ECONOMICS
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 1 11/24/18 11:03 AM
The McGraw-Hill Series in Economics
EssEntials of Economics
Brue, McConnell, and Flynn
Essentials of Economics
Fourth Edition
Mandel
Economics: The Basics
M: Economics—The Basics
Third Edition
Schiller
Essentials of Economics
Tenth Edition
PrinciPlEs of Economics
Asarta and Butters
Connect Master: Economics
Second Edition
Colander
Economics, Microeconomics,
and Macroeconomics
Eleventh Edition
Frank, Bernanke, Antonovics, and Heffetz
Principles of Economics, Principles
of Microeconomics, and Principles of
Macroeconomics
Seventh Edition
Frank, Bernanke, Antonovics, and Heffetz
A Streamlined Approach for:
Principles of Economics, Principles
of Microeconomics, and Principles of
Macroeconomics
Third Edition
Karlan and Morduch
Economics, Microeconomics, and
Macroeconomics
Second Edition
McConnell, Brue, and Flynn
Economics, Microeconomics, and
Macroeconomics
Twenty-First Edition
McConnell, Brue, and Flynn
Brief Editions: Microeconomics and
Macroeconomics
Third Edition
Samuelson and Nordhaus
Economics, Microeconomics, and
Macroeconomics
Nineteenth Edition
Schiller
The Economy Today, The Micro
Economy Today, and The Macro
Economy Today
Fifteenth Edition
Slavin
Economics, Microeconomics, and
Macroeconomics
Eleventh Edition
Economics of social issuEs
Guell
Issues in Economics Today
Seventh Edition
Register and Grimes
Economics of Social Issues
Twenty-First Edition
EconomEtrics and data
a
nalytics
Hilmer and Hilmer
Practical Econometrics
First Edition
Prince
Predictive Analytics for Business
Strategy
First Edition
managErial Economics
Baye and Prince
Managerial Economics and Business
Strategy
Ninth Edition
Brickley, Smith, and Zimmerman
Managerial Economics and
Organizational Architecture
Sixth Edition
Thomas and Maurice
Managerial Economics
Twelfth Edition
intErmEdiatE Economics
Bernheim and Whinston
Microeconomics
Second Edition
Dornbusch, Fischer, and Startz
Macroeconomics
Thirteenth Edition
Frank
Microeconomics and Behavior
Ninth Edition
advancEd Economics
Romer
Advanced Macroeconomics
Fifth Edition
monEy and Banking
Cecchetti and Schoenholtz
Money, Banking, and Financial
Markets
Fifth Edition
urBan Economics
O’Sullivan
Urban Economics
Ninth Edition
laBor Economics
Borjas
Labor Economics
Eighth Edition
McConnell, Brue, and Macpherson
Contemporary Labor Economics
Eleventh Edition
PuBlic financE
Rosen and Gayer
Public Finance
Tenth Edition
EnvironmEntal Economics
Field and Field
Environmental Economics:
An Introduction
Seventh Edition
intErnational Economics
Appleyard and Field
International Economics
Ninth Edition
Pugel
International Economics
Seventeenth Edition
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 2 11/24/18 11:03 AM
ELEVENTH EDITION
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 3 11/24/18 11:03 AM
Economics
David C. Colander
Middlebury College
ECONOMICS, ELEVENTH EDITION
Published by McGraw-Hill Education, 2 Penn Plaza, New York, NY 10121. Copyright ©2020 by
McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. Printed in the United States of America. Previous editions
©2017, 2013, and 2010. No part of this publication may be reproduced or distributed in any form or by
any means, or stored in a database or retrieval system, without the prior written consent of McGraw-Hill
Education, including, but not limited to, in any network or other electronic storage or transmission, or
broadcast for distance learning.
Some ancillaries, including electronic and print components, may not be available to customers outside
the United States.
This book is printed on acid-free paper.
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 LWI 21 20 19
ISBN 978-1-260-22558-7 (bound edition)
MHID 1-260-22558-5 (bound edition)
ISBN 978-1-260-50694-5 (loose-leaf edition)
MHID 1-260-50694-0 (loose-leaf edition)
Director: Anke Weekes
Senior Product Developer: Christina Kouvelis
Marketing Manager: Bobby Pearson
Lead Content Project Manager, core: Christine Vaughan
Senior Content Project Manager, assessment: Bruce Gin
Senior Buyer: Laura Fuller
Designer: Egzon Shaqiri
Content Licensing Specialist: Melissa Homer
Cover Image: ©amiak/Shutterstock
Compositor: Aptara
®
, Inc.
All credits appearing on page or at the end of the book are considered to be an extension of the copyright
page.
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Names: Colander, David C., author.
Title: Economics / David C. Colander, Middlebury College.
Description: Eleventh edition. | New York, NY : McGraw-Hill Education, [2020]
Identifiers: LCCN 2018046218 | ISBN 9781260225587 (alk. paper) | ISBN
1260225585 (alk. paper)
Subjects: LCSH: Economics.
Classification: LCC HB171.5 .C788 2020 | DDC 330—dc23 LC record available at
https://lccn.loc.gov/2018046218
The Internet addresses listed in the text were accurate at the time of publication. The inclusion of a
website does not indicate an endorsement by the authors or McGraw-Hill Education, and McGraw-Hill
Education does not guarantee the accuracy of the information presented at these sites.
mheducation.com/highered
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 4 11/24/18 11:03 AM
About the
Author
Courtesy of David Colander
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii.indd 5 04/12/18 9:52 AM
David Colander is Distinguished College Professor at Middlebury College.
He has authored, coauthored, or edited over 40 books and over 200 articles on a
wide range of economic topics.
He earned his BA at Columbia College and his MPhil and PhD at Columbia
University
. He also studied at the University of Birmingham in England and at
Wilhelmsburg Gymnasium in Germany. Professor Colander has taught at
Columbia University, Vassar College, the University of Miami, and Princeton
University as the Kelley Professor of Distinguished Teaching. He has also been
a consultant to Time-Life Films, a consultant to Congress, a Brookings Policy
Fellow, and Visiting Scholar at Nuffield College, Oxford.
Professor Colander has been president of both the History of Economic
Thought Society and the Eas
tern Economics Association. He has also served on
the editorial boards of The Journal of Economic Perspectives, The Journal of
Economic Education, The Journal of Economic Methodology, The Journal of the
History of Economic Thought, The Journal of Socio-Economics, and The Eastern
Economic Journal. He has been chair of the American Economic Association
Committee on Electronic Publishing, a member of the AEA Committee on
Economic Education, and is currently the associate editor for content of The
Journal of Economic Education.
He is married to a pediatrician, Patrice. In their spare time, the Colanders
designed and built an oak post-and-beam house on a ridg
e overlooking the Green
Mountains to the east and the Adirondacks to the west. The house is located on
the site of a former drive-in movie theater. (They replaced the speaker poles with
fruit trees and used the I-beams from the screen as support for the second story of
the carriage house and the garage.) They now live in both Florida and Vermont.
vi
Preface
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 6 11/24/18 11:03 AM
Economics is about ideas, not models. The goal of this
text is to convey to students the ideas that make up mod-
ern economics. The ideas are both about the way the
economy works, and about how to design policy to make
the economy work better.
How This Book Differs
from Others
Ideas are nuanced; models are not. From its beginning, this
book has provided a nuanced narrative that emphasizes
both ideas and models. Its distinctive features have been
itsconversational style and its inclusion of different views
within mainstream economics. It doesnt offer a cookie cut-
ter presentation of material, but instead offers a blend of
logical model building and nuanced discussion of applying
the models. The writing style is conversational, designed to
allow the student to feel a connection with me—the
writer—to make it clear that I am a human being, not a ma-
chine. This approach is particularly welcomed as students
spend more and more time learning material online.
Even while spending a lot of time online, students seek
personal connections. It still makes my day when students
whom I’ve never met in person write me thanking me for
making the course fun and for relating to them. I’m delighted
with the reception this book has received, and the loyal
following who have used, and continue to use, the book.
While the book is consciously mainstream, it differs from
most other top books in its tone. It presents economic theory
more as a changing heuristic than as an unchanging scientific
theory. So, while the discussion of the models is the same as
in other books, the discussion of the application of the mod-
els is different. I emphasize the difficulties of applying the
models while most principles books gloss over them.
Nuanced Economics: Teaching
More Than Models
Recent economic pedagogy has shifted away from seeing
textbooks as a narrative, to seeing them as a compilation
of models that can be presented in separable building
blocks or modules. This modularization of the teaching of
economic principles involves dividing economic knowl-
edge into learning objectives, sub learning objectives, and
sub-sub learning objectives.
This building block approach makes lots of sense as
long as one remembers that you also need mortar and
architectural blueprints to hold the building blocks to-
gether
. That mortar and those blueprints are embedded in
the texts narrative. Unfortunately, mortar and blueprints
dont fit nicely into building block modules captured by
learning objectives. Mortar and blueprints require con-
ceptualization that goes beyond the standard models—
conceptualization that brings the big picture into focus.
And, because there are a variety of architectural blue-
prints, there is not a single, but a variety of, big pictures;
models highlight only one of those blueprints.
The study of such issues is the grist for “big think”
economics that characterizes this book where nuance is
integrated into understanding, and students see the im-
portance of mortar. Consideration of such issues often
goes under the heading of critical thought. To learn to
think critically students have to be presented with some
questions without definitive answers, but ones upon
which, when addressed creatively, economic models can
shed light. My book contains lots of such questions.
My approach to models follows the approach Alfred
Marshall used back when he first introduced the supply/
demand model into the principles course. Marshall em-
phasized that economics was an approach to problems,
not a body of confirmed truths. In my view, the modeling
method, not the models, is the most important element of
an economic understanding. In my presentation of mod-
els, I carefully try to guide students in the modeling
method, rather than having them memorize truths from
models. I carefully emphasize the limitations of the mod-
els and the assumptions that underlie them, and am con-
stantly urging students to think beyond the models. This
approach pushes the students a bit harder than the alterna-
tive, but it is, in my view, the best pedagogical approach;
it is the critical thinking approach.
When taking a critical thinking approach two princi-
ples stand out: (1) Institutions and history are important
in policy discussions and (2) good economics is open to
dealing with various viewpoints. Let me discuss each of
these principles briefly.
Institutions and History Are Important to
Understand Policy
If you open up Adam Smiths Wealth of Nations, John
Stuart Mill’s Principles of Political Economy, or Alfred
Marshall’s Principles of Economics, you will see eco-
nomic analysis placed in historical and institutional
Preface vii
context. The modern textbook template moved away from
that, and in previous editions, I have tried to return the
principles of economics toward that broader template,
presenting models in a historical and institutional context.
This edition continues that emphasis on institutions and
history. Modern work in game theory and strategic deci-
sion making is making it clear that the implications of
economic reasoning depend on the institutional setting.
To understand economics requires an understanding of
existing institutions and the historical development of
those institutions. In a principles course we dont have
time to present much about history and institutions,
butthat does not preclude us from letting students know
that these issues are important. And thats what I try to do.
When I say that institutions and history are important,
I am talking especially about economic policy. This text
and the accompanying supplements are not designed for
future economics majors. Most principles students arent
going to go on in economics. I write for students who will
probably take only one or two economics courses in their
lifetime. These students are interested in policy, and what
I try to present to them is modern economic reasoning
relevant to policy questions.
Because I think policy is so important in explaining
how to apply economic reasoning, I utilize a distinction
made by J. N. Keynes (John Maynard Keynes’ father) and
Classical economists generally. That distinction is be-
tween theorems—the deductive conclusions of models—
and precepts—the considered judgments of economists
about the policy implications of the models. I make it
clear to students that models do not tell us what to do
about policy—they give us theorems. Only when we
combine the models’ results with our understanding of
institutions, our understanding of the social context, and
our understanding of the normative goals we want to
achieve, can we arrive at policy conclusions embodied in
precepts.
Openness to Various Views
While I present modern economics, I present it in such a
way that is open to many different points of view. I don’t
present the material as “the truth” but simply as the con-
ventional wisdom. Learning conventional wisdom is a
useful hurdle for all students to jump over. To encourage
students to question conventional wisdom, at the end of
each chapter I include a set of questions—Questions from
Alternative Perspectives—written by economists from a
variety of different perspectives. These include Post-
Keynesian, Feminist, Austrian, Radical, Institutionalist,
and Religious perspectives. Each is described further in
the “Distinguishing Features” section that follows the
preface. The Radical questions come from the Dollars
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 7 11/24/18 11:03 AM
and Sense Collective, a group with whom I’ve worked to
coordinate their readers (www.dollarsandsense.org/
bookstore.html) with this text. I also often integrate Aus-
trian ideas into my class; I find that The Free Market
(www.mises.org) is a provocative resource.
I often pair an article in The Free Market with one in
Dollars and Sense in my assignments to students for sup-
plementary reading. Having students read both Radical
and Austrian views, and then integrate those views into
more middle-of-the-road views is, for me, a perfect way
to teach the principles course. (If I have a lot of radicals
and libertarians in the class, I assign them articles that
advocate more middle-of-the-road views.)
