in public capital increases economic growth in the short run and the effect is
stronger in the long run. However, there is a high degree of uncertainty about the estimated size of this
impact. It is heterogeneous across countries, regions, sectors and types of investment, and it depends on
the level and quality of the public capital stock in place (Romp and De Haan, 2007). Besides the long-term
effects, investment expenditures also seem to have a greater impact on demand than other expenditure
categories (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko, 2012; Gechert and Will, 2012). Increasing or reducing the
former rather than the latter therefore also has an effect on output in the short-term.
Investment expenditures as defined in the national accounts (‘gross fixed capital formation by the
government’) focus on physical capital such as infrastructure, housing and machinery. They als o include
spending on defence and intangible non-financial assets such as software. However, they do not include
maintenance spending or investment by state-owned enterprises (Barbiero and Darvas, 2014).
Furthermore, they do not include expenditure categories for example related to mitigating climate
change, education, or the accumulation of human capital. However, similar to investment expenditures,
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 13
these categories also incur costs today, and their benefits such as reduced future losses due to climate
change and educational benefits also accrue to future generations.
While studies seem to confirm the generally positive impact of some expenditure categories, it appears
that the main challenge is to clearly and narrowly define which expenditure categories are identified as
beneficial or worth protecting and which expenditures belong to each category. Furthermore, not every
project or expenditure within an identified category has a positive effect. And not every expenditure
category that is not listed above does not contain expenditures with positive longer-term effects. Ideally,
each spending decision involves a cost-benefit analysis and a subsequent decision to engage irrespective
of the expenditure category it belongs to. In addition, there are most probably strong interdependencies.
As an example, expenditures on the implementation of the rule of law do not form part of the categories
above, but they enable the other categories to have a positive effect. It is not always possible to
differentiate between productive and unproductive expenditures as, in many cases, both will be needed.
A proposed workaround is to identify expenditure categories which on average exhibit certain growth
effects or future benefits and accept the inaccuracy when it comes to each single expenditure item. In
general, however, it can be very difficult to identify the growth effects or future benefits of specific
categories over time and across countries, especially if politicians reallocate expenditures. Furthermore,
the identification of specific expenditures is usually made non-specifically and without reference to the
level of expenditures already implemented in that particular category. Consequently, the underlying
assumption is that spending in the respective category will always be associated with positive growth
contributions of equal size, irrespective of how and for what specific purpose the relevant expenditures
are made. However, this is not necessarily the case.
Even after categories have been identified, the issue of measurement is challenging. In many cases data
on the stock of public capital is not available and needs to be constructed based on historical series of
flow figures (Eurostat and OECD, 2014; Christofzik et al., 2019). While the latter are currently available for
physical capital, they might be more difficult to obtain for other categories, like mitigation of climate
change or human capital. In addition, replacement investment does not automatically increase the assets
available. Usage and time depreciate capital. Only if investment expenditure is higher than the
depreciation of existing assets are additional assets created for future generations. Depreciation has to
be estimated in order to obtain net investment figures, which is even more difficult than measuring gross
investment (Barbiero and Darvas, 2014). International comparisons of net investment figures are
especially difficult as various necessary assumptions differ across countries, such as the institutional
division of labour, frameworks and assumed usage periods (Christofzik et al., 2019). In the absence of any
double accounting systems for governments, reliable workarounds would need to be found.
2.2.2. Relationship with Fiscal Rules
The question is whether fiscal rules cause policymakers to put less emphasis on the expenditures
discussed above than would be optimal. The reasons given can broadly be grouped into two categories.
First, some of the expenditures identified above might be easier to cut than others. Thus, if compliance
with fiscal rules requires some expenditures to be reduced, these categories are cut not because they are
the lowest priority but because it is easier timewise and politically to do so. While it may be easy to
postpone the start of a new investment project today, for example, it might be hard to reduce public-
sector employment and wages or social benefits, which tend to be fixed for years ahead. Given the various
effects on demand, moreover, a reduction based on investment expenditure would tend to have a
stronger negative impact on economic growth than a similar reduction based on other expenditures.
Second, expenditures in the categories above either partially or mainly benefit future generations. This
means that, in one sense, they should also bear a share of the costs. This can be achieved by financing
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
14 PE 645.732
them through debt issuance. If they are not financed by debt, all of the costs are borne by the current
generation, which has to pay for them in the form of higher taxes or lower spending in other areas. This
can lead to less investment than would be ideal. A low-interest-rate environment makes it cheaper to shift
costs into the future. On the other hand, however, future generations are not able to fully participate in
the current political process. Thus although they cannot choose which investments are implemented,
their fiscal headroom is reduced. For example, while the current generation might choose to build roads,
which count as investment, future generations might want to reduce the scope for individual mobility.
Furthermore, policymakers might attach less importance to the future side-effects of higher debt and
might therefore opt for a higher level of debt than is ideal in order to gain some of the short-term benefits.
Some would argue that specific expenditures should be safeguarded through the design of fiscal rules.
This could be achieved by setting different limits to different expenditure aggregates. The most
prominent example would be a Golden Rule, which sets a limit to expenditures excluding investment
expenditures and allows borrowing to finance the latter. More generally, it sets a limit on a fiscal
aggregate net of a measure of deductible expenditures. Golden Rules have been implemented in various
countries and can come in different forms with respect to the rule type and the expenditures excluded. A
Golden Rule can essentially be designed based on any rule type, which means that there could be a
Golden expenditure rule or a Golden structural balance rule. Another option for safeguarding
expenditures is to add exceptions to fiscal rules, which either temporarily or permanently allow
exceptional and limited breaches of the fiscal rules and permit specific expenditures. The current EU rules
have exceptions added to them (see Section 3.3). Any rule containing an exception that permanently
allows non-compliance with the fiscal rule to the extent of specific expenditures would be equivalent to
a Golden Rule as described above.
One of the most serious challenges in implementing Golden Rules is associated with adverse incentives
for governments to engage in ‘creative accounting’. In cases where an exception in the form of a Golden
Rule is granted too casually, this could provide incentives to relabel public expenditures or to use
accounting tricks in order to (over-) exploit the leeway provided by the rule (Milesi-Ferretti, 2004). Burret
and Feld (2018) show how Swiss cantons, where a debt brake is in force, shift expenditures from
constrained parts of the budget to unconstrained parts for investment expenditure purposes. Von Hagen
and Wolff (2006) and Buti et al. (2006) provide empirical evidence that stock-flow adjustments have been
used in the EU to hide deficits from the SGP rules. Koen and Noord (2005) show for the EU Member States
that budgetary gimmickry is more likely the more binding fiscal rules become. Governments somehow
need to be prevented from shifting expenditures into the defined deductible categories. In addition,
categories need to be defined so as to minimise the incentives to increase one type of expenditure
benefiting future generations in favour of other expenditures that also benefit future generations. If, for
example, investment in physical capital is deductible but education expenditures are not, governments
might opt to invest a higher proportion of the total in physical capital rather than investing in human
capital.
3. EXPERIENCE WITH THE CURRENT EU FISCAL FRAMEWORK
3.1. Current Fiscal Rules at the European Level
Fiscal rules have been part of the European governance framework since the Treaty of Maastricht in 1992.
However, the framework has gradually evolved as a result of major reforms and has been augmented
considerably over time. These changes introduced second-generation fiscal rules, increased the
flexibility of the framework and amended institutional monitoring and governance. Whereas the
framework started out with just two simple fiscal rulesthe 3 per cent deficit rule and the 60 per cent
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 15
debt-to-GDP rule it has evolved into a complex web of rules and regulations today. Various rules coexist
with a multitude of exceptions and escape clauses as well as comprehensive provisions for assessing
compliance with the rules. In addition to the EU fiscal framework, policymakers also face fiscal rules at the
national and subnational levels when taking fiscal policy decisions.
In 2005, a rule restricting the structural balance and, in 2011, a rule on expenditure growth were
introduced in the preventive arm of the SGP. The former rule states that the structural balance should be
larger than or equal to a medium-term objective (MTO), which each country sets in its Stability or
Convergence Programme (European Commission, 2019b). The MTO for countries which signed the Fiscal
Compact must be larger than -0.5 per cent of GDP, unless their debt ratio is significantly below 60 per
cent of GDP and their sustainability risks are low, in which case the MTO needs to be larger than -1 per
cent of GDP. Furthermore, the European Commission calculates a minimum MTO for each country.
The two rules in the EU framework are connected, as the expenditure rule basically implements the path
towards the MTO set by the structural balance rule: i) In the case of a country which complies with the
latter rule, i.e. for which the structural balance is higher than or equal to their MTO, the expenditure rule
states that the growth in net expenditures should be less than or equal to the medium-term growth rate
of potential GDP (European Commission, 2019b). As described in Section 2.1.4, this is equivalent to a rule
which states that the structural balance should be improving or remaining constant. ii) If the country does
not comply, net expenditure growth should be less than the medium-term growth in potential GDP by a
convergence margin, which means that the structural balance should improve by a specific margin.
The expenditure rule in the EU fiscal framework defines net expenditures as total expenditures net of the
following items: i) discretionary revenue measures, ii) interest expenditures, iii) expenditures on EU
programmes matched by EU funds and iv) cyclical unemployment-related expenditures. By excluding
some investment expenditures, the expenditure rule in its current form already resembles a very limited
form of Golden Rule. Investment expenditures not matched by EU funds are smoothed over a four-year
period. The medium-term growth rate of potential GDP, which serves as the limit on expenditure growth,
is calculated for each country as the average of potential GDP over the past five years, the current year
and the forecasts for the next four years.
3.2. Forecast and Real-Time Errors
A series of variables are necessary to evaluate compliance with EU fiscal rules. When deciding on fiscal
policy ex-ante or in real-time, policymakers need to rely on forecasts and estimates of those variables.
Forecast errors can lead to incorrect policy prescriptions which were not originally intended by the fiscal
rules. Furthermore, most variables are also revised considerably ex-post such that any assessment of
compliance even without changes in policy can change over time. Figure 1 depicts the main variables
needed in the EU fiscal framework and their relationships. The latter are still underrepresented though,
as, e.g., a forecast of GDP is also necessary to forecast the cyclical parts of expenditures or revenues.
When interpreting the results below it is also important to note that errors in the estimation of variables