Integrating Nuance into the
Learning Platform
Changes in technology are changing the medium through
which ideas are conveyed and the way students learn. Stu-
dents today dont know a time without the Internet and
social media, which provide them with access to a broad
range of digital resources and instant feedback. Technol-
ogy has changed the way they learn, and if we are to reach
them, we have to present material in ways that fit their
learning style. They want to be able to access their
courses anywhere, anytime—at a coffee shop in the after-
noon, in their dorm room late at night, or at lunch hour at
work. They still want material that speaks to them, but it
has to speak to them in their language at the time they
want to listen. Modern learning is blended learning in
which online presentations, review, testing of material,
and feedback are seamlessly blended with the narrative of
the text. This revision is designed to improve what the
publisher calls the learning platform in both the content
presented and in the delivery of that content.
I think of this book as consisting of both the text and
the delivery system for the text. For the book to succeed,
the online delivery system has to deliver the material to
students in a manner that they can access both online and
in the physical book. The new reality of accessing books
online has driven important changes in the last edition,
and in this edition. Specifically, while the content and
pedagogical approach described above remain largely the
same, the delivery is different.
In the last two editions the learning platform was re-
fined, and all of the content, including end-of-chapter
questions, was made to line up directly with learning
objectives. These learning objectives serve as the organi-
zational structure for the material. The learning objectives
themselves were broken down into further learning objec-
tives associated with concepts that are presented in bite-
sized portions of the text as part of the SmartBook offer.
viii Preface
This now allows students the opportunity to master con-
cepts that support the larger picture no matter how they
access it in the Colander learning platform. Within
McGraw-Hill’s Connect and SmartBook platforms, stu-
dents can learn the core building blocks online with in-
stant feedback; instructors can assess student learning data
and know what their students understand, and what they
dont. With that information, they can devote class time to
those issues with which students are having problems.
In the previous two editions, the end-of-chapter ma-
terial was also restructured for online delivery: All of
the standard questions and problems were made auto-
gradable and integrated with the online experience.
Such integration allows students to move seamlessly
between homework problems and portions of the narra-
tive to get the information they need, when they need it.
This is a significant advance in pedagogy. Now, even
professors inlarge lecture classes can assign questions
and exercises at the end of chapters and provide feed-
back to students at the point of need.
While the new learning platforms made the teaching
of the building blocks easier, they presented a challenge
for my approach that emphasized the nuance of interpre-
tation as a key element of what students were to learn.
That discussion of nuance was scattered throughout the
text; it wasnt a building block to be learned in one place.
Rather it was mortar to be learned over the course of the
entire semester. This learning goal did not come through
in the learning platform as strongly as it did in the text it-
self. While the modular learning platform worked well in
teaching a building block approach to models, it didnt
work so well helping students understand the context of
the models. It provided the building blocks but not the
mortar. So the previous versions of my online learning
platforms emphasized models a bit more than I would
have liked and context a bit less.
The nuance material was still there, but it was not in-
tegrated into the learning platform as much as I thought it
should be. In previous editions, I did what I could to ac-
count for that. Specifically I added aspects of the book
that allowed professors who wanted to emphasize nuance
to do so. These included two sets of end-of-chapter ques-
tions, Issues to Ponder and Questions from Alternative
Perspectives, which have no “correct” answer, but instead
are designed to get the students to think. In a learning
environment that blends both online and in-person expe-
riences, these are the questions that can form the basis for
rich classroom discussions that engage the students with
broad issues as much as the online material engages them
with the building blocks.
In this edition I go a step further in integrating nuance
into the course. Specifically, I have essentially made
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 8 11/24/18 11:03 AM
nuance its own general learning objective—a learning
objective that relates to the entire book. So in addition to
the learning objectives specific to individual chapters,
there is a general learning objective that is relevant to all
chapters. The general learning objective—the mortar
that holds the building blocks together—is: Know that to
relate models to the real world, you need to use a nuanced
approach.
For professors who want to include this learning ob-
jective in their course, I have written a prologue to the
student found on pages P-1 to P-5, just before Chapter 1.
In it I discuss the need for context and nuance in applying
the models, and introduce students to two methodological
tools that philosophers use to move from models to policy
positions. This prologue, what you might think of as
Chapter 0, serves as the mortar and blueprint to guide stu-
dents in thinking critically about the models and their
application. This short prologue, which can be assigned
along with Chapter 1, presents a general discussion of the
problem of context and nuance and introduces the general
learning objective.
Students are reminded of this general learning objec-
tive throughout the book in chapter discussions of nu-
anced issues, which are highlighted in SmartBook and
probes that focus on nuance. I also provide professors
with some guidance and suggestions on how to integrate
a discussion of values and ethics into the course, along
with a list of Connect questions and material in SmartBook
that deal with integrating values into the analysis. These
are to be found in the Instructor’s website for the book. For
those who want to emphasize critical thought and nuance
in the course, it is much easier to do so than before.
Specific Content Changes
to This Edition
Any new edition provides the possibility to update dis-
cussions and I have done so throughout the book, both in
updating references to events, and in examples. On a
mundane level I changed examples and products being
discussed. For example, there was an earlier discussion of
the supply and demand for CDs, which at one point in the
past seemed reasonable. CDs have gone the way of buggy
whips, and so the discussion was changed to chocolate,
which has a longer shelf life—there will always be
demand for 80 percent dark chocolate, at least from me.
I also reviewed all the boxes, eliminating or updat-
ing those that were outdated, replacing them with new
boxes that capture some of the new ideas being dis-
cussed. For example, in Chapter 3 I added a box on
polycentric government and the ideas of economist
Preface ix
Elinor Ostrom, and in Chapter 8W I updated the discus-
sion of the farm program.
I did the same with discussions in the text, adding up-
dates where needed. That led to substantial changes in
some chapters. For example, President Trump’s changing
the narrative on trade meant some significant changes in
Chapter 10 on trade were needed. I replaced the opening
discussion of trade to include Trump’s criticism of
freetrade agreements and updated the discussion of WTO
trade negotiations and U.S. trade policy to account for the
Trump presidency. The growing importance of platform
monopolies and network externalities led to substantial
changes in Chapter 14 and the discussion of antitrust pol-
icy in Chapter 15. Chapter 17 on labor also was modified
to account for developments in the information revolu-
tion. I also added discussions of artificial intelligence and
deep learning in both the micro and macro chapters.
These developments will likely have significant implica-
tions for the economy in the coming decade, as AI and
deep learning do to mental labor what the Industrial
Revolution did to physical labor.
Because of the c
hanging nature of the macro problem
facing the economy, macro examples were updated more
frequently than micro examples. In this edition the dis-
cussion of the macro economy is from the perspective of
2018. The economy is strong, but there is continuing con-
cern that the growth is not sustainable. The monetary
policy discussion involved substantial changes since the
Fed is no longer using unconventional monetary policy,
but is instead trying to unwind its balance sheet as it
returns to a conventional monetary policy.
The use of fiscal policy also changed, wit
h the tax cut
and spending increase, even as the economy was doing
well, showing how politics generally trumps economics
in driving fiscal policy. Another change in the macro
chapters involved discussions of cryptocurrencies and
how they are not currencies, since they dont meet the
definition of money, but are instead crypto assets, almost
designed to be blown into bubbles. I discuss how block-
chain technology might be revolutionary, but the hype
around cryptocurrency is more like Tulipmania and how
the real revolution in currency is more likely to come
through new digital currencies such as M-Pesa.
Finally, there were a number of changes to allow the
introduction of nuanced understanding as a separate
learning objective. I added a discussion of Adam Smiths
impartial spectator tool, and how in assessing policy, one
must go beyond how it will benefit oneself, and concen-
trate on how it can be judged from society’s point of view.
I encourage students to discuss contentious policy issues
with others who approach the issues differently as a way
of advancing the discussion.
Enjoy!
In summary, this book differs from others in its distinc-
tive blend of nuance and no-nonsense modeling. Working
with models doesnt involve nuance; it involves knowing
the models and their assumptions—questions about mod-
els are right or wrong—and nuanced discussion of apply-
ing the models where there are inevitably gray areas
where critical thought is needed. Seeing students navigate
this gray area and arrive at a nuanced understanding of
economic principles gives me enormous joy. I hope it
does for you as well.
People to Thank
Let me conclude this preface by thanking the hundreds of
people who have offered suggestions, comments, kudos,
and criticism on this project since its inception. This book
would not be what it is without their input. So many peo-
ple have contributed to this text in so many ways that I
cannot thank everyone. So, to all the people who helped—
many, many thanks. I specifically want to thank the
ele venth edition reviewers, whose insightful comments
kept me on track. Reviewers include:
Catherine M. Chambers
University of Central
Missouri
Frankie P. Albritton Jr.
Seminole State College
Paul Chambers
University of Central
Missouri
B. Andrew Chupp
Georgia Institute of
Technology
Diane Cunningham
Los Angeles Valley College
Gregory E. DeFreitas
Hofstra University
John P. Finnigan
Marist College
Bernhard Georg Gunter
American University
Benjamin Leyden
Univer
sity of Virginia
Victoria Miller
Akin Technical College
ABM E. Nasir
North Car
olina Central
University
Christina Ann Robinson
Central Connecticut
State University
William Shambora
Ohio University
Mark Griffin Smith
Colorado College
Don Uy-Barreta
De Anza College
Kenneth Woodward
Saddleback College
In addition to the comments of the formal reviewers
listed above, I have received helpful suggestions, encour-
agement, and assistance from innumerable individuals
via e-mails, letters, symposia, and focus groups. Their
help made this edition even stronger than its predecessor.
They include James Wetzel, Virginia Commonwealth
University; Dmitry Shishkin, Georgia State University;
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii.indd 9 12/3/18 11:54 AM
x Preface
Amy Cramer, Pima Community College–West; Andrea
Terzi, Franklin College; Shelby Frost, Georgia State Uni-
versity; Doris Geide-Stevenson, Weber State University;
James Chasey, Advanced Placement Economics Teaching
Consultant and Homewood-Flossmoor High School
(ret.); David Tufte, Southern Utah University; Eric
Sarpong, Georgia State University; Jim Ciecka, DePaul
University; Fran Bradley, George School; Ron Olive,
University of Massachusetts–Lowell; Rachel Kreier,
Hofstra University; Kenneth Elzinga, University of Vir-
ginia; Ben Leyden, University of Virginia; Poul Thøis
Madse, Danmarks Medie—OG Journalistehojskole; Rich
Tarmey, Colorado Mountain College; Michael Mandelberg,
Stuart Webber, Trinity Lutheran College; Bob Rogers,
Ashland University; Zackery Hansen, Southern Utah
University; and Matt Gaffney, Missouri State University.
I want to give a special thank-you to the supplement
authors and subject matter experts including Jennifer
Rester Savoie, Pearl River Community College; Susan
Bell, Seminole State University; Per Norander, University
of North Carolina at Charlotte; Frankie P. Albritton Jr.,
Seminole State University; and Kenneth Woodward,
Saddleback College. They all did an outstanding job.
I’d also like to thank the economists who wrote the
alternative perspective questions. These include Ann
Mari May of the University of Nebraska–Lincoln, John
Miller of Wheaton College, Dan Underwood of Peninsula
College, Ric Holt of Southern Oregon University, and
Bridget Butkevich of George Mason University. I enjoyed
working with each of them, and while their views often
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii.indd 10 12/3/18 12:42 PM
differed substantially, they were all united in wanting ques-
tions that showed economics as a pluralist field that en-
courages students to question the text from all perspectives.
I have hired numerous students to check aspects of the
book, to read over my questions and answers to questions,
and to help proofread. For this edition, these include Reid
Smith, Amelia Pollard and Zhewei Yang. I thank them all.
A special thank-you for this edition goes to two peo-
ple. The first is Jenifer Gamber, whose role in the book
cannot be overestimated. She helped me clarify its vision
by providing research, critiquing expositions and often
improving them, and being a good friend. She has an
amazing set of skills, and I thank her for using them to
improve the book. The second is Christina Kouvelis,
senior pr oduct developer, who came into this project and
with her hard work, dedication, and superb ability made it
possible to get the book done on time. She and Jenifer are
two amazing women.
Next, I want to thank the entire McGraw-Hill team,
including Terri Schiesl, managing director; Anke Weekes,
director; Christine Vaughan, lead content project man-
ager; Bruce Gin, senior assessment project manager;
Egzon Shaqiri, designer; Bobby Pearson, marketing man-
ager; Julia Blankenship, marketing specialist; and Doug
Ruby, director of digital content. All of them have done a
superb job, for which I thank them sincerely.
Finally, I want to thank Pat, my wife, and my sons,
Kasey and Zach, for helping me keep my work in per-
spective, and for providing a loving environment in which
to work.
xi
Distinguishing
Features
Margin Comments
Located throughout the text in the margin, these key take-
aways underscore and summarize the importance of the
material, at the same time helping students focus on the
most relevant topics critical to their understanding.
Margin Questions
These self-test questions are presented in the margin of
the chapter to enable students to determine whether the
preceding material has been understood and to reinforce
understanding before students read further. Answers to
Margin Questions are found at the end of each chapter.
Web Notes
This feature extends the text discussion onto the web.
Web Notes are denoted within the margins, and are
housed within Connect and featured in SmartBook.
Nuance Prologue and Questions
Nuanced aspects of economics are presented throughout
the book, and in a Prologue for the Student. In SmartBook,
nuance questions have been added that directly relate to
applying the models and the problems of integrating values
into theanalysis. A guide to these questions can be found
on the Instructor Resource website.