used to operationalise fiscal rules might also be influencing the ex-post observations of certain variables.
For example, an erroneous reduction in potential GDP during a downturn could as a result of overly
restrictive fiscal rules lead to procyclical policies such as expenditure cuts, which in turn reduce GDP.
This could make the error self-fullfilling in the sense that lower GDP also lowers potential GDP estimates
(Fatás, 2019). In this case, therefore, the errors calculated from the difference between values published
for potential GDP in forecasts and ex-post might seem lower than they actually were.
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
16 PE 645.732
Figure 1: Main variables necessary for evaluating compliance with EU fiscal rules
Source: own illustration
In the following, the European Commission’s macro-economic database (AMECO) is used to calculate the
forecast and real-time errors for some of the main variables. The figures compare the forecast of a variable
for a specific year (t) from two years ahead (t-2), one year ahead (t-1) and in real-time (t) with the variable
value which was published four years after the specific year (t+4). The mean error is defined as the mean
difference between the two points in time across years and countries. As this difference can be positive
or negative, however, some of the errors might cancel each other out when a simple mean is taken. Mean
absolute errors are therefore also calculated, which take the mean of the absolute values of the
differences across countries and years. Annex 6.1 provides a more detailed methodological background.
Figure 2 presents the two measures of errors for the EU15 from 2005 to 2015. The timeframe is chosen to
have a consistent dataset which only compares data which is availabe for all countries and years across
all variables in forecast and ex-post data. However, Table 5 in Annex 6.5 presents the results for other
country and time samples (e.g. for the EU27 or excluding the years of the financial crisis), as well as for the
structural balance (for which data is only available for a shorter time period). For the years where data
overlaps, errors for the structural and the cyclically-adjusted balance are very similar.
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 17
Figure 2: Mean (absolute) errors of forecasts and real-time estimates (EU15, 2005-2015)
Notes: Calculations are based on 164 observations (no data for Luxembourg in 2002). Mean errors are calculated as mean across
countries and time of the difference between values for year t values in autumn vintage of year t+4 and in autumn vintage of
year t-2, t-1 and t. Mean absolute errors are the mean of the absolute value of the differences. To make results comparable only
years and vintages are included which are available for all variables in all years and countries. More details on calculations can be
found in Annex 6.1. Budget balance: net lending or borrowing. pp.: differences in percentage points.
Sources: European Commission’s AMECO database, Firstrun project, own calculations
3.2.1. Mean Absolute Errors
Figure 2 shows that, comparable to findings in other studies
1
, mean absolute errors are substantial,
especially in the case of forecasts for two years ahead. For real GDP this amounts to about 3.5 per cent of
GDP. Even for the variable which shows the lowest mean absolute error, i.e. expenditures, the two-year
ahead forecasts are associated with mean absolute errors of 1.5 per cent of GDP. Mean absolute errors in
real-time are substantially smaller than in forecasts, but are still quite significant. Whereas in the cases of
real GDP, revenues, expenditures and the budget balance the mean absolute errors for real-time
estimates are below 1 per cent of GDP, they are still larger than 1 per cent for all measures that involve
estimates of potential GDP. The mean absolute errors for the growth rate of potential GDP are only about
half the size of the errors for the level of potential GDP. The reason seems to be that errors for potential
1
Merola and Pérez (2013) calculate a mean absolute error for real GDP of around 1.3 per cent of GDP for the one-year ahead forecast and
between 0.7 per cent and 1.2 per cent for real-time estimates for 15 European countries (1999 - 2007). De Deus and de Mendonça (2015)
find very similar errors in real-time based on data from the IMF, the OECD and the European Commission (1998 - 2011).
-2.0
-1.0
0.0
1.0
2.0
3.0
4.0
t-2 t-1 t t-2 t-1
t t-2 t-1 t t-2 t-1 t t-2 t-1
t t-2 t-1 t t-2 t-1 t t-2 t-1 t
Real GDP
(% of GDP)
Potential GDP
(% of GDP)
Revenues
(% of GDP)
Expenditures
(% of GDP)
Output Gap
(pp.)
Budget
balance
(pp.)
Cyclically-
adjusted
budget
balance
(pp.)
Growth of
potential GDP
(pp.)
Mean Absolute Error Mean Error
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
18 PE 645.732
GDP are correlated over time
2
, i.e. if the value is revised for one year the previous year is very likely to also
be revised in the same direction.
The smallest mean absolute errors for forecasts and real-time estimates can be observed for expenditures.
Especially in forecasts the mean absolute errors for expenditures are substantially smaller (1.5 per cent for
two-year ahead and 1.1 per cent for one-year ahead forecasts) than, for example, the ones for real GDP.
In real-time, the mean absolute error for expenditures was equal to 0.6 per cent of GDP. However, when
interpreting these numbers one needs to bear in mind that expenditures are only a fraction of GDP. As a
percentage of expenditures, therefore, the mean absolute errors for the same sample would be much
higher (3.1 per cent in two-year ahead forecasts and 1.3 per cent in real-time).
3
As a percentage of the
variable itself, the errors are comparable to the errors for real GDP. Nevertheless, the errors expressed as
a percentage of GDP might be more relevant in terms of policy prescriptions.
3.2.2. Mean Errors
Besides the large size of the mean absolute errors, a bias in the errors can be observed for some of the
variables as well. The mean errors for real and potential GDP are strongly negative. This means that GDP
forecasts were too optimistic during the time period considered here. While for real GDP, however, the
bias vanishes from forecasts to estimates in real-time and the mean error in real-time is close to zero, there
remains a bias of -0.6 per cent of GDP for the real-time estimates of potential GDP. So while real GDP in
real-time was on average neither too optimistic nor too pessimistic, potential GDP estimates remained
too optimistic. This translates into a bias in the estimates of the output gap, which in real-time was on
average 0.7 percentage points of GDP too low compared with the estimates of four years later. Put
differently, the cyclical position in real-time was on average estimated to be worse than it turned out to
be ex-post. This confirms findings in other studies for different countries and time periods.
4
This pessimistic error in output gap estimates translates into errors in the estimation of the cyclically-
adjusted measures of the budget balance, which are based on output gaps. While the real-time mean
error for revenues, expenditures and the budget balance is close to zero, it is -0.3 percentage points for
the cyclically-adjusted budget balance, and it is -0.8 percentage points in the two-year-ahead forecasts.
Thus, the cyclically-adjusted fiscal position looked better in real-time than it did ex-post, and it looked
even better in forecasts. This means that cyclically-adjusted or structural balance rules in the time period
considered here were on average too lax in forecasts and real-time compared with ex-post estimates.
5
The estimation of potential GDP is often based on filtering techniques (such as the methods currently
used by the European Commission). These are prone to revisions especially because of end-of-sample
problems, i.e. they are sensitive to the latest available forecasts or observations of actual GDP (GCEE,
2019). A series of improvements to the currently used methods are discussed, such as using other
indicators, different models and estimation methods. However, ultimately, any revision of GDP is likely to
be composed of cyclical and structural factors, such that potential GDP also needs to be revised when
actual GDP is, although the exact extent of this will remain uncertain. Recognising the uncertain nature
2
The correlation of the value for a specific year () and the year before ( 1) for the two-year ahead forecasts is 0.69.
3
The same applies to revenues, for which Buettner and Kauder (2010), for example, calculate a mean absolute error of 4.5 per cent of
revenues in forecasts. This is comparable to the results presented for revenues in this section (error of 2.3 per cent of GDP).
4
Some of the studies are surveyed in Navarini and Zoppè (2020). Eyraud and Wu (2015) find a similar mean error for real-time output gap
estimates of 1.2 percentage points of GDP for the Eurozone countries between 2003 and 2013 and Kempkes (2012) finds a mean error of
1.0 to 1.3 percentage points for the EU15 between 1996 and 2011.
5
Eyraud and Wu (2015) and Claeys et al. (2016) show similar results for the structural balance (-0.5 per cent of GDP for Eurozone countries
between 2003 and 2013, and -0.7 per cent of GDP for core EU15 countries from 2003 to 2014 respectively). Frankel and Schreger (2013) also
document over-optimism on the part of European countries when forecasting fiscal balances between 1999 and 2011.
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 19
of potential GDP estimates, the EU has added a (constrained) judgement component to the
implementation of the rules and is trying to mitigate the implications of uncertainty (Buti et al., 2019).
3.2.3. Other Forecast and Estimation Errors
An additional source of uncertainty on top of those discussed in the previous sections is hidden in the
estimation of (semi-)elasticities and weights used to translate the cyclical position of GDP measured by
the output gap into cyclically-adjusted budget balance figures. Elasticities are revised every nine years
and weights are revised every six years (European Commission, 2019a). The currently used elasticities are
estimated based on data from 1990 to 2013 (Mourre et al., 2014). Between 2005 and 2014 changes in
budgetary semi-elasticities for the EU27 ranged between -0.02 and 0.15, with an average change of 0.05
(Girouard and André, 2005; Price et al., 2014). Given that the average budgetary semi-elasticity is 0.50,
these changes have quite significant effects on cyclically-adjusted variables.
To evaluate compliance with an expenditure rule, discretionary revenue measures and their impact in a
specific year, but also in subsequent yearshave to be estimated. Estimates of discretionary revenue
measures have only very recently been published in the AMECO dataset, starting with the vintages of
2014. It is therefore not yet possible to conduct a comparable analysis to the one above of forecast or real-
time errors. However, it appears that they can potentially become quite substantial.
6
A series of
assumptions and projections are necessary to estimate e.g. the impact of a change in the tax code (e.g.
changes in tax rates or the tax base) on current and future revenues. This involves, among others things,
estimating the microeconomic behavioural reactions to tax changes, e.g. changes in labour supply in
response to changes in labour taxation. Although the European Commission relies on national estimates
of discretionary revenue measures, it defines a procedure and common methodology as to how Member
States should assess the budgetary effects (European Commission, 2019b). This bottom-up approach is
used to evaluate compliance with the EU expenditure rule. This could be problematic as there is an
information asymmetry between Member States and the European Commission, estimations depend on
national budgeting practices and there is an incentive for Member States to present biased estimates.
Furthermore, as also discussed by Deutsche Bundesbank (2019), it would be desirable to conduct an in-
depth and independent ex-post examination of the quality and errors inherent in estimates of
discretionary revenue measures, e.g. at the European level.
3.3. Exceptions and Compliance
Many fiscal rules have exceptions and escape clauses added to them. The European rules allow larger
deficits or expenditures in the context of an escape clause for unusual events and severe economic
downturns (EC Regulations 1466/1997 and 1467/1997). Furthermore, there are exceptions, for exa mple,
for public investment, major structural or pension reforms (EC Regulation 1055/2005; EU COM (2015) 12
final) and small and temporary deviations. The activation of such an escape clause or exception allows, to
a certain extent, a deviation from limits set by the rules. This does not mean that the rules are not complied
with, because the exceptions and escape clauses are essential parts of the rulesdesign and deviations
from the limits in such cases are intended. One of the most important goals of fiscal rules is precisely to
build up fiscal buffers so as to be able to spend more than what the rules would allow in extraordinary
times for events such as natural disasters and severe economic crises. Nevertheless, poorly designed or
excessive numbers of exceptions could undermine the goals of fiscal rules.
6
The mean absolute change in the estimate of discretionary revenue measures from one vintage to the next for the years between 2014 and
2019 across the EU15 was 0.09 percentage points of GDP. This number is quite large when one considers that the other errors presented in
this section were calculated across several vintages and that the mean absolute value of discretionary revenue measures in the same
sample is only 0.33 percentage points of GDP.
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
20 PE 645.732
The EU’s escape clause for severe economic downturns had never been activated until the COVID-19
pandemic (Council of the EU, 2020). As shown in Figure 3, however, the escape clause for unusual events
and other exceptions have been used quite extensively in recent years. A total of 18 exceptions were
granted in 2016. Nonetheless, the investment clause has only been used five times since 2012 (Bulgaria
in 2013 and 2014, Romania and Slovakia in 2014, and Italy in 2016). These exceptions can be quite
substantial and have meant that, on average, some countries have been allowed to run deficits in excess
of the limits of the rules by 0.46 per cent of GDP due to pension reforms, 0.44 per cent due to structural
reforms and 0.30 per cent due to exceptions for investment expenditures between 2012 and 2018.
7
Figure 3: Number and average size of exceptions granted between 2012 and 2018
Notes: Numbers are based on figures reported in Assessments of the Stability Programmes by the EU Commission. Preliminary
numbers for 2018. Exceptions for refugees, security-related measures and natural disasters constitute exceptions for unusual
events. No size figures are reported for exceptions for small deviations.
Sources: Christofzik et al. (2018), EU Commisson assessments of stability programmes of Member States, own compilation
The use of escape clauses and exceptions is intended by the fiscal rules, and exceeding the limit to the
extent approved is still in compliance with the rules. In addition to this, however, countries seem to often
not comply with the rules, at least in terms of economic not legal compliance. According to calculations
by the European Fiscal Board (2019), average economic compliance with EU fiscal rules was only 57 per
cent between 1998 and 2018. Studies on fiscal rules at the national level (Reuter, 2019) and worldwide
(Lledó and Reuter, 2018) find similar compliance rates of around 50 per cent. Examining the types of fiscal
rules, Cordes et al. (2015) and Reuter (2019) find that expenditure rules at the national level tend to be
complied with more often than budget or structural balance rules. According to the European Fis cal
Board (2019), this seems not to be the case for the EU fiscal rules. Contrary to the general intention behind
fiscal rules, countries do not seem to treat rules as ceilings, but rather as targets which are aimed at over
the medium term (Reuter, 2015). If rules were designed to be targets from the outset, however, their
design and, especially, their calibration would be different. Furthermore, the low level of compliance has
to be taken into account when analysing the effects of fiscal rules on observed fiscal policy, e.g. within
the context of the pro-cylicallity of fiscal policy.
7
These numbers are close to the maximum amount which can be granted for structural reforms and investment per adjustment period,
which is 0.5 per cent of GDP (there is no such cap for the pension reform exception).
0
5
10
15
20
2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018*
Number of granted exceptions
Pension reform
Structural reform Investment
Small deviation Refugees Security-related
Natural disaster
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
Average size of granted exceptions
(2012-2018, % of GDP)
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 21
3.4. Composition of Public Expenditures
Overall the share of public investment (here represented by gross fixed capital formation by the
government’) and public education expenditures in total expenditures in the EU15 are on average at
around the same level in 2019 as in 1995 (Figure 4). The shares increased up until the mid of the 2000s,
decreased around the financial crisis and caught up some of the loss since then. Spending on basic
research and R&D increased as a percentage of total expenditures between 2001 and 2018 (Figure 10).
Annex 6.2 discusses the development of the shares also as a percentage of GDP in more detail. The
development was quite heterogenous across countries. For example, the sharpest drops in the share of
investment expenditures between 2008 and 2013 were observed in Member States that had financial
assistance programmes. Furthermore, many countries in an excessive deficit procedure (EDP) seemed to
have reduced their investment shares (European Fiscal Board, 2019). However, any comparison of
investment figures across countries even between the group of EU Member States is problematic
(Christofzik et al., 2019). For example, the reliance on outsourced public services is quite heterogenous
across Member States and across time.
Figure 4: Public investment and education expenditures in the EU15 from 1995 to 2019
Notes: Investment expenditures are represented by gross fixed capital formation by the government. Education expenditures by
the government according to COFOG classification. Blue areas represent the range between the maximum and minimum values
in each year. Lines represent the mean and mean plus and minus one standard deviation across Member States.
Sources: European Commission’s AMECO database, Eurostat, own calculations
To what extent the EU fiscal rules played a role in the reduction of these investment shares is an open
question. So far the rules, especially if they are cyclically-adjusted, do not directly interfere in the
composition of public expenditures. Initial studies which try to identify the possible effects of fiscal rules
on public investment have not come up with clear-cut findings across the studies (Turrini, 2004; Perée
and Välilä, 2005; Bacchiocchi et al., 2011; Dahan and Strawczynski, 2013; Hauptmeier et al., 2015).
However, specific expenditures like investment and the ones discussed in the previous section might be
reduced (relative to others) first and most sharply during fiscal consolidations. Annex 6.2 discusses the
empirical relationship across the past 23 years in detail. Overall, the results suggest that expenditures on
investment and, to a smaller extent, on education as well as basic research and R&D are reduced as a
percentage of GDP during periods of fiscal consolidation. However, expenditures on education as well as
basic research and R&D are affected less than other expenditure categories, which means that their share
of total expenditures increases. Overall, the share in total expenditures accounted for by investment
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
12%
14%
16%
General government gross fixed capital
formation (% of Total Expenditure)
Max-Min-Range Mean +/- Std.Dev. Mean
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
Public Education
(% of Total Expenditure)
Max-Min-Range Mean +/- Std.Dev. Mean
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
22 PE 645.732
expenditures does not seem to be systematically related to periods of fiscal consolidation or expansion
over the past 23 years.
3.5. Pro-Cyclicality of the Current Framework
Section 2.1.1 introduced a distinction between cyclical and structural parts of public finances. Any change
in the cyclical part has, by definition, a counter-cyclical effect. In a downturn this automatically r esults in
a larger deficit, lower revenues and higher expenditures. Fiscal rules which exclude cyclical components
from the variables constrained by the rule such as cyclically-adjusted or structural budget balance rules
as well as expenditure rules which exclude (cyclical) unemployment-related expenditures theoretically
do not prevent these counter-cyclical effects from happening. However, this counter-cyclical effect can
be weakened or even reversed if discretionary fiscal measures counteract the automatic stabilisation of
the cyclical component. Indeed, Fatas (2019), for example, shows that discretionary policy in the euro area
eliminated the benefits of automatic stabilisers between 2010 and 2014 and turned fiscal policy pro-
cyclical.
Within the context of fiscal rules, one or several of the following reasons could lead discretionary fiscal
policy to counteract the automatic stabilisers and thus turn fiscal policy pro-cyclical:
1. A bias in forecasts of the cyclical part of public finances might force discretionary fiscal policy to
take countermeasures to comply with fiscal rules. As seen in Section 3.2, assessments of the
position in the economic cycle both in forecasts and real-time have shown a bias and have been
too pessimistic over the past few years. Consequently, rules limiting cyclically-adjusted measures
have been too loose both in forecasts and real-time relative to ex-post assessments. In this
respect, therefore, rules seem to have on average not forced discretionary fiscal policy to
counteract automatic stabilisers owing to a bias in forecasts. On the contrary, these rules would
have actually made it possible to strengthen cyclical components by pursuing discretionary
policy in a downturn. Although the rules have not been restrictive enough during upturns,
discretionary policy has not needed to use all of the additional leeway granted by the rules.
2. The limits of fiscal rules might be changed pro-cyclically such that discretionary fiscal policy needs
to adjust. There appears to be no sign of any systematic changes in line with the economic cycle
to the limits of the EU fiscal rules, e.g. the minimum MTOs which are set for Member States. The
six-pack and two-pack reforms under the European fiscal framework tend to provide more fiscal
headroom to Member States for economic stabilisation purposes.
3. Exceptions and escape clauses might be applied pro-cyclically. Under the EU fiscal framework the
average change in the output gap during the years when the 64 exceptions were granted
between 2012 and 2018 (see Section 3.3) was a positive 0.49 percentage points. The average level
of the output gap was close to zero (0.08 per cent). 70 per cent of the years in which exceptions
were granted to countries saw a positive change in the output gap. It seems that exceptions were
granted especially for years in which there was an economic upturn (positive change in the
output gap). This would enable policymakers to expand discretionary fiscal policy pro-cyclically.
However, exceptions have only very recently been used extensively, which means that this
observation is severely limited because it is based on a very short time period.
4. Non-compliance with fiscal rules might be pro-cyclical. The European Fiscal Board (2019) points
out that compliance with cyclically-adjusted rules under the EU framework was relatively low
before 2008 and in recent years, which are both periods with fairly benign economic conditions.
By not complying with the rules, discretionary policy fostered a pro-cyclical fiscal stance, which
the rules would not have prescribed. Larch et al. (2020) look at the role of compliance with fiscal
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 23
rules as part of a more systematic approach. They find that compliance with fiscal rules would
have been associated with a more counter-cyclical fiscal stance, i.e. that non-compliance with the
cyclically-adjusted rules increases the likelihood of running pro-cyclical fiscal policies.
5. Aside from fiscal rules, policymakers face a variety of challenges which can lead them to pursue
pro-cyclical discretionary policies. Potential reasons could be high debt levels which mean that,
even in a downturn and although the rules would allow it, discretionary fiscal policy is used not
counter-cyclically but pro-cyclically. The European Fiscal Board (2019) points to the possibility
that concerns about fiscal sustainability may have pushed governments to consolidate more than
the fiscal rules would prescribe. The failure to build up buffers in the EU by running a pro-cyclically
expansionary discretionary fiscal policy in fairly good economic times before the financial crisis
was followed by pro-cyclical restrictive discretionary fiscal policy to try to rein in debt increases in
2012 and 2013. In both periods the fiscal rules per se did not force policymakers to act pro-
cyclically: on the contrary they would have allowed policy to be counter-cyclical.
In summary: It seems that political decisions outside the scope of the fiscal rules, non-compliance with
the rules and the use of exceptions rather than rule design or forecast errors tended to foster pro-
cyclical fiscal policy in the EU.
4. FOCUSING THE EU FRAMEWORK ON AN EXPENDITURE RULE
4.1. Proposals for Expenditure Rules
Many authors and institutions have suggested reforming the EU fiscal framework by focusing it on an
expenditure rule (Ayuso-i-Casals, 2012; Carnot, 2014; Andrle et al., 2015; Christofzik et al., 2018; Cottarelli,
2018; Darvas et al., 2018; Eyraud et al., 2018b; Kopits, 2018). Table 2 presents some of the proposals for
which a more detailed description of the proposed rule is available and compares their features with the
existing expenditure rule under the EU fiscal framework.
The proposed rules all set a limit on the growth rate of a derivative of gross expenditures, which in most
cases is net of interest expenditures, some measure of unemployment-related expenditures and an
estimate of discretionary revenue measures. The limit set by the rule is in most cases directly or indirectly
related to the growth rate of potential GDP. Furthermore, all proposals combine the expenditure rule with