Issues to Ponder
Each chapter ends with a set of Issues to Ponder questions
that are designed to encourage additional economic think-
ing and application.
Questions from Alternative
Perspectives
The end-of-chapter material includes a number of ques-
tions that ask students to assess economics from alterna-
tive perspectives. Specifically, six different approaches
are highlighted: Austrian, Post-Keynesian, Institutional-
ist, Radical, Feminist, and Religious. Below are brief
descriptions of each group.
Austrian Economists
Austrian economists believe in methodological individu-
alism, by which they mean that social goals are best met
through voluntary, mutually beneficial interactions. Lack
of information and unsolvable incentive problems under-
mine the ability of government to plan, making the mar-
ket the best method for coordinating economic activity.
Austrian economists oppose state intrusion into private
property and private activities. They are not economists
from Austria; rather, they are economists from anywhere
who follow the ideas of Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich
Hayek, two economists who were from Austria.
Austrian economists are sometimes classified as con-
servative, but they are more appropriately classified as
libertarians, who believe in liberty of individuals first and
in other social goals second. Consistent with their views,
they are often willing to support what are sometimes con-
sidered radical ideas, such as legalizing addictive drugs
or eliminating our current monetary system—ideas that
most mainstream economists would oppose. Austrian
economists emphasize the uncertainty in the economy and
the inability of a government controlled by self- interested
politicians to undertake socially beneficial policy.
Institutionalist Economists
Institutionalist economists argue that any economic analy-
sis must involve specific considerations of institutions. The
lineage of Institutionalist economics begins with the pio-
neering work of Thorstein Veblen, John R. Commons, and
Wesley C. Mitchell. Veblen employed evolutionary analy-
sis to explore the role of institutions in directing and retard-
ing the economic process. He saw human behavior driven
by cultural norms and conveyed the way in which they
were with sardonic wit and penetrating insight, leaving us
with enduring metaphors such as the leisure class and con-
spicuous consumption. Commons argued that institutions
are social constructs that improve general welfare. Accord-
ingly, he established cooperative investigative programs to
support pragmatic changes in the legal structure of govern-
ment. Mitchell was a leader in developing economics as an
empirical study; he was a keen observer of the business
cycle and argued that theory must be informed by system-
atic attention to empirical data, or it was useless.
Contemporary Institutionalists employ the founders
“trilogy”—empirically informed, evolutionary analysis,
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 11 11/24/18 11:03 AM
xii Preface
directed toward pragmatic alteration of institutions shap-
ing economic outcomes—in their policy approach.
Radical Economists
Radical economists believe substantial equality-preferring
institutional changes should be implemented in our
economic system. Radical economists evolved out of
Marxian economics. In their analysis, they focus on the
lack of equity in our current economic system and on in-
stitutional changes that might bring about a more equita-
ble system. Specifically, they see the current economic
system as one in which a few people—capitalists and
high-level managers—benefit enormously at the expense
of many people who struggle to make ends meet in jobs
that are unfulfilling or who even go without work at
times. They see the fundamental instability and irratio-
nality of the capitalist system at the root of a wide array
of social ills that range from pervasive inequality to alien-
ation, racism, sexism, and imperialism. Radical econo-
mists often use a class-oriented analysis to address these
issues and are much more willing to talk about social
conflict and tensions in our society than are mainstream
economists.
A policy favored by many Radicals is the establish-
ment of worker cooperatives to replace the corporation.
Radicals argue that such worker cooperatives would see
that the income of the firm is more equitably allocated.
Likewise, Radical economists endorse policies, such as
universal health care insurance, that conform to the ethic
of “putting people before profits.
Feminist Economists
Feminist economics offers a substantive challenge to the
content, scope, and methodology of mainstream econom-
ics. Feminist economists question the boundaries of what
we consider economics to be and examine social arrange-
ments surrounding provisioning. Feminist economists
have many different views, but all believe that in some
way traditional economic analysis misses many important
issues pertaining to women.
Feminist economists study issues such as how the in-
stitutional structure tends to direct women into certain
types of jobs (generally low-paying jobs) and away from
other types of jobs (generally high-paying jobs). They
draw our attention to the unpaid labor performed by
women throughout the world and ask, “What would GDP
look like if women’s work were given a value and
included?” They argue for an expansion in the content of
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 12 11/24/18 11:03 AM
economics to include women as practitioners and as
worthy of study and for the elimination of the masculine
bias in mainstream economics. Is there such a bias? To
see it, simply compare the relative number of women in
your economics class to the relative number of women at
your school. It is highly likely that your class has relatively
more men. Feminist economists want you to ask why that
is, and whether anything should be done about it.
Religious Economists
Religion is the oldest and, arguably, the most influential
institution in the world—be it Christianity, Islam, Juda-
ism, Buddhism, Hinduism, or any of the many other reli-
gions in the world. Modern science, of which economics
is a part, emphasizes the rational elements of thought. It
attempts to separate faith and normative issues from ra-
tional analysis in ways that some religiously oriented
economists find questionable. The line between a reli-
gious and nonreligious economist is not hard and fast; all
economists bring elements of their ethical considerations
into their analysis. But those we call “religious econo-
mists” integrate the ethical and normative issues into eco-
nomic analysis in more complex ways than the ways
presented in the text.
Religiously oriented economists have a diversity of
views; some believe that their views can be integrated
reasonably well into standard economics, while others
see the need for the development of a distinctive faith-
based methodology that focuses on a particular group of
normative concerns centered on issues such as human
dignity and caring for the poor.
Post-Keynesian Economists
Post-Keynesian economists believe that uncertainty is a
central issue in economics. They follow J. M. Keynes’ ap-
proach more so than do mainstream economists in em-
phasizing institutional imperfections in the economy and
the importance of fundamental uncertainty that rational-
ity cannot deal with. They agree with Institutionalists that
the study of economics must emphasize and incorporate
the importance of social and political structure in deter-
mining market outcomes.
While their view about the importance of uncertainty
is similar to the Austrian view, their policy response to
that uncertainty is quite different. They do not see uncer-
tainty as eliminating much of government’s role in the
economy; instead, they see it leading to policies in which
government takes a larger role in guiding the economy.
xiii
Supplements
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii.indd 13 12/3/18 11:55 AM
McGraw-Hill has established a strong history of top-rate
supplements to accompany this text, and this eleventh
edition strives to carry on the tradition of excellence. The
following ancillaries are available for quick download
and convenient access via the Instructor Resource mate-
rial available through McGraw-Hill Connect
®
.
Solutions Manual
Prepared by Jenifer Gamber and me, this manual provides
answers to all end-of-chapter questions—the Questions
and Exercises, Questions from Alternative Perspectives,
and Issues to Ponder.
Test Banks
The test bank contains more than 5,600 quality multiple
choice and true-false questions for instructors to draw from
in their classrooms. Jenifer Gamber and I have worked dili-
gently to make sure that the questions are clear and useful.
Each question is categorized by learning objective, level of
difficulty, economic concept, AACSB learning categories,
and Bloom’s Taxonomy objectives. Questions were re-
viewed by professors and students alike to ensure that each
one was effective for classroom use. All of the test bank
content is available for assigning within Connect.
A computerized test bank is available via TestGen, a
complete, state-of-the-art test generator and editing applica-
tion software that allows instructors to quickly and easily
select test items. Instructors can then organize, edit, and cus-
tomize questions and answers to rapidly generate tests for
paper or online administration. With both quick-and-simple
test creation and flexible and robust editing tools, TestGen
is a complete test generator system for today’s educators.
An essay-only test bank, organized bychapter, will be
available via the Instructor Resource material available
within Connect.
PowerPoint Presentations
Jennifer Rester Savoie of Pearl River Community College
worked tirelessly to revise the PowerPoint slide program,
animating graphs and emphasizing important concepts.
Each chapter has been scrutinized to ensure an accurate,
direct connection to the text.
Problem Sets
Additional problem sets accompany each chapter, which
can be assigned to students either for practice or
assessment. They are also included as extra assessment
content available wit
hin Connect.
Assurance of Learning Ready
Many educational institutions today are focused on the
notion of assurance of learning, an important element of
some accreditation standards. Economics, 11/e is de-
signed specifically to support your assurance of learning
initiatives with a simple yet powerful solution.
Instructors can use Connect to easily query for learn-
ing outcomes/objectives that directly relate to the learn-
ing objectives of the course. You can then use the
reporting features of Connect to aggregate student results
in similar fashion, making the collection and presentation
of assurance of learning data simple and easy.
AACSB Statement
McGraw-Hill Global Education is a proud corporate
member of AACSB International. Understanding the im-
portance and value of AACSB accreditation, the author
of Economics, 11/e has sought to recognize the curricula
guidelines detailed in the AACSB standards for business
accreditation by connecting questions in the test bank and
end-of-chapter material to the general knowledge and
skill guidelines found in the AACSB standards.
It is important to note that the statements contained in
Economics, 11/e are provided only as a guide for the us-
ers of this text. The AACSB leaves content coverage and
assessment within the purview of individual schools, the
mission of the school, and the faculty. While Economics,
11/e and the teaching package make no claim of any spe-
cific AACSB qualification or evaluation, we have within
Economics, 11/e labeled selected questions according to
the general knowledge and skills areas.
McGraw-Hill Customer Care
ContactInformation
At McGraw-Hill, we understand that getting the most from
new technology can be challenging. Thats why our services
dont stop after you purchase our products. You can e-mail
our Product Specialists 24 hours a day to get product training
online. Or you can search our knowledge bank of Frequently
Asked Questions on our support website. For Customer
Support, call 800-331-5094 or visit www.mhhe.com/
support. One of our Technical Support Analysts will be
able to assist you in a timely fashion.
Students—study more eciently, retain more
and achieve better outcomes. Instructors—focus
on what you love—teaching.
SUCCESSFUL SEMESTERS INCLUDE CONNECT
65%
Less Time
Grading
F I
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 14 11/24/18 11:03 AM
You’re in the driver’s seat.
Want to build your own course? No problem. Prefer to use our turnkey,
prebuilt course? Easy. Want to make changes throughout the semester?
Sure. And you’ll save time with Connect’s auto-grading too.
They’ll thank you for it.
Adaptive study resources like SmartBook® help your
students be better prepared in less time. You can
transform your class time from dull definitions to dynamic
debates. Hear from your peers about the benefits of
Connect at www.mheducation.com/highered/connect
Make it simple, make it affordable.
Connect makes it easy with seamless integration using any of the
major Learning Management Systems
Blackboard®, Canvas,
and D2L, among others
to let you organize your course in one
convenient location. Give your students access to digital materials
at a discount with our inclusive access program. Ask your
McGraw-Hill representative for more information.
©Hill Street Studios/Tobin Rogers/Blend Images LLC
Solutions for your challenges.
A product isn’t a solution. Real solutions are affordable,
reliable, and come with training and ongoing support when
you need it and how you want it. Our Customer Experience
Group can also help you troubleshoot tech problems
although Connect’s 99% uptime means you might not need
to call them. See for yourself at status.mheducation.com
Chapter 12 Quiz Chapter 11 Quiz
Chapter 7 Quiz
Chapter 13 Evidence of Evolution Chapter 11 DNA Technology
Chapter 7 DNA Structure and Gene...
and 7 more...
13 14
F S
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 15 11/24/18 11:03 AM
Effective, efficient studying.
Connect helps you be more productive with your
study time and get better grades using tools like
SmartBook, which highlights key concepts and creates
a personalized study plan. Connect sets you up for
success, so you walk into class with confidence and
walk out with better grades.
©Shutterstock/wavebreakmedia
made it easy to study when
I really liked this appit
you don’t have your text-
book in front of you.
—Jordan Cunningham,
Eastern Washington University
Study anytime, anywhere.
Download the free ReadAnywhere app and access your
online eBook when it’s convenient, even if you’re oine.
And since the app automatically syncs with your eBook in
Connect, all of your notes are available every time you open
it. Find out more at www.mheducation.com/readanywhere
No surprises.
The Connect Calendar and Reports tools
keep you on track with the work you need
to get done and your assignment scores.
Life gets busy; Connect tools help you
keep learning through it all.
Learning for everyone.
McGraw-Hill works directly with Accessibility Services
Departments and faculty to meet the learning needs of all
students. Please contact your Accessibility Services oce
and ask them to email [email protected], or
visit www.mheducation.com/about/accessibility.html for
more information.