some mechanism related to the debt ratio or debt reduction targets.
Differences between the proposals are only visible in the details, which suggests that there already seems
to be a consensus on the broad design of an expenditure rule on which the EU fiscal framework could be
focused. The proposals differ, e.g., in the details of how limits are set and in the extent of debt correction,
either driven by formulas or by a process involving national governments, fiscal councils or the European
Commission. Another dimension in which the proposals differ is the design and usage of an adjustment
account, which in some proposals captures deviations between planned and actual expenditures and in
others also includes estimation errors or deviations from medium-term targets.
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
24 PE 645.732
Table 2: Comparison of expenditure rule proposals
Limit Excluded items Debt correction Adjustment account Special features
I
U
R
Other
Current EU rule
Medium-term potential GDP
growth
EU-funded investment
Implicit by relation to
MTOs
National investment
averaged over four
years
European Fiscal Board
(2018, 2019)
Trend rate of potential GDP
growth (limit fixed for a three-
year period)
EU-funded investment
Debt ratio within
range of long-run
objective within
maximum number of
years
Deviations of planned
expenditure growth;
subject to maximum;
decumulates in case of
windfall gain
Member States with
debt ratio below 60%
of GDP not subject to
net expenditure
ceiling
Christofzik et al. (2018)
Medium-term potential GDP
growth
Relative to difference
between present debt
levels and long-term
limit
Non-compliance
margin with structural
balance rule;
estimation errors;
small deviations in
budgetary process
Claeys et al. (2016)
Medium-term potential GDP
growth
All labour-market-re lated
expenditure; one-off
expenditure
0.02 times difference
between debt level in
previous year and 60 %
debt criterion
Difference between
actual expenditure
growth and the
expenditure growth
limit
Public investment
smoothed over
several years and
accounted for similarly
to corporate
investment
Darvas et al. (2018)
(very similar to
nassy-Quéré et al.,
2018)
Medium-term debt reduction
target set by national
government
(based on
potential GDP growth)
All unemployment
spending (except when
due to discretionary
changes)
Limit directly takes
care of debt correction
Limited deviations
between actual and
budgeted spending
I interest payments; U cyclical unemployment-related expenditures; R discretionary revenue measures:
Sources: Studies as indicated in first column of table, own compilation
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 25
4.2. Assessment of Rule Performance Based on Past Data
A starting point for investigating the possible performance of the proposed expenditure rules is to
compare limits that would have been set by different rule types with actual expenditure growth based
on past data. To isolate the effect of the rule type from the exact numerical calibration, both rules
considered in this exercise set a limit which would keep the cyclically-adjusted budget balance
constant over the medium-term. Policymakers can decide to calibrate the rules such that, for exa mple,
they improve the cyclically-adjusted budget balance (e.g. in relation to the debt ratio) or constantly
allow some borrowing. However, this is independent of the rule type and is discussed in Section 4.3.
Figure 5 presents the following three variables as published in real-time, i.e. data for year from the
autumn vintage in year , and ex-post, i.e. data from the autumn vintage in year + 4:
1. Growth rate of primary expenditures, which represents observed fiscal policy. Expenditures net
of cyclical unemployment-related expenditures and discretionary revenue measures would be
needed for an exact representation of most proposed expenditure rules. However, the latter
two variables are only available for a very short time period. Annex 6.2 discusses the differences
for the years in which data overlaps. When interpreting the following results it is important to
bear in mind the sizeable differences between different expenditure measures.
2. Five-year moving average of potential GDP growth, which represents the limit set by an
expenditure rule. The five-year average is just one possible way of calculating the limit in
relation to potential GDP. Annex 6.2 discusses other averages proposed for expenditure rules
in comparison with annual potential GDP estimates.
3. Growth rate of the sum of cyclically-adjusted revenues and the cyclical component of
expenditures, which represents the limit on expenditure growth to keep the cyclically-adjusted
balance constant in a specific year. A detailed discussion of this calculation can be found in
Annex 6.2. It is important to remember that this measure does not capture the actual limit set
by a cyclically-adjusted balanced budget rule. This measure shows by how much expenditures
could have grown without the cyclically-adjusted balance deteriorating.
Figure 5: Comparison of limits set for expenditure growth with observed fiscal policy (EU15)
Notes: Average potential GDP refers to backward-looking five-year moving average; calculation details in Annex 6.2.
Sources: European Commission’s AMECO database, Firstrun project, own calculations
-2%
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
Real-Time
Average potential GDP growth
Constant cyclically-adjusted balance
Observed primary expenditure growth
-2%
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
Ex-Post
Average potential GDP growth
Constant cyclically-adjusted balance
Observed primary expenditure growth
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
26 PE 645.732
The values depicted in Figure 5 represent averages across the EU15. Although a country-by-country
analysis would be too comprehensive for this paper, it could reveal interesting country-specific
insights, which are ignored in the following discussion. Furthermore, the discussion below is based on
a single, fairly short time series. More systematic analysis would be necessary to draw more robust
conclusions.
The first observation to make here is that average potential GDP growth and the average limit which
keeps the cyclically-adjusted balance constant were closely aligned over the medium term (especially
in the ex-post data), which confirms the similarity between expenditure and cyclically-adjusted balance
rules over the medium term (Section 2.1.4). The latter is, however, more volatile and seems to fluctuate
around medium-term potential GDP growth. A clear outlier in this regard is 2009. In that year, much
lower expenditure growth would have been necessary to keep the cyclically-adjusted balance constant
compared with medium-term potential GDP growth. To a large extent this is a feature of taking the
average for potential GDP growth, as annual potential GDP also decreased sharply in 2009 (see Figure
12 in Annex 6.2). As far as rule design is concerned, however, an escape clause was activated anyway in
that year, so the limits set by the rules were not applicable. This is also evident in the continuing high
level of expenditure growth observed in that year.
Second, both limits would have been lower than the expenditure growth observed before the financial
crisis in the early 2000s and in most recent years 2017 and 2018. Furthermore, both would have allowed
more expenditure growth between 2010 and 2014. The sharp drop in expenditure growth observed in
2011 and 2012 would not have been necessary to keep the cyclically-adjusted balance constant.
Consequently, both limits would have prescribed a more counter-cyclical fiscal policy over the past 18
years if they had been complied with and if the leeway granted by the rules had been used. This general
result confirms the findings presented by Andrle et al. (2015), who use model simulations to show that,
apart from measurement uncertainty, expenditure and structural balance rules operate similarly in
stabilising the economy.
Third, in the years when there was an ex-post negative change in the output gap, the limit based on
potential GDP growth would have allowed: i) slightly more expenditure growth in 2001-2003 than
necessary to keep the cyclically-adjusted balance constant, ii) much more in 2008 and 2009 when,
however, an escape clause would have been applicable to both rules, and iii) less in 2012 and 2013. In
years when there were significant positive changes in the output gap (2000, 2006, 2007, 2010, 2015)
average potential GDP growth would have set a slightly looser limit than a constant cyclically-adjusted
balance in real-time (also for ex-post data except for 2006). This suggests on the whole that, in relative
terms, the cyclically-adjusted balance seems to set a more restrictive limit during upturns, while
medium-term potential GDP growth sets a more expansionary limit during downturns. However, it
should be remembered that this assessment is based on a single, fairly short time series and a more
systematic evaluation across countries and settings would therefore be desireable.
4.3. Calibration
The preceding analysis abstracts from the actual calibration of the fiscal rules, i.e. the exact numerical
limits and how they are determined. The various calibrations in place and proposed do not alter the
basic characteristics of rule types. Consequently, the numerical calibration can be decided
independently of the rule type.
The choice of numerical calibration requires a risk assessment and the balancing of various trade-offs
and is therefore mainly a political decision. There is a trade-off between overly restrictive limits, which
might hamper growth and investment, and overly lax limits, which reduce the fiscal headroom
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 27
available during times of crisis and increase vulnerability to shocks (Eyraud et al., 2018a). A key measure
here is the public debt-to-GDP ratio to which public debt would converge in the long run if the rule
were always complied with. The selection of the respective ratio depends on the maximum debt limit
below which it is highly probable that the debt dynamics can be controlled by the government, m inus
a safety margin. The maximum debt limit is very uncertain and depends on many factors like long-term
growth rates, interest rates as well as the country-specific environment and institutions (Ghosh et al.,
2013; D’Erasmo et al., 2016). The safety margin is necessary because of the high uncertainty and
because negative shocks, such as severe economic crises, can trigger exceptions and increase the ratio
by fairly large amounts.
However not only the targeted debt-to-GDP ratio, i.e. the long-run point of convergence, but also the
desired speed of convergence play a role in determining the numerical limits for fiscal rules. The
process of converging to the long-run ratio can take quite a long time. Given an initial debt ratio of 80
per cent, for example, with a constant government deficit of 0.5 per cent of GDP and a steady nominal
growth rate of 3 per cent, the debt-to-GDP ratio would converge to 17 per cent in the long term.
However, it will take 53 years for the ratio to fall below 30 per cent, and after twelve years it will still be
above 60 per cent.
In order to lower the debt ratio faster for countries with higher debt ratios, all proposals on expenditure
rules involve some kind of deduction from the limit set by the rule relative to the level of debt ratio. In
choosing this deduction, one is again faced with the above-mentioned trade-off. The feedback
mechanism could also take care of medium-term changes in structural public revenues which are not
related to discretionary revenue measures.
8
Furthermore, the process of calibrating the speed of
convergence would vary depending on whether governments use the limits set by the rules as ceilings
or targets, even if they merely misuse them as targets.
When an expenditure rule is introduced, some transitory adjustment mechanism will be necessary, as
not all countries will be starting from the same cyclically-adjusted budget balance. A specific limit on
expenditure growth could therefore mean very different things to different countries in terms of their
medium-term budget balance.
5. CONVERTING AN EU FISCAL RULE INTO A GOLDEN RULE
5.1. Proposals for Safeguarding Specific Expenditure Categories
A wide range of publications propose that specific expenditure categories, such as investment
expenditures, should be treated differently in terms of debt financing in the context of the EU fiscal
framework (Fitoussi and Creel, 2002; Blanchard and Giavazzi, 2004; Barbiero and Darvas, 2014; Truger,
2015; Claeys, 2019; Deutsche Bundesbank, 2019; European Fiscal Board, 2019). Table 3 presents an
overview of some of the more detailed proposals. Such a provision, often referred to as aGolden Rule,
can be added to the various types of fiscal rules, such as structural balance rules and expenditure rules,
and thus does not really represent a new type of rule. As the EU framework already involves different
types of rules, the goal of such a reform would be to modify an existing or reformed rule (as shown in
Table 3). This could be achieved either by changing the variable constrained by the rule or by reforming
the use and extent of exceptions (see Section 2.2.2).
8
As Heinemann (2018) describes, such changes could be due to factors such as tax competition, which could give rise to structurally lower
revenues despite the fact that the tax code and statutory tax rates remain unchanged.
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
28 PE 645.732
All proposals focus on some form of investment expenditures. However, the general term conceals
differences between what these expenditures actually represent. Whereas the European Fiscal Board
(2019), for example, would only count expenditures which top up the co-financing of EU investment
projects, others use the investment concept as defined in the internationally harmonised national
accounts (some with minor adaptations, such as Truger, 2015), while others still propose a more open
approach where some institution or institutional process decides which expenditures are deductible
and which are not. Similar to the latter, Pisani-Ferry (2019) argues that the EU should define goals that
justify public spending that is temporarily above the limits set by fiscal rules (although this is
conditional on the availability of low long-term interest rates and a country not being in a financially
precarious situation).
As one of the main arguments in favour of a Golden Rule is that investment expenditures also generate
assets which counterbalance debt increases, most proposals focus on net rather than gr oss investment
expenditures (as described in Section 2.2.1). Only the creation of additional assets would thus allow
debt financing. Blanchard and Giavazzi (2004) point out that if, under a Golden Rule, debt financing is
only allowed for net investment expenditures over time, the level of public debt would approach that
of the stock of public capital. Consequently, Deutsche Bundesbank (2019) proposes that such a rule be
applied symmetrically so that negative net investment would not only not allow any debt financing
but would also require budgetary surpluses in relation to negative net investment. One caveat of using
net rather than gross investment figures is that this poses significant methological challenges for
estimating the measure (see Section 2.2.1).
Some proposals set a limit (cap) on the amount of expenditures that can be deducted. This is achieved
either by choosing a fixed amount of, say, 0.5 per cent of GDP (Deutsche Bundesbank, 2019), or,
alternatively, 1 per cent or 1.5 per cent of GDP (Truger, 2015), or by transferring the identification of the
cap to other measures such as the green investment gap identified in the European Semester (Claeys,
2019) or projects identified in the EU Budget (European Fiscal Board, 2019).
Most proposals do not mention any changes to the limits of existing rules after allowing the deduction
of (net) investment expenditures, which means that these proposals seem to place investment
expenditures on top of the existing limits. Consequently, if the current rule sets a limit of 0.5 per cent
of GDP on the structural balance, the new rule would set the same limit of 0.5 per cent of GDP on a
structural balance from which net investment expenditures are subtracted. In contrast, Deutsche
Bundesbank (2019) suggests to reduce previous limits on the residual structural balance by the
maximum amount deductible for net investment purposes.
Furthermore, most proposals would implement the deduction of net investment regardless of the
economic cycle. In contrast, Barbiero and Darvas (2014) argue in favour of an asymmetric Golden R ule,
which provides extra scope for investment only in adverse economic times (and gradually reduces it
again in more benign times). However, this approach might be challenging given the estimation errors
associated with output gaps (see Section 3.2) and the objective of keeping investment levels r elatively
stable over the economic cycle.
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 29
Table 3: Comparison of proposals related to a Golden Rulein the context of the EU fiscal framework
Barbiero and
Darvas (2014)
Blanchard and
Giavazzi (2004)
Claeys (2019) Deutsche
Bundesbank
European Fiscal
Board (2019)
Fitoussi and
Creel (2002)
Truger (2015)
Type of rule
Structural balance
rule in current EU
framework
Based on rules in
2004 EU
framework (i.e. no
structural balance
rule yet)
Adapting
investment
exception clause
in current EU
framework
Structural balance
rule, but limit on
non-investment
reduced (same
MTOs still apply)
New expenditure
rule (see Table 2)
Structural balance
rule
Deficit or
structural balance
rule as in current
EU framework
Deductible
If negative output
gap exceeds a
determined
threshold, net
public investment
Net public
investment
Green investment
related to level of
green investment
gap(identified in
European
Semester)
Net public
investment,
capped at max of
0.5 % of GDP
Top-up
expenditures on
national
investment
projects beyond
co-financing
Public investment
Net public
investment, max.
of 1 % or 1.5 % of
GDP
Identification
of
expenditures
Not specified
Delegated to
Eurostat, should
especially deal
with the incentive
to re-define
current spending
as public
investment
Clear accounting
rules needed, a.o.
taxonomy for
sustainable
finance and rules
for issuance of
green bonds
As in national
accounts
Projects which are
growth-enhancing
and adding pan-
European value as
in EU budget,
opinions by
independent fiscal
institutions
Decision by
European Council
(based on policy
areas that have
been highlighted
as European
priorities)
As in national
accounts minus
military
investment plus
investment grants
to private firms
and non-profit
organisations
Special
features
If negative output
gap is eliminated:
transition period
during which extra
room for deficit is
gradually
eliminated
Specific
investment
agencies for
transparency and
better
management
Issuance of green
bonds to finance
investment
expenditures
Higher deficits if
net investment is
positive, if net
investment
negative
budgetary
objectives stricter
Notes: Net investment figures are broadly defined as gross investment figures net of deprecation.
Sources: Studies as indicated in top row of table, own compilation
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
30 PE 645.732
5.2. Limits Set by Golden Rules
In general, cyclically-adjusted budget balance rules or expenditure rules do not prevent policymakers
from choosing a composition of public expenditures according to their political priorities. In addition
to specific expenditures such as investment as a share of total expenditures, these rules do not place
limits on the level of specific expenditure categories either, as policymakers can alter the level of total
expenditures within the limits of the rules by using discretionary measures on the revenue side.
However, the rules do place limits on the amount of expenditures that can be financed by debt issuance
rather than annual revenues.
9
Fiscal rules are introduced because there are various forms of deficit bias on the part of politicians and
governments, which means that, without any rules, the amount financed by debt issuance would be
higher than is optimal (see Section 1). In addition to this deficit bias, there are various factors that could
create a bias towards less-than-optimal levels of specific expenditures, such as the discrepancy
between which generation has to bear the costs and who benefits from investment expenditures (see
Section 2.2.1). If it were possible to show that politicians are biased in this way when deciding on
specific expenditure categories, this could justify a rule which differentiates between expenditure
categories. A Golden Rule sets a limit to the amount of non-deductible expenditures that can be
financed by debt issuance and either none or a different limit for deductible, like investment,
expenditures.
When deciding on the introduction of a Golden Rule, there is a trade-off to be addressed. Governments
would still be able to choose any composition and level of expenditures, but not independent of the
amount of debt issuance relative to annual revenues. For a given amount of debt issuance and annual
revenues, governments would not be able to freely choose a level of expenditures in specific categories
anymore. Although the general trade-off between rules and choices for governments is similar for any
fiscal rule, a Golden Rule goes beyond the current focus of the EU fiscal framework on cons training
fiscal aggregates and distinguishes between different expenditures in Member States.
Under a Golden Rule there is still a maximum total amount of debt financing which is consistent with
sustainable public finances. The numerical calibration follows the same considerations as described in
Section 4.3. However, the maximum debt limit might be higher if a Golden Rule credibly leads to a
better composition of public expenditures which increases long-term growth rates or reduces interest
rates, e.g. through higher investors’ confidence. For Golden Rules which do not set a limit to the
deductible expenditures, the implicit assumption might be that those can only increase within a range,
e.g. due to capacity constraints, and are thus constrained also without an explicit limit. However,
addressing the bias towards excessively low investment expenditures would not remove the bias
towards excessively high deficits in general. The deficit bias is relevant not only for total expenditures
but also for specific expenditure categories that are not constrained. If current expenditures are limited
by a fiscal rule but investment expenditures are not, it is likely that a bias towards excessively high
deficits will remain, except that it will then be based on investment expenditures or might foster the
usage of ‘creative accounting. For example, common-pool problems and political budget cycles could
then be concentrated on investment expenditures potentially also leading to the realization of less
efficient investments and a weakening of their growth contribution.
This suggests setting a cap on the amount of expenditure that is deductible (as also discussed in some
proposals). It should be noted that this does not set a limit on the maximum level of expenditures in a
9
Depending on the rules’ design this amount can also be negative, i.e. require a budgetary surplus, in some or all years.
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 31
specific category; it merely sets a limit on the amount which can be deducted. If policymakers want to
increase the expenditures in that category beyond what is deductible, they would be able to do so in
full compliance with the rule, e.g. by reducing other non-deductible expenditures or increasing
revenues.
To guarantee the intended effect of the introduction of a Golden Rule, i.e. to increase the quality of
public finances by increasing the share of growth-friendly or future-oriented expenditures, the limit set
for the remaining part of the budget, i.e. for the non-deductible expenditures, would most likely need
to be reduced in accordance with the change of the maximum amount of total debt issuance.
Otherwise, this remaining part would be allowed to increase even without a respective increase in
revenues or deductible expenditures. This could lead to a higher structural deficit due to an increase in
non-deductible expenditures, without necessarily an improvement of the quality of public
expenditures.
A system which allows specific expenditures to be deducted up to a cap and lowers the original rule
limit for the remaining expenditures would effectively constitute two fiscal rules: one setting a limit on
total expenditures (deductible and non-deductible) and a second one setting a limit on the non-
deductible portion of expenditures, with the difference between the two limits being the cap on how
much of the safeguarded expenditures can be deducted. This also shows that such a system can be
designed in a way that does not jeopardise long-term fiscal sustainability.
6. CONCLUSIONS
This paper, first, discusses the benefits of focusing the European fiscal framework on an expenditure
rule. Discussions of reforms often focus on the benefits of expenditure rules in relation to observed
fiscal policy rather than other possible rules or rule designs. However, fiscal policy is often chosen not
only in accordance with the limits set by fiscal rules, but also because of other considerations, s uch that
analysing observed fiscal policy to evaluate the current fiscal framework might be misleading.
Expenditure rules are similar to structural balance rules in various respects. Although there are minor
differences from year to year, both rules per se would have prescribed that fiscal policy in the EU should
have been more-counter cyclical over the past few years. However, expenditure rules achieve this by
imposing a less volatile limit on expenditure growth which, in terms of output stabilisation, can be
either a benefit or a drawback depending on the direction in which the economy is heading. Under the
current framework, it appears not to be the rule design itself but, rather, political decisions outside the
scope of the fiscal rules, non-compliance with these rules, and accompanying regulations like the use
of exceptions that tended to foster pro-cyclical fiscal policy. Like structural balance rules, expenditure
rules are also associated with significant challenges when forecasting and estimating the variables
needed for implementation. These errors are substantial and biased in the case of variables required to
operationalise structural balance rules. They are smaller, although still significant, and less biased, in
the case of expenditures. However, the operationalisation of expenditure rules also requires other
variables, such as discretionary revenue measures, which involve cumbersome estimates and are
associated with a high degree of uncertainty.
The main advantage of expenditure rules is that (almost all) expenditures and discretionary revenue
measures are directly controlled by policymakers. Governments can therefore ensure compliance with