2 The Production Possibility Model, Trade, and
Globalization 25
Appendix: Graphish:The Language of Graphs 44
3 Economic Institutions 53
Appendix: The History of Economic Systems 73
4 Supply and Demand 78
5 Using Supply and Demand 101
Appendix: Algebraic Representation of Supply,
Demand, and Equilibrium 117
 II MICROECONOMICS
THE POWER OF TRADITIONAL
ECONOMIC MODELS
6 Describing Supply and Demand: Elasticities 124
7 Taxation and Government Intervention 144
8 Market Failure versus Government Failure 165
8W Politics and Economics: The Case of Agricultural
Markets 187
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC
POLICYISSUES
9 Comparative Advantage, Exchange Rates,
and Globalization 188
10 International Trade Policy 207
PRODUCTION AND COST ANALYSIS
11 Production and Cost Analysis I 229
12 Production and Cost Analysis II 249
Appendix: Isocost/Isoquant Analysis 267
MARKET STRUCTURE
13 Perfect Competition 272
14 Monopoly and Monopolistic Competition 293
Appendix: The Algebra of Competitive and
Monopolistic Firms 319
15 Oligopoly and Antitrust Policy 321
16 Real-World Competition and Technology 340
FACTOR MARKETS
17 Work and the Labor Market 359
Appendix: Derived Demand 383
17W Nonwage and Asset Income: Rents, Profits, and
Interest 389
18 Who Gets What? The Distribution of Income 390
CHOICE AND DECISION MAKING
19 The Logic of Individual Choice:
The Foundation ofSupply and Demand 416
Appendix: Indifference Curve Analysis 436
20 Game Theory, Strategic Decision Making, and
Behavioral Economics 441
Appendix: Game Theory and Oligopoly 462
MODERN ECONOMIC THINKING
21 Thinking Like a Modern Economist 466
22 Behavioral Economics and Modern Economic
Policy 492
23 Microeconomic Policy, Economic Reasoning,
and Beyond 511
 III MACROECONOMICS
MACROECONOMIC BASICS
24 Economic Growth, Business Cycles, and
Unemployment 534
25 Measuring and Describing the Aggregate
Economy 557
POLICY MODELS
26 The Keynesian Short-Run Policy Model:
Demand-Side Policies 582
26W The Multiplier Model 609
27 The Classical Long-Run Policy Model: Growth and
Supply-Side Policies 610
FINANCE, MONEY, AND THE ECONOMY
28 The Financial Sector and the Economy 631
Appendix: A Closer Look at Financial Assets and
Liabilities 653
29 Monetary Policy 659
xvi
Brief
Contents
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 16 11/24/18 11:03 AM
 I INTRODUCTION: THINKING
LIKE AN ECONOMIST
11 Economics and Economic Reasoning 4
30 Financial Crises, Panics, and Unconventional
Monetary Policy 681
TAXES, BUDGETS, AND
FISCAL POLICY
31 Deficits and Debt: The Austerity Debate 701
32 The Fiscal Policy Dilemma 718
MACROECONOMIC PROBLEMS
33 Jobs and Unemployment 736
34 Inflation, Deflation, and Macro Policy 754
INTERNATIONAL MACROECONOMIC
POLICY ISSUES
35 International Financial Policy 777
Appendix: History of Exchange Rate Systems 802
36 Macro Policy in a Global Setting 805
37 Structural Stagnation and Globalization 820
Appendix: Creating a Targeted Safety Net to Help the
Least Well Off 843
38 Macro Policy in Developing Countries 845
Brief Contents xvii
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 17 11/24/18 11:03 AM
xviii
Trade and Comparative Advantage 32
Markets, Specialization, and Growth 33
The Benefits of Trade 34
Globalization and the Law of One Price 36
Globalization 36
Exchange Rates and Comparative Advantage 38
The Law of One Price 38
Globalization and the Timing of Benefits of Trade 39
Conclusion 39
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 40–43
Appendix: Graphish: The Language of Graphs 44
3 Economic Institutions 53
Economic Systems 54
How Markets Work 54
Whats Good about the Market? 55
Capitalism and Socialism 55
Economic Institutions in a Market Economy 58
Business 59
Households 61
The Roles of Government 62
Government as an Actor 62
Government as a Referee 64
Specific Roles for Government 65
Market Failures and Government Failures 67
Global Institutions 68
Global Corporations 68
Coordinating Global Issues 68
Conclusion 69
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 69–72
Appendix: The History of Economic Systems 73
4 Supply and Demand 78
Demand 78
The Law of Demand 79
The Demand Curve 79
2 The Production Possibility Model, Trade,
and Globalization 25
The Production Possibility Model 26
A Production Possibility Curve for an Individual 26
Increasing Opportunity Costs of the Trade-Off 27
Comparative Advantage 28
Efficiency 29
Distribution and Productive Efficiency 30
Examples of Shifts in the PPC 31
Contents
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 18 11/24/18 11:03 AM
PART I
INTRODUCTION:
THINKING LIKE
AN ECONOMIST
11 Economics and Economic Reasoning 4
What Economics Is 5
Scarcity 5
Microeconomics and Macroeconomics 6
A Guide to Economic Reasoning 6
Marginal Costs and Marginal Benefits 8
The Economic Decision Rule 8
Economics and Passion 8
Opportunity Cost 9
Economic Forces, Social Forces, and Political Forces 11
Economic and Market Forces 11
Social and Political Forces 11
Using Economic Insights 13
The Invisible Hand Theorem 14
Economic Theory and Stories 15
Economic Institutions 15
Economic Policy Options 16
Objective Policy Analysis 17
Policy and Social and Political Forces 20
Conclusion 20
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 21–24
Shifts in Demand versus Movements
along a Demand Curve 80
Some Shift Factors of Demand 81
The Demand Table 82
From a Demand Table to a Demand Curve 82
Individual and Market Demand Curves 83
Supply 85
The Law of Supply 85
The Supply Curve 86
Shifts in Supply versus Movements along a Supply
Curve 87
Shift Factors of Supply 88
The Supply Table 88
From a Supply Table to a Supply Curve 88
Individual and Market Supply Curves 88
The Interaction of Supply and Demand 89
Equilibrium 90
The Graphical Interaction of Supply and Demand 91
What Equilibrium Isnt 91
Political and Social Forces and Equilibrium 92
Shifts in Supply and Demand 93
A Limitation of Supply/Demand Analysis 95
Conclusion 95
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises,
Questions from Alternative Perspectives,
Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 96–100
5 Using Supply and Demand 101
Real-World Supply and Demand
Applications 101
Government Intervention: Price Ceilings
and Price Floors 104
Price Ceilings 105
Price Floors 106
Government Intervention: Excise Taxes
and Tariffs 108
Government Intervention: Quantity
Restrictions 109
Third-Party-Payer Markets 111
Conclusion 112
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises,
Questions from Alternative Perspectives,
Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 112–116
Appendix: Algebraic Representation of Supply, Demand,
and Equilibrium 117
PART II
MICROECONOMICS
THE POWER OF TRADITIONAL
ECONOMIC MODELS
6 Describing Supply and Demand:
Elasticities 124
Price Elasticity 124
What Information Price Elasticity Provides 125
Classifying Demand and Supply as Elastic
or Inelastic 125
Elasticity Is Independent of Units 126
Calculating Elasticities 126
Other Examples 128
Elasticity Is Not the Same as Slope 128
Five Terms to Describe Elasticity 130
Substitution and Elasticity 130
Substitution and Demand 131
How Substitution Factors Affect Specific
Decisions 132
Elasticity, Total Revenue, and Demand 133
Total Revenue along a Demand Curve 134
Income and Cross-Price Elasticity 135
Income Elasticity of Demand 135
Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand 136
Some Examples 137
The Power of Supply/Demand Analysis 138
When Should a Supplier Not Raise Price? 138
Elasticity and Shifting Supply and Demand 139
Conclusion 139
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 140–143
7 Taxation and Government
Intervention 144
Producer and Consumer Surplus 144
Burden of Taxation 146
Who Bears the Burden of a Tax? 148
Tax Incidence and Current Policy Debates 151
Government Intervention as Implicit Taxation 152
Price Ceilings and Floors 152
The Difference between Taxes and Price
Controls 153
Contents xix
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 19 11/24/18 11:03 AM
xx Contents
Rent Seeking, Politics, and Elasticities 154
Inelastic Demand and Incentives to Restrict Supply 154
Inelastic Supplies and Incentives to Restrict Prices 157
The Long-Run/Short-Run Problem of Price
Controls 158
Conclusion 160
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 160–164
8 Market Failure versus Government
Failure 165
Externalities 166
Effects of Positive and Negative Externalities 167
Alternative Methods of Dealing with
Externalities 168
Direct Regulation 169
Incentive Policies 170
Voluntary Reductions 171
The Optimal Policy 172
Public Goods 172
The Market Value of a Public Good 173
Excludability and the Costs of Pricing 175
Informational and Moral Hazard Problems 176
Signaling and Screening 177
Policies to Deal with Informational Problems 177
Government Failure and Market Failures 180
Conclusion 182
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 182–186
8W Politics and Economics: The Case of
Agricultural Markets 187 and 8W-1
The Good/Bad Paradox in Agriculture 8W-3
The Long-Run Decline of Farming 8W-3
The Short-Run Cyclical Problem Facing Farmers 8W-4
The Difficulty of Coordinating Farm Production 8W-4
Ways around the Good/Bad Paradox 8W-4
The General Rule of Political Economy 8W-5
Four Price Support Options 8W-5
Supporting the Price by Regulatory Measures 8W-6
Providing Economic Incentives to Reduce Supply 8W-8
Subsidizing the Sale of the Good 8W-9
Buying Up and Storing, Giving Away, orDestroying
the Good 8W-9
Which Group Prefers Which Option? 8W-10
Economics, Politics, and Real-World Policies 8W-10
Interest Groups 8W-11
International Issues 8W-12
Conclusion 8W-12
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 8W-13–8W-16
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC POLICY
ISSUES
9 Comparative Advantage, Exchange
Rates, and Globalization 188
The Principle of Comparative Advantage 188
The Gains from Trade 189
Dividing Up the Gains from Trade 190
Why Economists and Laypeople Differ in Their Views
of Trade 192
Gains Are Often Stealth 192
Opportunity Cost Is Relative 192
Trade Is Broader Than Manufactured Goods 192
Trade Has Distributional Effects 193
Sources of U.S. Comparative Advantage 194
Some Concerns about the Future 196
Inherent and Transferable Sources of
Comparative Advantages 196
The Law of One Price 196
How the United States Gained and Is Now Losing
Sources of Comparative Advantage 197
Methods of Equalizing Trade Balances 197
Determination of Exchange Rates and Trade 198
Exchange Rates and Trade 200
Some Complications in Exchange Rates 201
Conclusion 202
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 202–206
10 International Trade Policy 207
The Nature and Patterns of Trade 207
Increasing but Fluctuating World Trade 207
Differences in the Importance of Trade 208
What and with Whom the United States Trades 208
Debtor and Creditor Nations 210
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 20 11/24/18 11:03 AM
Contents xxi
12 Production and Cost
Analysis II 249
Technical Efficiency and Economic
Efficiency 250
The Shape of the Long-Run Cost Curve 250
Economies of Scale 251
Diseconomies of Scale 253
Constant Returns to Scale 254
The Importance of Economies and
Diseconomies of Scale 255
Envelope Relationship 255
Entrepreneurial Activity and the
Supply Decision 257
Using Cost Analysis in the Real World 258
Economies of Scope 258
Learning by Doing and Technological Change 259
Many Dimensions 262
Unmeasured Costs 262
The Standard Model as a Framework 263
Conclusion 263
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 264–267
Appendix: Isocost/Isoquant Analysis 267
MARKET STRUCTURE
13 Perfect Competition 272
Perfect Competition as a Reference Point 272
Conditions for Perfect Competition 273
Demand Curves for the Firm and the Industry 273
The Profit-Maximizing Level of Output 274
Marginal Revenue 274
Marginal Cost 275
Profit Maximization: MC = MR 275
The Marginal Cost Curve Is the Supply Curve 276
Firms Maximize Total Profit 276
Total Profit at the Profit-Maximizing
Level of Output 278
Determining Profit from a Table of Costs and
Revenue 278
Determining Profit from a Graph 279
The Shutdown Point 281
Short-Run Market Supply and Demand 282
Long-Run Competitive Equilibrium:
Zero Profit 283
Varieties of Trade Restrictions 212
Tariffs and Quotas 212
Voluntary Restraint Agreements 214
Sanctions 214
Regulatory Trade Restrictions 215
Nationalistic Appeals and “Buy Domestic”
Requirements 215
Reasons for and against Trade Restrictions 215
Unequal Internal Distribution of the Gains from Trade 216
Haggling by Companies over the Gains from Trade 218
Haggling by Countries over Trade Restrictions 218
Specialized Production 219
Macroeconomic Costs of Trade 220
National Security 221
International Politics 221
Increased Revenue Brought In by Tariffs 221
Why Economists Generally Oppose Trade
Restrictions 221
Institutions Supporting Free Trade 223
Conclusion 225
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 225–228
PRODUCTION AND COST ANALYSIS
11 Production and Cost
Analysis I 229
The Role of the Firm 230
Firms Maximize Profit 231
The Difference between Economists’ Profits and
Accountants’ Profits 232
The Production Process 233
The Long Run and the Short Run 233
Production Tables and Production Functions 233
The Law of Diminishing Marginal Productivity 235
The Costs of Production 236
Fixed Costs, Variable Costs, and Total Costs 236
Average Costs 237
Marginal Cost 237
Graphing Cost Curves 238
Total Cost Curves 239
Average and Marginal Cost Curves 239
Intermission 243
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions, 244–248
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 21 11/24/18 11:03 AM
Adjustment from the Short Run to the Long Run 284
An Increase in Demand 284
Long-Run Market Supply 285
An Example in the Real World 286
Conclusion 287
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 288–292
14 Monopoly and Monopolistic
Competition 293
The Key Difference between a Monopolist and a Perfect
Competitor 293
A Model of Monopoly 294
Determining the Monopolist’s Price and Output
Numerically 294
Determining Price and Output Graphically 295
Comparing Monopoly and Perfect Competition 297
An Example of Finding Output and Price 297
Profits and Monopoly 298
Welfare Loss from Monopoly 300
The Normal Monopolist 300
The Price-Discriminating Monopolist 301
Barriers to Entry and Monopoly 302
Natural Ability 304
Natural Monopolies 304
Network and Platform Monopolies 306
Monopolistic Competition 308
Characteristics of Monopolistic Competition 308
Advertising and Monopolistic Competition 309
Output, Price, and Profit of a Monopolistic
Competitor 311
Comparing Monopoly, Monopolistic Competition,
and Perfect Competition 312
Conclusion 313
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 314–319
Appendix: The Algebra of Competitive and Monopolistic
Firms 319
15 Oligopoly and Antitrust Policy 321
The Distinguishing Characteristics of Oligopoly 321
Models of Oligopoly Behavior 322
The Cartel Model 322
The Contestable Market Model 325
Comparison of the Contestable Market Model
and the Cartel Model 325
Classifying Industries and Markets in Practice 327
The North American Industry Classification
System 328
Empirical Measures of Industry Structure 329
Conglomerate Firms and Bigness 330
Oligopoly Models and Empirical Estimates
of Market Structure 330
Antitrust Policy 331
Judgment by Performance or Structure? 331
The Role of Antitrust in Today’s Economy 333
Conclusion 335
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 336–339
16 Real-World Competition and
Technology 340
Competition Is for Losers 341
The Goals of Real-World Firms
and the Monitoring Problem 341
What Do Real-World Firms Maximize? 344
The Lazy Monopolist and X-Inefficiency 344
The Fight between Competitive and Monopolistic
Forces 346
How Monopolistic Forces Affect Perfect Competition 347
Economic Insights and Real-World Competition 347
How Competitive Forces Affect Monopoly 348
Competition: Natural and Platform Monopolies 349
How Firms Protect Their Monopolies 350
Cost/Benefit Analysis of Creating and
MaintainingMonopolies 351
Establishing Market Position 351
Platform Monopolies and Technology 352
Standards and Winner-Take-All Industries 352
Technological Lock-In 353
Conclusion 354
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 354–358
FACTOR MARKETS
17 Work and the Labor Market 359
The Supply of Labor 360
Real Wages and the Opportunity Cost of Work 361
The Supply of Labor and Nonmarket Activities 362
xxii Contents
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 22 11/24/18 11:03 AM
Contents xxiii
Income Taxation, Work, and Leisure 362
The Elasticity of the Supply of Labor 363
Immigration and the International Supply
of Labor 364
The Derived Demand for Labor 364
Factors Influencing the Elasticity of Demand for
Labor 365
Labor as a Factor of Production 365
Shift Factors of Demand 365
Determination of Wages 369
Imperfect Competition and the Labor Market 370
Political and Social Forces and the Labor Market 371
Fairness and the Labor Market 372
Discrimination and the Labor Market 374
Three Types of Direct Demand-Side
Discrimination 374
Institutional Discrimination 376
The Evolution of Labor Markets 377
Evolving Labor Laws 377
The Labor Market and You 377
Conclusion 378
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 379–382
Appendix: Derived Demand 383
17W Nonwage and Asset Income: Rents,
Profits, and Interest 389 and 17W-1
Rent 17W-3
The Effect of a Tax on Land 17W-3
Quasi Rents 17W-4
Rent Seeking and Institutional Constraints 17W-5
Profit 17W-6
Profit, Entrepreneurship, and Disequilibrium
Adjustment 17W-6
Market Niches, Profit, and Rent 17W-7
Interest 17W-7
The Present Value Formula 17W-8
Some Rules of Thumb for Determining Present
Value 17W-9
The Importance of Present Value 17W-11
The Marginal Productivity Theory
of Income Distribution 17W-11
Conclusion 17W-12
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 17W-12–17W-14
18 Who Gets What?
The Distribution of Income 390
Measuring the Distribution of Income,
Wealth, and Poverty 391
The Lorenz Curve 391
U.S. Income Distribution over Time 393
Defining Poverty 394
International Dimensions of Income Inequality 397
The Distribution of Wealth 398
Socioeconomic Dimensions of Income
and Wealth Inequality 400
Income Distribution According to
Socioeconomic Characteristics 400
Income Distribution According to Class 400
Income Distribution and Fairness 403
Philosophical Debates about Equality
and Fairness 403
Fairness and Equality 403
Fairness as Equality of Opportunity 404
The Problems of Redistributing Income 405
Three Important Side Effects of Redistributive
Programs 405
Politics, Income Redistribution, and Fairness 405
Income Redistribution Policies 407
How Successful Have Income Redistribution Programs
Been? 410
Conclusion 411
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 412–415
CHOICE AND DECISION MAKING
19 The Logic of Individual Choice:
The Foundation ofSupply and
Demand 416
Rational Choice Theory 417
Total Utility and Marginal Utility 417
Diminishing Marginal Utility 419
Rational Choice and Marginal Utility 419
Maximizing Utility and Equilibrium 422
An Example of Maximizing Utility 422
Extending the Principle of Rational Choice 423
Rational Choice and the Laws
of Demand and Supply 424
The Law of Demand 424
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 23 11/24/18 11:03 AM
Income and Substitution Effects 425
The Law of Supply 426
Opportunity Cost 427
Applying Economists’ Theory of Choice
to the Real World 427
The Cost of Decision Making 427
Given Tastes 428
Utility Maximization 430
Conclusion 431
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 432–435
Appendix: Indifference Curve Analysis 436
20 Game Theory, Strategic Decision
Making, and Behavioral Economics 441
Game Theory and the Economic
Way of Thinking 442
Game Theory and Economic Modeling 442
The Game Theory Framework 443
The Prisoner’s Dilemma 444
Dominant Strategies and Nash Equilibrium 445
An Overview of Game Theory as a Tool
in Studying Strategic Interaction 447
Some Specific Games 447
Strategies of Players 448
Informal Game Theory and Modern
Behavioral Economics 451
Informal Game Theory 452
Real-World Applications of Informal Game
Theory 452
An Application of Game Theory: Auction
Markets 454
Game Theory and the Challenge to Standard Economic
Assumptions 455
Fairness 455
Endowment Effects 456
Framing Effects 456
Behavioral Economics and the Traditional
Model 456
The Importance of the Traditional Model:
Money Is Not Left on the Table 457
Conclusion 457
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 458–461
Appendix: Game Theory and Oligopoly 462
MODERN ECONOMIC THINKING
21 Thinking Like a Modern
Economist 466
The Nature of Economists’ Models 467
Scientific and Engineering Models 468
Behavioral and Traditional Building Blocks 468
Behavioral Economic Models 468
The Advantages and Disadvantages of Modern Traditional
and Behavioral Models 471
Behavioral and Traditional Informal
(Heuristic)Models 473
The Armchair Economist: Heuristic Models
UsingTraditional Building Blocks 473
The Economic Naturalist: Heuristic Models
UsingBehavioral Building Blocks 476
The Limits of Heuristic Models 477
Empirical and Formal Models 478
The Importance of Empirical Work in Modern
Economics 478
The Role of Formal Models 481
What Difference Does All This Make to Policy? 487
Conclusion 488
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 488–491
22 Behavioral Economics and Modern
Economic Policy 492
Behavioral Economic Policy in Perspective 492
Behavioral Economics and Economic Engineering 493
Economists as Mechanism Design Engineers 494
Behavioral Economics and Mechanism Design 495
Policy Implications of Traditional Economics 497
Choice Architecture and Behavioral
Economic Policy 497
Nudge Policy and Libertarian Paternalism 499
When Are Nudges Needed? 499
Two Types of Nudges 501
The Problems of Implementing Nudges 502
Distinguishing a Nudge from a Push 503
Behavioral and Traditional Economic Policy
Frames 503
Concerns about Behavioral Economic Policies 505
Few Policies Meet the Libertarian Paternalism
Criterion 505
Designing Helpful Policies Is Complicated 505
xxiv Contents
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 24 11/24/18 11:03 AM
Contents xxv
Keynesian Economics 536
The Merging of Classical and Keynesian
Economics 537
Politics as the Driving Force in Macro Policy 537
Two Frameworks: The Long Run and
the Short Run 539
Growth 540
Global Experiences with Growth 541
The Prospect for Future U.S. Growth 542
Business Cycles and Structural Stagnation 542
Describing the Business Cycle 543
Structural Stagnation 545
Unemployment and Jobs 546
How Is Unemployment Measured? 547
Unemployment as a Social Problem 550
Unemployment as Government’s Problem 550
The Future of Unemployment 551
Conclusion 553
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 553–556
25 Measuring and Describing the
Aggregate Economy 557
Aggregate Accounting 558
Calculating GDP 558
The Components of GDP 559
Two Things to Remember about GDP 561
Calculating GDP: Some Examples 563
Some Complications 565
Calculating Aggregate Income 566
Equality of Aggregate Income, Output, and
Production 567
Adjusting for Global Dimensions of Production 568
Inflation: Distinguishing Real from Nominal 568
Real versus Nominal GDP 569
Other Real-World Price Indexes 571
Other Real and Nominal Distinctions 572
Some Limitations of Aggregate Accounting 574
Comparing GDP among Countries 574
GDP Measures Market Activity, Not Welfare 575
Measurement Errors 575
Misinterpretation of Subcategories 575
Genuine Progress Indicator 576
Conclusion 577
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 577–581
It Isn’t Clear Government Knows Better 506
Government Policy May Make the Situation Worse 506
A Changing View of Economists: From Pro-market
Advocates to Economic Engineers 507
Conclusion 507
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 508–510
23 Microeconomic Policy, Economic
Reasoning, and Beyond 511
Economists’ Differing Views about Social Policy 512
How Economists’ Value Judgments Creep into Policy
Proposals 512
The Need for a Worldview 514
Agreement among Economists about Social Policy 514
Economists’ Cost/Benefit Approach
to Government Regulation 515
The Value of Life 515
Comparing Costs and Benefits of Different
Dimensions 517
Putting Cost/Benefit Analysis in Perspective 518
The Problem of Other Things Changing 518
The Cost/Benefit Approach in Context 519
Failure of Market Outcomes 519
Distribution 520
Consumer Sovereignty and Rationality Problems 521
Inalienable Rights 523
Government Failure 524
Conclusion 525
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 527–530
PART III
MACROECONOMICS
MACROECONOMIC BASICS
24 Economic Growth, Business Cycles, and
Unemployment 534
The Historical Development of Macroeconomics 535
From Classical to Keynesian Economics 535
Classical Economics 535
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 25 11/24/18 11:03 AM
POLICY MODELS
26 The Keynesian Short-Run Policy Model:
Demand-Side Policies 582
The Key Insight of the Keynesian AS/AD Model 583
Fixed Price Level 583
The Paradox of Thrift 584
Three Things to Remember about the Keynesian
Model 585
The Components of the AS/AD Model 586
The Aggregate Demand Curve 586
The Slope of the AD Curve 586
Dynamic Price-Level Adjustment Feedback Effects 589
Shifts in the AD Curve 590
The Aggregate Supply Curves 592
The Short-Run Aggregate Supply Curve 592
The Long-Run Aggregate Supply Curve 595
Equilibrium in the Aggregate Economy 596
Integrating the Short-Run and Long-Run Frameworks 597
The Recessionary Gap 598
The Inflationary Gap 599
The Economy beyond Potential 599
Aggregate Demand Policy 599
Some Additional Policy Examples 600
Limitations of the AS/AD Model 602
How Feedback Effects Complicate
the AS/AD
Model 602
Additional Complications That the AS/AD
Model Misses 603
Reality and Models 604
Conclusion 605
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises,
Questions from Alternative Perspectives,
Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 605–608
26W The Multiplier Model 609 and 26W-1
The Multiplier Model 26W-3
Aggregate Production 26W-3
Aggregate Expenditures 26W-3
Determining the Equilibrium Level
of Aggregate Income 26W-8
The Multiplier Equation 26W-9
The Multiplier Process 26W-10
The Circular-Flow Model and the Intuition
behind the Multiplier Process 26W-12
The Multiplier Model in Action 26W-13
Fiscal Policy in the Multiplier Model 26W-16
Fighting Recession: Expansionary Fiscal Policy 26W-16
Fighting Inflation: Contractionary Fiscal Policy 26W-17
Using Taxes Rather Than Expenditures
as the Tool of Fiscal Policy 26W-18
Limitations of the Multiplier Model 26W-19
The Multiplier Model Is Not a Complete Model
of the Economy 26W-19
Shifts Are Sometimes Not as Great as the Model
Suggests 26W-19
Fluctuations Can Sometimes Be Greater
Than the Model Suggests 26W-20
The Price Level Will Often Change in Response
to Shifts in Demand 26W-20
Peoples Forward-Looking Expectations
Make the Adjustment Process Much
More Complicated 26W-21
Shifts in Expenditures Might Reflect Desired Shifts
in Supply and Demand 26W-21
Expenditures Depend on Much More Than Current
Income 26W-21
Conclusion 26W-22
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 26W-22–26W-26
Appendix A: An Algebraic Presentation of the Expanded
Multiplier Model 26W-26
Appendix B: The Multiplier Model and the AS/AD
Model 26W-29
27 The Classical Long-Run Policy Model:
Growth and Supply-Side Policies 610
General Observations about Growth 611
Growth and the Economy’s Potential Output 611
The Benefits and Costs of Growth 613
The Importance of Growth for Living Standards 613
Markets, Specialization, and Growth 614
Economic Growth, Distribution, and Markets 615
Per Capita Growth 616
The Sources of Growth 617
Growth-Compatible Institutions 617
Investment and Accumulated Capital 618
Available Resources 620
Technological Development 621
Entrepreneurship 622
Turning the Sources of Growth into Growth 622
Capital and Investment 622
Technology 623
Growth Policies 626
xxvi Contents
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 26 11/24/18 11:03 AM
Contents xxvii
The Complex Nature of Monetary Policy 670
The Taylor Rule 672
Maintaining Policy Credibility 675
Conclusion 677
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 677–680
30 Financial Crises, Panics,
and Unconventional Monetary
Policy
681
The Central Bank’s Role in a Crisis 682
Anatomy of a Financial Crisis 683
The Financial Crisis: The Bubble Bursts 683