fiscal rules more directly. With the exception of cyclical unemployment-related expenditures and
discretionary revenue measures, most of the expenditure measures are easy to communicate and
involve less complex explanations. This is especially helpful when communicating rule compliance to
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
32 PE 645.732
the general public and the media, which in turn is the most promising lever for increasing the
accountability of politicians and compliance with fiscal rules.
Second, the paper discusses ways of converting a fiscal rule under the European fiscal framework into
a Golden Rule. There is a concern that needs to be adressed first, which is that such a rule would go
beyond the current focus of the EU fiscal framework on fiscal aggregates and distinguish between
different expenditures in Member States. If a Golden Rule is introduced nonetheless, the main
challenge is to clearly and narrowly define the deductible expenditures or expenditure categories
(Section 2.2.1). Once these have been identified, a two-rule system could implement the Golden Rule:
one rule for total (deductible and non-deductible) expenditures and one rule for non-deductible
expenditures only.
One of the main overarching challenges when reforming the EU fiscal framework is to increase
compliance with its fiscal rules. The best-designed fiscal rules are no good if they are not complied with
or if the leeway granted by these rules is not used where it would be advisable. As has been seen in
recent years, discretionary fiscal policy actions rather than fiscal rule design have often tended to
make fiscal policy more pro-cyclical and less focused on fiscal sustainability. A more transparent, more
predictable and less complex framework could make a significant contribution to enhancing
compliance and the role of fiscal rules. Furthermore, it is important to have supporting institutions
such as independent and vocal fiscal councils at the national and European level explaining fiscal
policy and rules. The most important lever is to increase ownership of national governments as well as
the visibility of rules and their compliance for politicians, the general public and the media. This could
give the fiscal rules more impact than any complex system of sanctions or enforcement mechanisms.
REFERENCES
Andrle, M. et al. (2015), Reforming fiscal governance in the European Union, IMF Staff Discussion Note
15/09, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Auerbach, A.J. and Y. Gorodnichenko (2012), Measuring the Output Responses to Fiscal Policy,
American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 4 (2), 127.
Ayuso-i-Casals, J. (2012), National Expenditure Rules Why, How and When, European Economy 473,
Directorate General Economic and Financial Affairs (DG ECFIN), European Commission,
December.
Bacchiocchi, E., E. Borghi and A. Missale (2011), Public investment under fiscal constraints, Fiscal
Studies 32 (1), 1142.
Badinger, H. and W.H. Reuter (2017), The case for fiscal rules, Economic Modelling 60, 334343.
Badinger, H. and W.H. Reuter (2015), Measurement of fiscal rules: Introducing the application of
partially ordered set (POSET) theory, Journal of Macroeconomics 43, 108123.
Barbiero, F. and Z. Darvas (2014), In sickness and in health: Protecting and supporting public
investment in Europe, Bruegel Policy Contribution 2014/02, Bruegel, Brussels.
nassy-Quéré, A. et al. (2018), Reconciling risk sharing with market discipline: a constructive
approach to euro area reform, CEPR Policy Insight 91, Centre for Economic Policy Research,
London.
Blanchard, O.J. and F. Giavazzi (2004), Improving the SGP through a proper accounting of public
investment, CEPR Discussion Paper 4220, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.
Bom, P.R.D. and J.E. Ligthart (2014), What Have We Learned From Three Decades Of Research On The
Productivity Of Public Capital?, Journal of Economic Surveys 28 (5), 889916.
Buettner, T. and B. Kauder (2010), Revenue Forecasting Practices: Differences across Countries and
Consequences for Forecasting Performance, Fiscal Studies 31 (3), 313340.
Burret, H.T. and L.P. Feld (2018), (Un-)intended effects of fiscal rules, European Journal of Political
Economy 52, 166191.
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 33
Buti, M., N. Carnot, A. Hristov, K.M. Morrow, W. Roeger and V. Vandermeulen (2019), Potential output
and EU fiscal surveillance, VoxEU.org.
Buti, M., J.N. Martins and A.A. Turrini (2006), From Deficits to Debt and Back: Political Incentives under
Numerical Fiscal Rules, CEPR Discussion Papers 5809, Centre for Economic Policy Research,
August.
Carnot, N. (2014), Evaluating Fiscal Policy - A Rule of Thumb, European Economy 52, Directorate
General Economic and Financial Affairs (DG ECFIN), European Commission.
Caselli, F. and J. Reynaud (2020), Do fiscal rules cause better fiscal balances? A new instrumental
variable strategy, European Journal of Political Economy 63, 101873.
Caselli, F. and P. Wingender (2018), Bunching at 3 Percent: The Maastricht Fiscal Criterion and
Government Deficits, IMF Working Papers 18/182, International Monetary Fund, August.
Christofzik, D.I., L.P. Feld, W.H. Reuter and M. Yeter (2018), Uniting European fiscal rules: How to
strengthen the fiscal framework, Arbeitspapier 04/2018, Sachverständigenrat zur
Begutachtung der gesamtwirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, Wiesbaden.
Christofzik, D.I., L.P. Feld and M. Yeter (2019), Öffentliche Investitionen: Wie viel ist zu wenig?,
Schweizer Monat Die Autorenzeitschrift für Politik, Wirtschaft und Kultur 1064 (rz).
Claeys, G. (2019), The European Green Deal needs a reformed fiscal framework, Bruegel Blog Post.
Claeys, G., Z.M. Darvas and A. Leandro (2016), A proposal to revive the European fiscal framework,
Bruegel Policy Contribution 2016/07, Bruegel, Brussels.
Cordes, T. et al. (2015), Expenditure Rules: Effective Tools for Sound Fiscal Policy?, IMF Working Papers
15 (29).
Cottarelli, C. (2018), How could the Stability and Growth Pact be simplified?, IN-DEPTH ANALYSIS
Requested by the ECON committee, Economic Governance Support Unit, Brussels, April.
Council of the EU (2020), Statement of EU ministers of finance on the Stability and Growth Pact in
light of the COVID-19 crisis.
Dahan, M. and M. Strawczynski (2013), Fiscal rules and the composition of government expenditures
in OECD countries, Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 32 (3), 484504.
Darvas, Z.M., P. Martin and X. Ragot (2018), European fiscal rules require a major overhaul, Les notes
du conseil d’analyse économique No. 47, French Council of Economic Analysis, Paris.
D’Erasmo, P., E.G. Mendoza and J. Zhang (2016), What is a sustainable public debt?, in: Taylor, J. B. and
H. Uhlig (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. 2, Amsterdam, 24932597.
de Deus, J.D.B.V. and H.F. de Mendonça (2015), Empirical evidence on fiscal forecasting in Eurozone
countries, Journal of Economic Studies 42 (5), 838860.
Deutsche Bundesbank (2019), European Stability and Growth Pact: individual reform options,
Monthly Report, April.
European Commission (2019a), Report on Public Finances in EMU 2018, January.
European Commission (2019b), Vade Mecum on the Stability and Growth Pact, Institutional Paper
101, European Commission, Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs, Brussels,
April.
European Fiscal Board (2019), Assessment of EU fiscal rules with a focus on the six and two-pack
legislation, August.
European Fiscal Board (2018), Annual Report 2018, September.
Eurostat and OECD (2014), EUROSTAT-OECD Survey of National Practices in Estimating Net Stocks of
Structures.
Eyraud, L. et al. (2018a), How to Calibrate Fiscal Rules, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.
Eyraud, L., X. Debrun, A. Hodge, V.D. Lledo and C. Pattillo (2018b), Second-generation fiscal rules:
Balancing simplicity, flexibility, and enforceability, IMF Staff Discussion Note SDN/18/04,
Internationaler Währungsfonds, Washington, DC.
Eyraud, L. and T. Wu (2015), Playing by the Rules: Reforming Fiscal Governance in Europe, IMF
Working Paper WP/15/67, IMF Working Paper WP/15/67, March.
Fatás, A. (2019), Fiscal Policy, Potential Output, and the Shifting Goalposts, IMF Economic Review 67
(3), 684702.
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
34 PE 645.732
Fatas, A. (2019), Are the current “automatic stabilisers” in the Euro Area Member States sufficient to
smooth economic cycles?, IN-DEPTH ANALYSIS Requested by the ECON committee, Economic
Governance Support Unit, Brussels, May.
Fatás, A. and L.H. Summers (2018), The permanent effects of fiscal consolidations, Journal of
International Economics 112, 238250.
Feld, L.P. (2018), The quest for fiscal rules, Freiburg Discussion Papers on Constitutional Economics
18/9, Walter Eucken Institut, Freiburg.
Fitoussi, J.-P. and J. Creel (2002), How to reform the European Central Bank, Centre for European
Reform, London.
Frankel, J. and J. Schreger (2013), Over-optimistic official forecasts and fiscal rules in the eurozone,
Review of World Economics 149 (2), 247272.
GCEE, ‘German Council of Economic Experts’ (2019), Dealing with Structural Change, Annual Report
2019/20.
Gechert, S. and H. Will (2012), Fiscal Multipliers: A Meta Regression Analysis, IMK Working Paper 97, 36.
Ghosh, A.R., J.I. Kim, E.G. Mendoza, J.D. Ostry and M.S. Qureshi (2013), Fiscal Fatigue, Fiscal Space and
Debt Sustainability in Advanced Economies, The Economic Journal 123 (566), F4F30.
Girouard, N. and C. André (2005), Measuring Cyclically-adjusted Budget Balances for OECD Countries,
OECD Economics Department Working Papers 434, OECD Publishing, Paris, 4. July.
von Hagen, J. and G.B. Wolff (2006), What do deficits tell us about debt? Empirical evidence on
creative accounting with fiscal rules in the EU, Journal of Banking & Finance 30 (12), 3259
3279.
Hauptmeier, S., A.J. Sánchez-Fuentes and L. Schuknecht (2015), Spending dynamics in euro area
countries: Composition and determinants, Haciendablica Española / Review of Public
Economics 215 (4/2015), 119138.
Heinemann, F., M.-D. Moessinger and M. Yeter (2018), Do fiscal rules constrain fiscal policy? A meta-
regression-analysis, European Journal of Political Economy 51, 6992.
Kempkes, G. (2012), Cyclical adjustment in fiscal rules: some evidence on real-time bias for EU-15
countries, Discussion paper 15, Deutsche Bundesbank, Frankfurt am Main.
Koen, V. and P. van den Noord (2005), Fiscal Gimmickry in Europe: One-Off Measures and Creative
Accounting, OECD Economics Department Working Papers 417, OECD Publishing, Paris,
February.
Kopits, G. (2018), How could the Stability and Growth Pact be simplified?, IN-DEPTH ANALYSIS
Requested by the ECON committee, Economic Governance Support Unit, Brussels, April.
Larch, M., E. Orseau and W. van der Wielen (2020), Do EU Fiscal Rules Support or Hinder Counter-
Cyclical Fiscal Policy?, JRC Technical Reports.
Lledó, V. and W.H. Reuter (2018), The Dynamics of Fiscal Rule Compliance, Second-Generation Fiscal
Rules - Background Papers, IMF Staff Discussion Note, SDN/18/04, International Monetary
Fund, Washington, D.C.
Merola, R. and J.J. Pérez (2013), Fiscal forecast errors: Governments versus independent agencies?,
European Journal of Political Economy 32, 285299.
Milesi-Ferretti, G.M. (2004), Good, bad or ugly? On the effects of fiscal rules with creative accounting,
Journal of Public Economics 88 (1), 377394.
Mourre, G., C. Astarita and S. Princen (2014), Adjusting the budget balance for the business cycle: the
EU methodology, European Economy - Economic Papers 2008 - 2015 536, Directorate General
Economic and Financial Affairs (DG ECFIN), European Commission, Brüssel.
Navarini, L. and A. Zop (2020), Potential output estimates and their role in the EU fiscal policy
surveillance, Briefing, European Parliament, Economic Governance Support Unit (EGOV),
Brussels.
Perée, E. and T. Väli(2005), Fiscal rules and public investment, Economic and Financial Report
2005/02, Europäische Investitionsbank, Luxemburg.
Pisani-Ferry, J. (2019), When Facts Change, Change the Pact, Project Syndicate Blog.
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 35
Price, R., T.-T. Dang and Y. Guillemette (2014), New Tax and Expenditure Elasticity Estimates for EU
Budget Surveillance, (1174).
Reuter, W.H. (2019), When and why do countries break their national fiscal rules?, European Journal of
Political Economy 57, 125141.
Reuter, W.H. (2015), National numerical fiscal rules: Not complied with, but still effective?, European
Journal of Political Economy 39, 6781.
Romp, W. and J. De Haan (2007), Public Capital and Economic Growth: A Critical Survey, Perspektiven
der Wirtschaftspolitik 8 (S1), 652.
Truger, A. (2015), Implementing the Golden Rule for Public Investment in Europe Safeguarding Public
Investment and Supporting the Recovery, Materialien zu Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft 138,
Working Paper-Reihe der AK-Wien, March.
Turrini, A. (2004), Public investment and the EU fiscal framework, European Economy Economic Paper
202, Euroische Kommission, Brüssel.
Wyplosz, C. (2012), Fiscal Rules: Theoretical Issues and Historical Experiences, Working Paper Series,
Working Paper 17884, National Bureau of Economic Research, March.
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
36 PE 645.732
ANNEX
6.1. Formal Description of Cyclically-Adjusted Balance and Expenditure
Rules
The main part of public expenditures () which systematically changes with the economic cycle are
expenditures related to unemployment (