The Fed as the Lender of Last Resort 685
The Role of Leverage and Herding in a Crisis 686
Leverage 686
Herding 686
The Problem of Regulating the Financial Sector 687
Regulation, Bubbles, and the Financial Sector 689
The Law of Diminishing Control 690
General Principles of Regulation 693
Monetary Policy in the Post–Financial Crisis Era 693
Unconventional Monetary Policy 694
Conclusion 697
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 697–700
TAXES, BUDGETS, AND FISCAL POLICY
31 Deficits and Debt:
The Austerity Debate 701
Defining Deficits and Surpluses 702
Financing the Deficit 703
Arbitrariness of Defining Deficits and
Surpluses 703
Many Right Definitions 704
Deficits and Surpluses as Summary Measures 704
Structural and Cyclical Deficits and Surpluses 704
Nominal and Real Deficits and Surpluses 705
Defining Debt and Assets 707
Debt Management 708
Difference between Individual and
Government Debt 710
Conclusion 627
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 628–630
FINANCE, MONEY, AND THE ECONOMY
28 The Financial Sector and
the Economy 631
The Definition and Functions of Money 632
The U.S. Central Bank: The Fed 632
Functions of Money 633
Alternative Measures of Money 636
Distinguishing between Money and Credit 636
Banks and the Creation of Money 638
How Banks Create Money 639
The Process of Money Creation 641
The Relationship between Reserves
and Total Money 644
Faith as the Backing of Our Money Supply 644
Why Is the Financial Sector Important to Macro? 645
The Role of Interest Rates in the Financial Sector 645
Long- and Short-Term Interest Rates 647
The Demand for Money and the Role of the Interest
Rate 647
Why People Hold Money 647
The Many Interest Rates in the Economy 648
Conclusion 650
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 650–653
Appendix: A Closer Look at Financial Assets and
Liabilities 653
29 Monetary Policy 659
How Monetary Policy Works in the Models 659
How Monetary Policy Works in Practice 661
Monetary Policy and the Fed 661
Structure of the Fed 661
Duties of the Fed 664
The Tools of Conventional Monetary Policy 665
Open Market Operations 665
Reserves and the Money Supply 667
Borrowing from the Fed and the Discount Rate 669
The Fed Funds Market 669
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 27 11/24/18 11:03 AM
U.S. Government Deficits and Debt:
The Historical Record 710
The Debt Burden 711
U.S. Debt Relative to Other Countries 712
Interest Rates and Debt Burden 712
Conclusion 714
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 714–717
32 The Fiscal Policy Dilemma 718
Classical Economics and Sound Finance 719
Ricardian Equivalence Theorem: Deficits Don’t Matter 719
The Sound-Finance Precept 720
Keynesian Economics and Functional Finance 721
Assumptions of the AS/AD Model 722
Financing the Deficit Has No Offsetting Effects 722
The Government Knows the Situation 724
The Government Knows the Economy’s
Potential Income Level 724
The Government Has Flexibility in Changing
Spending and Taxes 725
The Size of the Government Debt
Doesn’t Matter 727
Fiscal Policy Doesnt Negatively Affect
Other Government Goals 728
Summary of the Problems 728
Building Fiscal Policies into Institutions 728
How Automatic Stabilizers Work 728
State Government Finance and Procyclical Fiscal
Policy 729
The Negative Side of Automatic Stabilizers 731
Conclusion 731
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 733–735
MACROECONOMIC PROBLEMS
33 Jobs and Unemployment 736
The Debate about the Nature and Measurement of
Unemployment 738
Entrepreneurship and Unemployment 738
Microeconomic Categories of Unemployment 738
Unemployment and Potential Output 740
Is Unemployment Structural or Cyclical? 741
Why Has the Target Rate of Unemployment
Changed over Time? 742
Globalization, Immigration, and Jobs 743
Framing the Debate about Voluntary and
Involuntary Unemployment 744
Individual Responsibility and Unemployment 744
Social Responsibility and Unemployment 744
The Tough Policy Choices 745
Summary of the Debate 746
A Guaranteed-Job Proposal: Government as Employer
of Last Resort 746
The Design and Characteristics of the Program 747
Why Dont the Guaranteed Jobs Do Something Useful? 748
Paying for the Program 749
Would Such a Plan Ever Be Implemented? 750
Conclusion 750
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues To Ponder, Answers
to Margin Questions 751–753
34 Inflation, Deflation, and Macro Policy 754
Defining Inflation 755
Asset Price Inflation and Deflation 755
The Costs and Benefits of Inflation 758
The Costs of Inflation 758
The Benefits of (Low) Inflation 760
The Danger of Accelerating Inflation 762
The Inflation Process and the Quantity
Theory of Money 763
Productivity, Inflation, and Wages 764
The Quantity Theory of Money and Inflation 764
The Declining Influence of the Quantity Theory 766
Inflation and the Phillips Curve Trade-Off 768
The Long-Run and Short-Run Phillips Curves 769
Global Competition and the Phillips Curve 771
Conclusion 772
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 772–776
INTERNATIONAL MACROECONOMIC
POLICY ISSUES
35 International Financial Policy 777
The Balance of Payments 777
The Current Account 779
xxviii Contents
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 28 11/24/18 11:03 AM
Contents xxix
Conclusion 816
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 816–819
37 Structural Stagnation and
Globalization 820
The Structural Stagnation Hypothesis 821
Why the Assumed Underlying Growth
Trend Is Important for Policy 821
Structural Stagnation as a Cause of the Slow
Recovery 824
Structural Stagnations Implications for Macro
Policy 824
Structural, Not Secular, Stagnation 825
The AS/AD Model with Globalization 826
Globalization Can Limit Potential Output 828
International Adjustment Forces 829
Why the Adjustments Did Not Occur 830
Aggregate Demand Increases No Longer
Cause Accelerating Inflation 830
Summary: Globalization and Structural
Imbalances 831
Structural Problems of Globalization 831
Structural Change in the Nontradable Sector 832
Globalization and Income Distribution 833
Remembering the Benefits of Globalization 835
The Future of Globalization 835
Policies to Deal with Structural Stagnation 836
Shifting the World Supply Curve Up 836
Shifting the Domestic SAS Curve Down 838
The Problems with the Standard Political
Solution 839
Conclusion 839
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 840–842
Appendix: Creating a Targeted Safety Net to Help the Least
Well Off 843
38 Macro Policy in Developing
Countries 845
Developing Countries in Perspective 846
Don’t Judge Society by Its Income Alone 847
Some Comparative Statistics on Rich and Poor
Nations 847
The Financial and Capital Account 780
What Is Meant by a Balance of Payments Deficit or
Surplus? 780
Exchange Rates 781
Fundamental Forces Determining Exchange Rates 782
Exchange Rate Dynamics 783
Influencing Exchange Rates with Monetary and Fiscal
Policy 785
The Problems of Determining the
Appropriate Exchange Rate 789
Purchasing Power Parity and Real Exchange Rates 789
Criticisms of the Purchasing Power Parity Method 791
Real Exchange Rates 791
Advantages and Disadvantages of
Alternative Exchange Rate Systems 792
Fixed Exchange Rates 792
Flexible Exchange Rates 793
Partially Flexible Exchange Rates 794
Which View Is Right? 795
Advantages and Disadvantages of a Common
Currency: The Future of the Euro 795
Conclusion 798
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 798–801
Appendix: History of Exchange Rate Systems 802
36 Macro Policy in a Global Setting 805
The Ambiguous International Goals of Macroeconomic
Policy 805
The Exchange Rate Goal 806
The Trade Balance Goal 806
International versus Domestic Goals 808
Balancing the Exchange Rate Goal with Domestic
Goals 808
Monetary and Fiscal Policy and the Trade Deficit 809
Monetary Policy’s Effect on the Trade Balance 809
Fiscal Policy’s Effect on the Trade Balance 810
International Phenomena and Domestic Goals 811
International Goals and Policy Alternatives 811
International Monetary and Fiscal Coordination 812
Coordination Is a Two-Way Street 812
Crowding Out and International Considerations 813
Globalization, Macro Policy, and
the U.S. Economy 813
International Issues and Macro Policy 814
Restoring International Trade Balance to the U.S.
Economy 815
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 29 11/24/18 11:03 AM
Growth versus Development 848
Differing Goals 849
Differing Institutions 849
Monetary Policy in Developing Countries 853
Central Banks Are Less Independent 853
Focus on the International Sector and the
Exchange Rate Constraint 855
The Need for Creativity 857
Obstacles to Economic Development 857
Political Instability 858
Corruption 859
Lack of Appropriate Institutions 860
Lack of Investment 860
Inappropriate Education 863
Overpopulation 865
Health and Disease 867
Conclusion 867
Summary, Key Terms, Questions and Exercises, Questions
from Alternative Perspectives, Issues to Ponder, Answers to
Margin Questions 867–870
Glossary G-1
Colloquial Glossary CG-1
Index I-1
xxx Contents
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 30 11/24/18 11:03 AM
xxxi
List of
Boxes
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 31 11/24/18 11:03 AM
REALWORLD APPLICATION
Winston Churchill and Lady Astor 12
Economists and Market Solutions 16
Economics and Climate Change 19
Made in China? 36
What Government Are We Talking About? 64
Uber, Lyft, and Taxi Pricing 110
Empirically Measuring Elasticities 136
Economists and the Debate about the Corporate
Income Tax 151
The Excess Burden of a Draft 155
Is It Time to Start Paying for Driving on Roads? 173
Climate Change, Global Warming, and Economic P
olicy 181
Hormones and Economics 216
Trump Trade Policy and Antiglobalization Forces 219
Transaction Costs and the Internet 231
Economies of Scale and 3D Printing 251
Travels of a T-Shirt and Economies of Scale 253
Holacracy, Diseconomies of Scale, and Zappos 254
Why Are Textbooks So Long? 256
The Internet and the Perfectly Competitive Model 275
The Shutdown Decision and the Relevant Costs 286
The Dark Side of Amazon 307
Strategic Competition between Uber and Lyft 326
Nefarious Business Practices 332
Why Are CEOs Paid So Much? 343
Branding 352
Are Humans Obsolete? 368
Why Do Women Earn Less Than Men? 375
From Welfare to Work 410
What Game Is Being Played? 450
Can You Explain Landsburg’
s Provocative Insights? 475
Can You Explain Frank’s Observations? 477
Markets as Information-Gathering Mechanisms 496
The Nudge Unit 502
Economists in the Courtroom 516
Where to Locate Polluting Industries 523
The Author’s Biases 538
NBER Dating of the Business Cycle 543
Gross Output: A New Revolutionary Way to Measure
the Economy? 562
The Underground Economy and Undocumented
Immigration 576
Growth and Terrorism 622
Short-Run Supply-Side Macro Policy 627
The Cryptocurrency Bubble
635
Characteristics of a Good Money 638
The Press and Present Value 656
Central Banks in Other Countries 663
Inside an FOMC Meeting 666
Will the Reserve Requirement Be Eliminated? 671
Cryptomania 692
Social Security and the U.S. Deficit 707
Fighting the Vietnam War Inflation 726
Austerity and the Greek Deficit Problem 730
Incentive and Supply-Side Effects of Public Finance 732
Categories of Unemployment 737
Previous Government Jobs Programs 749
Inflation, Nominal Income, and Asset
Inflation Targeting 769
The Exorbitant Privilege Puzzle 781
Iceland’s Monetary Woes 786
Determining the Causes of Fluctuations in
the Dollar’s Value 790
The U.S. Trade Deficit and the Value of the Dollar 807
Why Are the Structural Problems of Globalization So Much
Greater Now? 833
M-Pesa and Leapfrogging 852
A Real, Real-World Application: The Traditional Economy
Meets the Internet 853
Development and the Failure of the Doha Round 861
Sustainable Development Goals 864
ADDED DIMENSION
Economic Knowledge in One Sentence: TANSTAAFL 7
Economics in Perspective 10
Choices in Context: Decision Trees 31
The Developing Country’s Perspective on
Globalization 37
Tradition and Today’s Economy 56
Our International Competitors 67
The Supply and Demand for Children 94
Geometric Tricks for Estimating Price Elasticity 131
The Ambiguity of Total Surplus 146
Pareto Optimality and the Perfectly Competitive
Benchmark 166
xxxii List of Boxes
coL25585_fm_i-xxxii_1.indd 32 11/24/18 11:03 AM
Common Resources and the Tragedy of the Commons 169
Licensure and Surgery 179
International Issues in Perspective 211
Dumping 224
V
alue Added and the Calculation of Total
Production 232
A Trick in Graphing the Marginal Revenue Curve 296
Can Price Controls Increase Output and Lower Market
Price? 303
Monopolizing Monopoly 305
Normative Views of Monopoly 306
Who Controls Corporations? 342
Other Factors of Production 360
Income and Substitution Effects 362
Nonwage Income and Property Rights 373
The Gini Coefficient 396
What Should Be the Goal of Economic Policy? 404
Income Distribution Policy, Fairness, and the Takeaway
Principle 406
Making Stupid Decisions 430
Game Theory and Experimental Economics 448
The Segregation Game and Agent-Based Modeling 453
Neuroeconomics and Microeconomics 472
Karl Marx and Shove Policy 505
Economic Efficiency and the Goals of Society 520
Elasticity and Taxation to Change Behavior 522
The Conventional Policy Wisdom among Economists 526
The Power of Compounding 540
Alternative Measures of the Unemployment Rate 549
From Full Employment to the Target Rate of
Unemployment 551
Is GDP Biased against Women? 564
In the Long Run, We’re All Dead
585
Why Are Prices Inflexible? 593
Demand, Keynesian Economics, and Growth 612
Is Growth Good? 614
Is the 21st Century the Age of Technology or One of Many
Ages of Technology? 624
Interest Rates and the Price of Bonds 649
Do Financial Assets Make Society Richer? 657
How Independent Should the Central Bank Be? 664
Using the Money Multiplier in Practice 668
Generational Accounting 708
The Keeper of the Classical Faith: Milton Friedman 767
Business Cycles in History 822
What to Call Developing Countries 846
A REMINDER
Production Possibility Curves 29
Inverse and Direct Relationships 46
Six Things to Remember about a Demand Curve 85
Six Things to Remember about a Supply Curve 90
Supply and Demand in Action 103
A Review of Various Elasticity Terms 138
What Goods Should Be Taxed? 148
A Review of Costs 244
Finding Output, Price, and Profit 284
A Summary of a Perfectly Competitive Industry 287
Finding a Monopolist’s Output, Price, and Profit 299
A Comparison of Various Market Structures 327
Choices at the Margin 424
The Austan Goolsbee Check-a-Box Method for Finding
Dominant Strategies and Nash Equilibria 446
Modern Traditional and Behavioral Economists 485
A Review of the AS/AD Model 598
Some Limits of Fed Control 675
Conventional Wisdom about Conventional Monetary
Policy 676
Four Important Points about Deficits and Debt 713
Fundamental Forces and Exchange Rates 784
Monetary and Fiscal Policy’s Effect on International
Goals 813
THINKING LIKE A MODERN ECONOMIST
Why Do So Many Prices End in 99 Cents? 130
How to Get Students to Be Responsible 159
What “Goods” Do Firms Produce? The Costs of Producing
Image 238
Social Norms and Production 259
Profit Maximization and Real-World Firms 281
The Traditional Models as Stepping-Stones 417
Mental Accounting 428
Tulipmania, the South Sea Bubble, and Behavioral
Economics 684
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 04/10/18 4:01 PM 2
PART
I
Introduction:
Thinking Like an Economist
CHAPTER 1 Economics and Economic Reasoning
CHAPTER 2 The Production Possibility Model, Trade, and Globalization
CHAPTER 3 Economic Institutions
CHAPTER 4 Supply and Demand
CHAPTER 5 Using Supply and Demand
Part I is an introduction, and an introduction to an intro-
duction seems a little funny. But other sections have in-
troductions, so it seemed a little funny not to have an
introduction to Part I; and besides, as you will see, I’m a
little funny myself (which, in turn, has two interpreta-
tions; I’m sure you will decide which of the two is appro-
priate). It will, however, be a very brief introduction,
consisting of questions you may have had and some
answers to those questions.
Some Questions and Answers
Why study economics?
Because its neat and interesting and helps provide insight
into events that are constantly going on around you.
Why is this book so big?
Because there’s a lot of important information in it and
because the book is designed so your teacher can pick and
choose. You’ll likely not be required to read all of it,
especially if you’re on the quarter system. But once you
start it, you’ll probably read it all anyhow. (Would you
believe?)
Why does this book cost so much?
To answer this question, you’ll have to read the book.
Will this book make me rich?
No.
Will this book make me happy?
It depends.
This book doesnt seem to be written in a normal textbook
style. Is this book really written by a professor?
Yes, but he is different. He misspent his youth working
on cars; he married his high school sweetheart after they
met again at their 20th high school reunion, and they re-
main happily married today, still totally in love. Twenty-
five years after graduating from high school, his wife
went back to medical school and got her MD because
shewas tired of being treated poorly by doctors. Their
five kids make sure he doesnt get carried away in the
professorial cloud.
Will the entire book be like this?
No, the introduction is just trying to rope you in. Much of
the book will be hard going. Learning happens to be a
difficult process: no pain, no gain. But the author isn’t a
sadist; he tries to make learning as pleasantly painful as
possible.
What do the author’s students think of him?
Weird, definitely weird—and hard. But fair, interesting,
and sincerely interested in getting us to learn. (Answer
written by his students.)
So there you have it. Answers to the questions that
you might never have thought of if they hadnt been put in
front of you. I hope they give you a sense of me and the
approach I’ll use in the book. There are some neat ideas
in it. Lets now briefly consider whats in the first five
chapters.
A Survey of the
First Five Chapters
This first section is really an introduction to the rest of the
book. It gives you the background necessary so that the
later chapters make sense. Chapter 1 gives you an over-
view of the entire field of economics as well as an intro-
duction to my style. Chapter 2 focuses on the production
possibility curve, comparative advantage, and trade. It
explains how trade increases production possibilities but
also why, in the real world, free trade and no government
regulation may not be the best policy. Chapter 3 gives you
some history of economic systems and introduces you
tothe institutions of the U.S. economy. Chapters 4 and
5introduce you to supply and demand, and show you
notonly the power of those two concepts but also the
limitations.
Now let’s get on with the show.
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 04/10/18 4:01 PM3
CHAPTER
1
Economics and
Economic Reasoning
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 10/5/18 4:23 PM
In my vacations, I visited the poorest quarters of
several cities and walked through one street after
another, looking at the faces of the poorest people.
Next I resolved to make as thorough a study as
Icould of Political Economy.
—Alfred Marshall
After reading this chapter,
you should be able to:
LO1-1 Define economics and
identify its components.
LO1-2 Discuss various ways in
which economists use
economic reasoning.
LO1-3 Explain real-world events in
terms of economic forces,
social forces, and political
forces.
LO1-4 Explain how economic
insights are developed
andused.
LO1-5 Distinguish among positive
economics, normative
economics, and the art
ofeconomics.
©Ingram Publishing
When an artist looks at the world, he sees color. When a musician looks at the
world, she hears music. When an economist looks at the world, she sees a sym-
phony of costs and benefits. The economists world might not be as colorful or
as melodic as the others’ worlds, but its more practical. If you want to under-
stand whats going on in the world that’s really out there, you need to know
economics.
I hardly have to convince you of this fact if you keep up with the news.
You will be bombarded with stories of unemployment, interest r
ates, how
commodity prices are changing, and how businesses are doing. The list is
endless. So lets say you grant me that economics is important. That still
doesnt mean that it’s worth studying. The real question then is: How much
will you learn? Most of what you learn depends on you, but part depends on
the teacher and another part depends on the textbook. On both these counts,
4
Chapter 1 Economics and Economic Reasoning 5
youre in luck; since your teacher chose this book for your course, you must have a
super teacher.
1
What Economics Is
Economics is the study of how human beings coordinate their wants and desires, given
the decision-making mechanisms, social customs, and political realities of the society.
One of the key words in the definition of the term economics is coordination. Coordi-
nation can mean many things. In the study of economics, coordination refers to how
the three central problems facing any economy are solved. These central problems are:
1. What, and how much, to produce.
2. How to produce it.
3. For whom to produce it.
Three central coordination problems
any economy must solve are what to
produce, how to produce it, and for
whom to produce it.
How hard is it to make the three decisions? Imagine for a moment the problem of
living in a family: the fights, arguments, and questions that come up. “Do I have to do
the dishes?” “Why cant I have piano lessons?” “Bobby got a new sweater. How come
I didnt?” “Mom likes you best.” Now multiply the size of the family by millions. The
same fights, the same arguments, the same questions—only for society the questions
are millions of times more complicated. In answering these questions, economies find
that inevitably individuals want more than is available, given how much they’re will-
ing to work. That means that in our economy there is a problem of scarcitythe
goods available are too few to satisfy individuals’ desires.
The coordination questions faced by
society are complicated.
Scarcity
Scarcity has two elements: our wants and our means of fulfilling those wants. These
can be interrelated since wants are changeable and partially determined by society. The
way we fulfill wants can affect those wants. For example, if you work on Wall Street,
you will probably want upscale and trendy clothes. In Vermont I am quite happy wearing
Levi’s and flannel; in Florida I am quite happy in shorts.
The degree of scarcity is constantly changing. The quantity of goods, services, and
usable resources depends on technology and human action, which underlie production.
Individuals’ imagination, innovativeness, and willingness to do what needs to be done
can greatly increase available goods and resources. Who knows what technologies are
in our future—nanites or micromachines that change atoms into whatever we want
could conceivably eliminate scarcity of goods we currently consume. But they would
not eliminate scarcity entirely since new wants are constantly developing.
The quantity of goods, services,
and usable resources depends on
technology and human action.
So, how does an economy deal with scarcity? The answer is coercion. In all known
economies, coordination has involved some type of coercion—limiting people’s wants
and increasing the amount of work individuals are willing to do to fulfill those wants.
The reality is that many people would rather play than help solve society’s problems.
So the basic economic problem involves inspiring people to do things that other people
want them to do, and not to do things that other people dont want them to do. Thus, an
alternative definition of economics is: the study of how to get people to do things
they’re not wild about doing (such as studying) and not to do things they are wild
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 5 04/10/18 4:01 PM
1
This book is written by a person, not a machine. That means that I have my quirks, my odd sense
of humor, and my biases. All textbook writers do. Most textbooks have the quirks and eccentricities
edited out so that all the books read and sound alike—professional but dull. I choose to sound like
me—sometimes professional, sometimes playful, and sometimes stubborn. In my view, that makes
the book more human and less dull. So forgive me my quirks—don’t always take me too seriously—
and I’ll try to keep you awake when you’re reading this book at 3 a.m. the day of the exam. If you
think it’s a killer to read a book this long, you ought to try writing one.
6 Introduction Thinking Like an Economist
about doing (such as eating all the ice cream they like), so that the things some people
want to do are consistent with the things other people want to do.
Microeconomics and Macroeconomics
Economic theory is divided into two parts: microeconomic theory and macroeconomic
theory. Microeconomic theory considers economic reasoning from the viewpoint of indi-
viduals and firms and builds up to an analysis of the whole economy. Microeconomics is
the study of individual choice, and how that choice is influenced by economic forces.
Microeconomics studies such things as the pricing policies of firms, households’ deci-
sions on what to buy, and how markets allocate resources among alternative ends.
Microeconomics is the study of how
individual choice is influenced by
economic forces.
As we build up from microeconomic analysis to an analysis of the entire economy,
everything gets rather complicated. Many economists try to uncomplicate matters by taking
a different approach—a macroeconomic approach—first looking at the aggregate, or
whole, and then breaking it down into components. Macroeconomics is the study of the
economy as a whole. It considers the problems of inflation, unemployment, business cycles,
and growth. Macroeconomics focuses on aggregate relationships such as how household
consumption is related to income and how government policies can affect growth.
Macroeconomics is the study of the
economy as a whole. It considers the
problems of inflation, unemployment,
business cycles, and growth.
Consider an analogy to the human body. A micro approach analyzes a person by
looking first at each individual cell and then builds up. A macro approach starts with
the person and then goes on to his or her components—arms, legs, fingernails, feel-
ings, and so on. Put simply, microeconomics analyzes from the parts to the whole;
macroeconomics analyzes from the whole to the parts.
Q-1 Classify the following topics
asprimarily macroeconomic or
microeconomic:
1. The impact of a tax increase on
aggregate output.
2. The relationship between two
competing firms’ pricing behavior.
3. A farmer’s decision to plant soy or
wheat.
4. The effect of trade on economic
growth.
Microeconomics and macroeconomics are very much interrelated. What happens in
the economy as a whole is based on individual decisions, but individual decisions are
made within an economy and can be understood only within its macro context. For
example, whether a firm decides to expand production capacity will depend on what the
owners expect will happen to the demand for their products. Those expectations are
determined by macroeconomic conditions. Because microeconomics focuses on indi-
viduals and macroeconomics focuses on the whole economy, traditionally microeco-
nomics and macroeconomics are taught separately, even though they are interrelated.
A Guide to Economic Reasoning
People trained in economics think in a certain way. They analyze everything critically;
they compare the costs and the benefits of every issue and make decisions based on those
costs and benefits. For example, say you’re trying to decide whether a policy to eliminate
terrorist attacks on airlines is a good idea. Economists are trained to put their emotions
aside and ask: What are the costs of the policy, and what are the benefits? Thus, they are
open to the argument that security measures, such as conducting body searches of every
passenger or scanning all baggage with bomb-detecting machinery, might not be the
appropriate policy because the costs might exceed the benefits. To think like an econo-
mist involves addressing almost all issues using a cost/benefit approach. Economic rea-
soning also involves abstracting from the “unimportant” elements of a question and
focusing on the “important” ones by creating a simple model that captures the essence of
the issue or problem. How do you know whether the model has captured the important
elements? By collecting empirical evidence and “testing” the model—matching the
predictions of the model with the empirical evidence—to see if it fits. Economic
reasoning—how to think like a modern economist, making decisions on the basis of
costs and benefits—is the most important lesson you’ll learn from this book.