). Based on estimates of the output gap ( ) the
cyclical unemployment-related expenditures (
 .
) can be estimated. Cyclically-adjusted
expenditures (
 .
), e.g. as calculated by the European Commission, are total expenditures net of
cyclical unemployment-related expenditures:
=
.
+

(

)
 .
=

(

)
.
(

)
(1)
Cyclical revenues

(

)
which depend on the economic cycle make up a much larger part of public
revenues (). The cyclically-adjusted revenues (
.
) are total revenues net of cyclical revenues:
=
.
+

(

)
(2)
A budget balance or deficit rule sets a limit () on the gross budget balance, i.e. the difference between
public revenues and public expenditures. Using Equations 1 and 2 this is equivalent to the sum of the
difference between the cyclically-adjusted revenues and cyclically-adjusted expenditures and the
difference in the cyclical components of revenues and expenditures:
< =
.
.
+

(

)
.
()
(3)
A cyclically-adjusted balance rule takes the economic cycle into account and sets a limit only to the
parts of revenues and expenditures which are independent of the economic cycle, i.e. the level of
revenues and expenditures which would be observed if the output gap was exactly closed. Thus, it sets
a limit () for the difference between cyclically-adjusted revenues and cyclically-adjusted expenditures:
<
.
 .

(

)
.
()
(4)
A structural balance rule is similar but in addition takes temporary, one-off items into account.
Most proposals of expenditure rules would restrict the growth rate in public expenditures net of
(cyclical) unemployment-related expenditures to some limit related to potential GDP growth (
).
> (
.
(

)
)
(5)
The growth of revenues over the medium-term (cyclically-adjusted revenues) is closely related to the
growth of the tax base, which grows approximately with potential GDP. Rearanging Equation 4 and
taking first differences shows the similarity between cyclically-adjusted budget balance and
expenditure rules:
.
> (
.
(

)
) 
.
(6)
6.2. Additional Details on Composition of Public Expenditures in the EU
6.2.1. Development of Specific Expenditure Categories
The share of public investment expenditures (here represented by gross fixed capital formation by the
government) in the EU declined over the long term from 1970 until 1995, which was broadly in line
with the decline seen in other advanced economies (Barbiero and Darvas, 2014). Figure 6 s ho ws that
this share on average is at the same level in 2019 as in 1995 in the EU15. It was equal to 6.9 per cent of
total expenditures in 1995 and 2019. It increased significantly up until the financial crisis and had
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 37
compensated for its decline by 2019. As a share of GDP, however, this catch-up was not evident, which
is why investment as a percentage of GDP declined over the time horizon from 3.5 per cent in 1995 to
3.1 per cent in 2019.
The sharpest drops between 2008 and 2013 were observed in Member States that had financial
assistance programmes, i.e. Ireland (-3.25 pp of GDP), Spain (-2.38 pp), Greece (-2.14 pp) and Portugal
(-1.54 pp), where the relevant shares fell from above-average levels of, for example, more than 5 per
cent in Greece and Ireland to below-average values of close to 2 per cent of GDP. The Eur opean Fis cal
Board (2019) points out that this reduction shows how rapid fiscal consolidations can be accompanied
by a decline in investment.
Figure 6: Public investment expenditures in the EU15 from 1995 to 2019
Notes: Investment expenditures are represented by gross fixed capital formation by the government. Blue areas represent the
range between the maximum and minimum values in each year. Lines represent the mean and mean plus and minus one
standard deviation across Member States.
Sources: European Commission’s AMECO database, own calculations
Figure 7: Public investment expenditures in EU27 from 1995 to 2019
Notes: Investment expenditures represented by gross fixed capital formation of general government. Blue areas represent
range between maximum and mimum value in each year. Lines represent mean and mean plus and minus one standard
deviation across Member States.
Sources: European Commission’s AMECO database, own calculations
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
12%
14%
% of Total Expenditure
Max-Min-Range Mean +/- Std.Dev. Mean
0%
1%
2%
3%
4%
5%
6%
7%
% of GDP
Max-Min-Range
Mean +/- Std.Dev. Mean
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
12%
14%
16%
18%
20%
% of Total Expenditure
Max-Min-Range Mean +/- Std.Dev. Mean
0%
1%
2%
3%
4%
5%
6%
7%
8%
9%
% of GDP
Max-Min-Range Mean +/- Std.Dev. Mean
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
38 PE 645.732
Spending on education has on average also remained stable over the past 22 years in the EU15. The
average relevant share of total expenditures was 10.5 per cent in 1995 and 10.7 per cent in 2018 (Figure
8). At the peak of the current sample in 2002 and 2003 this share was 11.5 per cent. Since then this
share has decreased especially in Portugal (-3.8 pp), the United Kingdom (-2.7 pp) and Finland (-2.3 pp),
all three of which had above-average shares in 2003 (Portugal 14.3 per cent, the United Kingdom 14.5
per cent and Finland 12.7 per cent). The countries with the lowest shares in 2018 were Italy (8.2 per
cent) and Greece (8.3 per cent), which had already had the lowest shares back in 1996.
Figure 8: Public education expenditures in EU15 from 1995 to 2018
Notes: Education expenditures of general government according to COFOG classification. Blue areas represent range
between maximum and mimum value in each year. Lines represent mean and mean plus and minus one standard deviation
across Member States.
Source: Eurostat, own calculations
Figure 9: Public education expenditures in EU27 from 1995 to 2018
Notes: Education expenditures of general government according to COFOG classification. Blue areas represent range
between maximum and mimum value in each year. Lines represent mean and mean plus and minus one standard deviation
across Member States.
Source: Eurostat, own calculations
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
Public Education (% of Total Expenditure)
Max-Min-Range Mean +/- Std.Dev. Mean
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
Public Education (% of GDP)
Max-Min-Range Mean +/- Std.Dev. Mean
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
199519971999
200120032005
200720092011201320152017
% of Total Expenditure
Max-Min-Range Mean +/- Std.Dev. Mean
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
19951997199920012003
2005
20072009201120132015
2017
% of GDP
Max-Min-Range Mean +/- Std.Dev. Mean
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 39
Spending on basic research and R&D as a percentage of total expenditures in the EU15 increased on
average by 0.46 percentage points between 2001 and 2018 (Figure 10). In contrast to investment and
education expenditures this spending did not drop sharply during the financial crisis. As a percentage
of GDP (shown in Figure 10), there was actually a pronounced increase during the financial crisis, i.e.
while GDP decreased during these years, R&D expenditures increased or at least remained stable. In
Germany, for example, research expenditures formed part of the fiscal stimulus packages introduced
in response to the crisis.
Figure 10: Public basic research and R&D expenditures in the EU15 from 2001 to 2018
Notes: Share of the sum of expenditures on basic research and research & development (R&D) by the government in various
categories according to COFOG classification. Blue areas represent the range between the maximum and minimum values in
each year. Lines represent the mean and mean plus and minus one standard deviation across Member States.
Sources: Eurostat, own calculations
Figure 11: Public basic research and R&D expenditures in EU25 from 2001 to 2018
Notes: Share of sum of expenditures on basic research and research and development (R&D) of general government in
various categories according to COFOG classification. EU27 without Bulgaria and Lithuania. Blue areas represent range
between maximum and mimum value in each year. Lines represent mean and mean plus and minus one standard deviation
across Member States.
Source: Eurostat, own calculations
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
4
4.5
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
Basic research and R&D (% of Total Expenditure)
Max-Min-Range Mean +/- Std.Dev. Mean
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
Basic research and R&D (% of GDP)
Max-Min-Range Mean +/- Std.Dev. Mean
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
3
3.5
4
4.5
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
% of Total Expenditure
Max-Min-Range
Mean +/- Std.Dev.
Mean
0
0.5
1
1.5
2
2.5
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
% of GDP
Max-Min-Range Mean +/- Std.Dev. Mean
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
40 PE 645.732
6.2.2. Specific Expenditure Categories during Fiscal Consolidations
Specific expenditures like the ones discussed in the previous section might be reduced (relative to
others) first and most sharply during fiscal consolidations. The upper panel of Table 4 presents the
correlation of changes in these expenditures with changes in the cyclically-adjusted fiscal balance. If
the latter is positive, this is a period of discretionary fiscal consolidation (not due to the economic cycle),
while if it is negative it corresponds to periods of discretionary fiscal expansion. The results show that
these expenditure categories when measured as a percentage of GDP do indeed seem to be
negatively correlated. Investment expenditures in particular tend to decrease as a share of GDP in times
of consolidation and increase in times of expansion. This also becomes evident in the lower panel of
Table 4, which shows that, during fiscal consolidations, investment expenditures have on average
decreased by 0.17 percentages points as a share of GDP. In the case of education and R&D
expenditures, correlations and average changes in times of fiscal consolidation are very small, which
means that the development of these categories seems to be largely independent of phases of
consolidation and expansion.
During periods of fiscal consolidation one would usually expect expenditures to grow more slowly or
to be reduced, so the observation of decreases in levels or percentages of GDP in expenditure
categories is not surprising. However, the question is whether specific expenditure categories are
reduced relative to other categories. Looking at expenditure categories as a share of total expenditures
reveals that based on correlations (upper panel) and averages (lower panel) education and R&D
expenditures as a share of total expenditures increased during fiscal consolidations. In other words,
these categories were less affected than other categories. The positive correlation is relatively high for
education expenditures in particular. The correlation is virtually zero in the case of investment
expenditures, so there seems to be no clear relationship between changes in the cyclically-adjusted
budget balance and the relevant share of investment expenditures.
Overall, the results suggest that expenditures on investment and, to a smaller extent, on education as
well as basic research and R&D are reduced as a percentage of GDP during periods of fiscal
consolidation. However, expenditures on education as well as basic research and R&D are affected less
than other expenditure categories, which means that their share of total expenditures increases.
Overall, the share accounted for by investment expenditures does not seem to be systematically
related to periods of fiscal consolidation or expansion.
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 41
Table 4: Fiscal consolidations and specific public expenditure categories
Investment
Education
Basic research, R&D
1995-2018
1995-2018
2001-2018
Correlation of changes in the cyclically-adjusted fiscal balance (% of potential GDP) with changes in…
% of total
expenditures
EU15 0.003 0.608 0.201
EU27
-0.045
0.467
0.126
% of GDP
EU15
-0.296
-0.122
-0.094
EU27
-0.231
-0.102
-0.117
Average change during years of fiscal consolidation (cyc.-adj. fiscal balance improved by more than 0.5 pp)
% of total
expenditures
EU15 -0.148 0.173 0.053
EU27
-0.203
0.180
0.061
% of GDP
EU15
-0.166
-0.060
0.003
EU27
-0.185
-0.065
-0.002
Sources: European Commission’s AMECO database, Eurostat, own calculations
6.3. Forecast Errors based on AMECO Vintages
The European Commission publishes its macro-economic database AMECO twice a year (in spring and
in autumn) including forecasts for the coming years. Each publication is called “vintage” of the AMECO
database and currently the vintages from spring 2011 to autumn 2019 can be downloaded from the
European Commissions website. For some key variables data from older vintages are available to
download at the website of the EU funded Horizon 2020 projectFirstrun”. The project publishes data
from AMECO vintages starting in spring 2000.
In the context of this paper, the two-year ahead forecast error (
) of variables measured in Euros, like
expenditures, revenues or GDP, () for a specific year is defined as the percentage of GDP ()
difference between the value of the variable in the vintage of autumn four years after that specific year,
i.e. in + 4, and the forecast in the vintage of autumn two years ahead of the specific year, i.e. 2.

,
=


where

is the variable for year observed in the autumn vintage of year + 4. The vintage in +
4 is used as benchmark, instead of e.g. the last currently available vintage, to guarantee that the same
time has passed between the forecast and ex-post data for all observations. The largest revisions
usually happen within the first four years. Afterwards revisions still occur but in general they are
considerably smaller.
When comparing data across vintages data revisions, changes of base years and changes of accounting
rules pose a problem. To deal with this, this paper follows Fatás and Summers (2018) and rebases the
variables using an adjustment factor. This approach uses the ratio of observations for a year for which
the data lies in the past in both vintages, i.e. 3, to adjust the values in the older vintage.
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
42 PE 645.732
=



,
=



For potential GDP also data of past years are still an estimation at the time of the publication of a
vintage. Therefore, in case of potential GDP the adjustment factor as in Fatás and Summers (2018) is
based on past values for actual GDP.
The exercises in this paper do not only use two-year ahead forecast errors, but also one-year ahead
(
) and real-time (
) errors. The latter calculates the error based on the values published in the
vintage in autumn of year for this year .

,
=

For variables, which are differences and are expressed in percentage of (potential) GDP, like fiscal
balance, growth rates, structural balance or output gap, the approach described above is not feasible.
However, as for percentages of GDP the numerator and denominator are both within one vintage,
problems of different base years or changes of accounting rules are of less concerns. Thus, for those
variables the forecast error is defined as the simple percentage point difference between the value in
the autumn vintage of + 4 and the forecast of the variable in the autumn vintage of 2, 1 or .
6.4. Calculation of past growth rates of cyclically-adjusted revenue,
potential GDP and expenditures
The calculations in this section are based on the same dataset as described in Annex 6.3. As cyclically-
adjusted revenues and the cyclical component of expenditures are both not part of the Firstrun dataset
(i.e. older vintages), a workaround is used to calculate the limit for expenditure growth which would
keep the cyclically-adjusted budget balance constant. By summing up total expenditures (UUTGE) and
the cyclically-adjusted budget balance (UBLGAP), which are both available for the longer time period,
the sum of cyclically-adjusted revenues and the cyclical component of expenditures is obtained.
Expenditures are allowed to increase by the growth rate of this sum to keep the cyclically-adjusted
balance constant.

 .
=
.
 .
=

(

)
.
(

)

.
=
.
 .
(

)
The cyclically-adjusted budget balance (UBLGAP) is only available in percent of GDP for the longer time
series (based on Firstrun data), while total expenditures (UUTGE) are measured in nominal terms. Thus,
the former is multiplied with nominal GDP (UVGDH) to receive the cyclically-adjusted budget balance
in nominal terms. As a cross-check for the time period in which data overlaps, the direct sum of
cyclically-adjusted revenues (URTGAP) and the cyclical component of expenditures (UUCGCP) is
compared with the measures obtained through above described workaround. The values (except for
rounding differences) are identical.
Most expenditure rules discussed in this paper use some measure related to potential GDP growth as
limits. If expenditures are measured in nominal terms, so should be potential GDP (OVGDP). Thus, for
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 43
the calculations in this section it is multiplied with the BIP deflator (UVGDH / OVGD). Furthermore, some
proposals use contemporaneous potential GDP growth, others some averages across past or future
years. Figure 12 first compares nominal potential GDP between forecast, real-time and ex-post for
annual data and for a moving average. It seems that forecasted growth rates lag developments seen in
ex-post numbers. I.e. while forecast potential GDP growth was (much) higher than ex-post figures
between 2008 and 2015, it was lower afterwards. This observeration remains valid when taking
averages, but the difference becomes smaller. In contrast to forecasts the difference between real-time
and ex-post estimates of potential GDP growth seems small, especially when taking averages it is very
small. Figure 12 also compares different averages at various estimation points with the annual potential
GDP growth rates. As intended, taking averages over longer time periods smoothens changes in
potential GDP growth and if growth rates are lower for more than a few years this lower growth rates
become visible in the averages later. Thus, in the period between 2000 and 2019, various averages of
growth rates were approximately equal or higher than actual potential GDP growth for most years until
2016. The strong increase in potential GDP in ex-post data in 2014 can be attributed to Ireland, without
Ireland the growth rate in 2014 would be 2.1 %.
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
44 PE 645.732
Figure 12: Comparison of measures of potential GDP growth (forecast, real-time, ex-post)
Source: European Commission’s AMECO database, Firstrun project, own calculations
Most expenditure rules do not set a limit to gross total public expenditures, but to some adjusted
measure subtracting and estimating various parts. Figure 13 compares growth rates of different
measures of expenditures. However, some of the more detailed variables are not available over longer
time periods. For primary expenditures, i.e. total expenditures net of interest payments, the interest
payments are calculated as difference between net lending excluding interest (UBLGIE) and net lending
(UBLGE), which are both available in the longer dataset. Those interest payments are then subtracted
from total expenditures (UUTGE) to receive primary expenditures. Estimates of the cyclical component
of expenditures (UUCGCP) are available for vintages since 2011 and estimates of discretionary revenues
measures only since 2014. Figure 13 shows that growth rates for primary expenditures in real-time and
ex-post seem to be very close, which confirms the findings regarding forecast and real-time errors in
Section 3.2. Furthermore, at least in real-time there seems to be almost no difference between total
expenditure and primary expenditure growth rates. However, the difference of those to the estimates
subtracting the cyclical component and discretionary revenues measures can be quite large, with the
0.00%
1.00%
2.00%
3.00%
4.00%
5.00%
6.00%
7.00%
2000 2002 2004 2006
2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
Nominal potential GDP growth
t-2 t t+4
0.00%
1.00%
2.00%
3.00%
4.00%
5.00%
6.00%
7.00%
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
Average nominal pot. GDP growth
t-2 t t+4
0.00%
1.00%
2.00%
3.00%
4.00%
5.00%
6.00%
7.00%
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
Nominal potential GDP growth:
Forecast
Nominal potential GDP in t
5-year backward looking average
10-year backward looking average
2year back & 2 year front
0.00%
1.00%
2.00%
3.00%
4.00%
5.00%
6.00%
7.00%
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
Nominal potential GDP growth:
Real-time
Nominal potential GDP in t
Average potential GDP growth
10-year backward looking average
2year back & 2 year front
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732 45
most comprehensive measure showing a growth rate which is on average 1.2 percentage points higher
between 2014 and 2019 in real-time than for primary expenditure.
Figure 13: Comparison of growth rates of different measures of public expenditure
Source: European Commissions AMECO database, Firstrun project, own calculations
Only growth rates are compared in the exercises of this section and each growth rate is calculated only
within one vintage of the database. Thus, no adjustment is applied to the data. However, it cannot be
excluded that changes of accounting rules or changes of base years might still have an effect also on
growth rates across different vintages. Nevertheless, the issue should be much less severe than when
comparing levels across vintages.
-2.00%
0.00%
2.00%
4.00%
6.00%
8.00%
10.00%
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
Primary expenditures
t-2 t t+4
-2.00%
-1.00%
0.00%
1.00%
2.00%
3.00%
4.00%
5.00%
6.00%
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
Expenditure growth rates (Real-time)
Expenditures
Primary expenditure
… net of cyclical component
... net of discretionary revenues measures
IPOL | Economic Governance Support Unit
46 PE 645.732
6.5. Additional results regarding forecast and real-time estimation errors
Table 5: Mean absolute errors and mean errors of forecasts and real-time estimates
Notes: Calculations based on number of observations stated in N. Errors calculated as difference between values for year t in autumn vintage of year t-2, t-1 and t compared to values in
autumn vintage of year t+4. Mean errors are calculated as mean across countries and time of the difference between values for year t values in autumn vintage of year t+4 and in autumn
vintage of year t-2, t-1 and t. Mean absolute errors are the mean of the absolute values of the differences. To make results comparable only years and vintage are included which are
available for all variables (or a specific variable in last column) in all years and countries. More details on calculations can be found in Annex 6.3. Abs.: Mean absolute error. Budget balance:
Net lending or borrowing. pp.: differences in percentage points. Sources: European Commission’s AMECO database, Firstrun project, own calculations
EU 15, 2005-2015 EU13 (wo EL, IE), 2005-2015 EU15, without 2007 & 2008 EU27, 2007-2015 Max. obs. for each variable
Abs. Mean N Abs. Mean N Abs. Mean N Abs. Mean N Abs. Mean N
Real GDP t-2 3.46 -1.37 164 2.87 -1.18 142 3.74 -1.76 134 4.74 -1.96 239 4.10 -0.96 379
(% of GDP) t-1 2.10 -0.39 164 1.74 -0.37 142 2.20 -0.33 134 2.72 -0.53 239 2.36 0.10 379
t 0.81 0.11 164 0.61 0.03 142 0.79 0.25 134 0.91 0.21 239 0.85 0.34 379
Potential GDP t-2 2.90 -1.60 164 2.37 -1.62 142 2.94 -1.40 134 3.96 -2.09 239 3.54 -1.81 295
(% of GDP) t-1 2.13 -1.00 164 1.77 -1.09 142 1.90 -0.54 134 2.78 -1.08 239 2.54 -0.98 295
t 1.49 -0.58 164 1.26 -0.74 142 1.29 -0.17 134 1.75 -0.36 239 1.72 -0.52 295
Revenues t-2 2.34 0.03 164 2.13 0.18 142 2.35 -0.33 134 2.29 0.25 219
(% of GDP) t-1 1.56 0.22 164 1.40 0.31 142 1.63 0.21 134 1.65 0.43 219
t 0.69 0.26 164 0.63 0.29 142 0.70 0.33 134 0.73 0.38 219
Expenditures t-2 1.52 0.38 164 1.22 0.23 142 1.47 0.21 134 1.65 0.37 219
(% of GDP) t-1 1.12 0.45 164 0.81 0.18 142 1.11 0.38 134 1.26 0.48 219
t 0.64 0.11 164 0.56 0.01 142 0.64 0.06 134 0.75 0.24 219
Output Gap t-2 2.22 0.19 164 2.02 0.40 142 2.07 -0.41 134 2.53 0.08 239 2.46 0.40 294
(pp.) t-1 1.80 0.61 164 1.69 0.72 142 1.63 0.19 134 2.05 0.58 239 2.06 0.82 294
t 1.27 0.72 164 1.16 0.78 142 1.11 0.43 134 1.42 0.63 239 1.48 0.82 294
Budget balance t-2 2.50 -0.75 164 2.10 -0.32 142 2.59 -0.97 134 2.56 -0.73 239 2.36 -0.45 300
(pp.) t-1 1.88 -0.45 164 1.51 -0.02 142 1.95 -0.44 134 1.87 -0.50 239 1.78 -0.26 300
t 0.90 0.00 164 0.77 0.18 142 0.89 0.11 134 0.98 -0.10 239 0.97 -0.03 300
Cyclically-adjusted t-2 2.09 -0.77 164 1.65 -0.46 142 2.12 -0.67 134 2.31 -0.63 239 2.15 -0.62 283
budget balance (pp.) t-1 1.65 -0.68 164 1.28 -0.32 142 1.58 -0.44 134 1.81 -0.64 239 1.71 -0.57 283
t 1.01 -0.31 164 0.87 -0.18 142 0.89 -0.03 134 1.16 -0.29 239 1.12 -0.30 283
Growth of potential t-2 0.99 -0.47 164 0.66 -0.50 142 1.03 -0.39 134 1.42 -0.73 239 1.25 -0.64 295
GDP (p.p.) t-1 0.79 -0.20 164 0.51 -0.26 142 0.77 -0.04 134 1.08 -0.34 239 0.96 -0.32 295
2
t 0.63 -0.05 164 0.39 -0.14 142 0.62 0.08 134 0.74 -0.05 239 0.70 -0.11 295
Structural balance t-2 2.35 -0.30 215
(pp.) t-1 1.66 -0.15 215
t 1.04 0.20 215
Benefits and drawbacks of an “expenditure rule”, as well as of a "golden rule", in the EU fiscal framework
PE 645.732
IP/A/ECON-ED/IC/2020-055
Print ISBN 978-92-846-6868-7 | doi: 10.2861/222285 | QA-01-20-416-EN-C
PDF ISBN 978-92-846-6869-4 | doi: 10.2861/147212 | QA-01-20-416-EN-N
Focusing the EU fiscal framework on an expenditure rule could help to increase transparency,
compliance and ownership. In various other respects, like estimation errors or counter-cyclicality of
the prescribed fiscal policy, an expenditure rule is similar to a structural balance rule.
If the EU decides to go beyond the current focus on fiscal aggregates, a two-rule system aimed at
safeguarding specific expenditures could be placed at the centre of the EU fiscal framework. The key
challenge is to define and measure the protected expenditures.
This document was provided by the Economic Governance Support Unit at the request of the ECON
Committee).