Economic reasoning is making decisions
on the basis of costs and benefits.
The book Freakonomics gives examples of the economists approach. It describes
a number of studies by University of Chicago economist Steve Levitt that unlock
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 6 04/10/18 4:01 PM
7
ADDED DIMENSION
Economic Knowledge in One Sentence: TANSTAAFL
Once upon a time, Tanstaafl was made king of all the
lands. His first act was to call his economic advisers and
tell them to write up all the economic knowledge the society
possessed. After years of work, they presented their mon-
umental effort: 25 volumes, each about 400 pages long.
But in the interim, King Tanstaafl had become a very busy
man, what with running a kingdom of all the lands and all.
Looking at the lengthy volumes, he told his advisers to
summarize their findings in one volume.
Despondently, the economists returned to their desks,
wondering how they could summarize what they’d
been so
careful to spell out. After many more years of rewriting, they
were finally satisfied with their one-volume effort and tried
to make an appointment to see the king. Unfortunately, af-
fairs of state had become even more pressing than before,
and the king couldn’t take the time to see them. Instead he
sent word to them that he couldn’t be bothered with a whole
volume, and ordered them, under threat of death (for he had
become a tyrant), to reduce the work to one sentence.
The economists returned to their desks, shivering in
their sandals and pondering their impossible task. Think-
ing about their fate if they were not successful, they de-
cided to send out for one last meal. Unfortunately, when
they were collecting money to pay for the meal, they dis-
covered they were broke. The disgusted delivery person
took the last meal back to the restaurant, and the econo-
mists started down the path to the beheading station. On
the way
, the delivery person’s parting words echoed in
their ears. They looked at each other and suddenly they
realized the truth. “We’re saved!” they screamed. “That’s it!
That’s economic knowledge in one sentence!” They wrote
down the sentence and presented it to the king, who
thereafter fully understood all economic problems. (He
also gave them a good meal.) The sentence?
There Ain’t No Such Thing As A Free Lunch—
TANSTAAFL
seemingly mysterious observations with basic economic reasoning. For example, Levitt
asked the question: Why do drug dealers on the street tend to live with their mothers?
The answer he arrived at was that they couldnt afford to live on their own; most
earned less than $5 an hour. Why, then, were they dealing drugs and not working a
legal job that, even for a minimum wage job, paid over $7 an hour? The answer to that
is determined through cost/benefit analysis. While their current income was low, their
potential income as a drug dealer was much higher since, given their background and
existing U.S. institutions, they were more likely to move up to a high position in
thelocal drug business (and Freakonomics describes how it is a business) and earn a
six-figure income than they were to move up from working as a Taco Bell technician to
an executive earning a six-figure income in corporate America. Levitts model is a very
simple one—people do what is in their best interest financially—and it assumes that
people rely on a cost/benefit analysis to make decisions. Finally, he supports his argu-
ment through careful empirical work, collecting and organizing the data to see if they fit
the model. His work is a good example of “thinking like a modern economist” in action.
Economic reasoning, once learned, is infectious. If you’re susceptible, being
exposed to it will change your life. It will influence your analysis of everything, includ-
ing issues normally considered outside the scope of economics. For example, you will
likely use economic reasoning to decide the possibility of getting a date for Saturday
night, and who will pay for dinner. You will likely use it to decide whether to read this
book, whether to attend class, whom to marry, and what kind of work to go into after
you graduate. This is not to say that economic reasoning will provide all the answers.
As you will see throughout this book, real-world questions are inevitably complicated,
and economic reasoning simply provides a framework within which to approach a
question. In the economic way of thinking, every choice has costs and benefits, and
decisions are made by comparing them.
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 7 04/10/18 4:01 PM
8 Introduction Thinking Like an Economist
Marginal Costs and Marginal Benefits
The relevant costs and relevant benefits to economic reasoning are the expected incre-
mental, or additional, costs incurred and the expected incremental benefits that result
from a decision. Economists use the term marginal when referring to additional or
incremental. Marginal costs and marginal benefits are key concepts.
A marginal cost is the additional cost to you over and above the costs you have
already incurred. That means not counting sunk costscosts that have already been
incurred and cannot be recovered—in the relevant costs when making a decision.
Consider, for example, attending class. Youve already paid your tuition; it is a sunk
cost. So the marginal (or additional) cost of going to class does not include tuition.
Web Note 1.1
Costs and Benefits
Similarly with marginal benefit. A marginal benefit is the additional benefit
abov
e what youve already derived. The marginal benefit of reading this chapter is the
additional knowledge you get from reading it. If you already knew everything in this
chapter before you picked up the book, the marginal benefit of reading it now is zero.
The Economic Decision Rule
Comparing marginal (additional) costs with marginal (additional) benefits will often
tell you how you should adjust your activities to be as well off as possible. Just follow
the economic decision rule:
If the marginal benefits of doing
something exceed the marginal costs,
do it. If the marginal costs of doing
something exceed the marginal
benefits, don’t do it.
If the marginal benefits of doing something exceed the marginal costs, do it.
If the marginal costs of doing something exceed the marginal benefits, dont do it.
As an example, lets consider a discussion I might have with a student who tells me that
she is too busy to attend my classes. I respond, “Think about the tuition youve spent for this
class—it works out to about $60 a lecture.” She answers that the book she reads for class is a
book that I wrote, and that I wrote it so clearly she fully understands everything. She goes on:
Q-2 Say you bought a share of
Oracle for $100 and a share of Cisco for
$10. The price of each is currently $15.
Assuming taxes are not an issue, which
would you sell if you needed $15?
I’ve already paid the tuition and whether I go to class or not, I cant get any of the
tuition back, so the tuition is a sunk cost and doesnt enter into my decision. The
marginal cost to me is what I could be doing with the hour instead of spending it
in class. I value my time at $75 an hour [people who understand everything value
their time highly], and even though I’ve heard that your lectures are super, I esti-
mate that the marginal benefit of attending your class is only $50. The marginal
cost, $75, exceeds the marginal benefit, $50, so I don’t attend class.
I congratulate her on her diplomacy and her economic reasoning, but tell her that I give
a quiz every week, that students who miss a quiz fail the quiz, that those who fail all the quiz-
zes fail the course, and that those who fail the course do not graduate. In short, she is under-
estimating the marginal benefits of attending my classes. Correctly estimated, the marginal
benefits of attending my class exceed the marginal costs. So she should attend my class.
Economics and Passion
Recognizing that everything has a cost is reasonable, but its a reasonableness that
many people dont like. It takes some of the passion out of life. It leads you to consider
possibilities like these:
Web Note 1.2
Blogonomics
Saving some people’s lives with liver transplants might not be worth the
additional cost. The money might be better spent on nutritional programs that
would save 20 lives for every 2 lives you might save with transplants.
Maybe we shouldnt try to eliminate all pollution because the additional cost
ofdoing so may be too high. To eliminate all pollution might be to forgo too
much of some other worthwhile activity.
Economic reasoning is based on the
premise that everything has a cost.
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 8 04/10/18 4:01 PM
Chapter 1 Economics and Economic Reasoning 9
Providing a guaranteed job for every person who
wants one might not be a worthwhile policy goal if it
means that doing so will reduce the ability of an
economy to adapt to new technologies.
You get the idea. This kind of reasonableness is often
criticized for being coldhearted. But, not surprisingly, econ-
omists disagree; they argue that their reasoning leads to a
better society for the majority of people.
Economists’ reasonableness isnt universally appreciated.
Businesses love the result; others aren’t so sure, as I discovered
some years back when my then-girlfriend told me she was leav-
ing me. “Why?,” I asked. “Because,” she responded, “you’re
so, so . . . reasonable.” It took me many years after she left to
learn what she already knew: There are many types of reason-
ableness, and not everyone thinks an economists reasonable-
ness is a virtue. I’ll discuss such issues later; for now, let me
simply warn you that, for better or worse, studying economics
will lead you to view questions in a cost/benefit framework.
Opportunity costs have always made choice difficult, as we
see in the early-19th-century engraving One or the Other.
©Heritage Images/Houlton Archive/Getty Images
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 9 04/10/18 4:01 PM
Opportunity Cost
Putting economists’ cost/benefit rules into practice isnt easy. To do so, you have to be
able to choose and measure the costs and benefits correctly. Economists have devised the
concept of opportunity cost to help you do that. Opportunity cost is the benefit that you
might have gained from choosing the next-best alternative. To obtain the benefit of
something, you must give up (forgo) something else—namely, the next-best alternative.
The opportunity cost is the market value of that next-best alternative; it is a cost because
in choosing one thing, you are precluding an alternative choice. The TANSTAAFL story
in the earlier Added Dimension box embodies the opportunity cost concept because it
tells us that there is a cost to everything; that cost is the next-best forgone alternative.
Q-3 Can you think of a reason why
acost/benefit approach to a problem
might be inappropriate? Can you give
an example?
Lets consider some examples. The opportunity cost of going out once with Natalie
(or Nathaniel), the most beautiful woman (attractive man) in the world, is the benefit
youd get from going out with your solid steady, Margo (Mike). The opportunity cost
of cleaning up the environment might be a reduction in the money available to assist
low-income individuals. The opportunity cost of having a child might be two boats,
three cars, and a two-week vacation each year for five years, which are what you could
have had if you hadnt had the child. (Kids really are this expensive.)
Opportunity cost is the basis of cost/
benefit economic reasoning; it is the
benefit that you might have gained from
choosing the next-best alternative.
Examples are endless, but lets consider two that are particularly relevant to you: what
courses to take and how much to study. Lets say youre a full-time student and at the
beginning of the term you had to choose five courses. Taking one precludes taking some
other, and the opportunity cost of taking an economics course may well be not taking a
course on theater. Similarly with studying: You have a limited amount of time to spend
studying economics, studying some other subject, sleeping, or partying. The more time
you spend on one activity, the less time you have for another. That’s opportunity cost.
Notice how neatly the opportunity cost concept takes into account costs and bene-
fits of all other options and converts these alternative benefits into costs of the decision
youre now making. One of the most useful aspects of the opportunity cost concept is
that it focuses on two aspects of costs of a choice that often might be forgotten—
implicit costs and illusionary sunk costs. Implicit costs are costs associated with a
decision that often arent included in normal accounting costs.
For example, in thinking about whether it makes sense to read this book, the next-
best value of the time you spend reading it should be one of the costs that y
ou consider.
Web Note 1.3
Opportunity Cost
10
ADDED DIMENSION
Economics in Perspective
All too often, students study economics out of context.
They’re presented with sterile analysis and boring facts to
memorize, and are never shown how economics fits into
the larger scheme of things. That’s bad; it makes econom-
ics seem boring—but economics is not boring. Every so
often throughout this book, sometimes in the appendixes
and sometimes in these boxes, I’ll step back and put the
analysis in perspective, giving you an idea from whence
the analysis sprang and its historical context. In educa-
tional jargon, this is called enrichment.
I begin here with economics itself.
First, its history: In the 1500s there were few universi-
ties. Those that existed taught religion,
Latin, Greek, phi-
losophy, history, and mathematics. No economics. Then
came the Enlightenment (about 1700), in which reasoning
replaced God as the explanation of why things were the
way they were. Pre-Enlightenment thinkers would answer
the question “Why am I poor?” with “Because God wills it.
Enlightenment scholars looked for a different explanation.
“Because of the nature of land ownership” is one answer
they found.
Such reasoned explanations required more knowledge
of the way things were, and the amount of information ex-
panded so rapidly that it had to be divided or categorized
for an individual to have hope of knowing a subject. Soon
philosophy was subdivided into science and philosophy. In
the 1700s, the sciences were
split into natural sciences
and social sciences. The amount of knowledge kept increas-
ing, and in the late 1800s and early 1900s social science
itself split into subdivisions: economics, political science,
history, geography, sociology, anthropology, and psychol-
ogy. Many of the insights about how the economic system
work
ed were codified in Adam Smith’s The Wealth of
Nations, written in 1776. Notice that this is before econom-
ics as a subdiscipline developed, and Adam Smith could
also be classified as an anthropologist, a sociologist, a
political scientist, and a social philosopher.
Throughout the 18th and 19th centuries, economists such
as Adam Smith, Thomas Malthus, John Stuart Mill, David
Ricardo, and Karl Marx were more than economists; they
were social philosophers who covered all aspects of social
science. These writers were subsequently called Classical
economists. Alfred Marshall continued in that classical tradi-
tion, and his book, Principles of Economics, published in the
late 1800s, was written with the other social sciences much
in evidence. But Marshall also changed the questions econ-
omists ask; he focused on those questions that could be
asked in a graphical supply/demand framework.
This book falls solidly in the Marshallian tradition. It
presents economics as a way of thinking—as an engine of
analysis used to understand real-world phenomena. But
itgoes beyond Marshall, and introduces you to a wider
variety of models and thinking than the supply and demand
models that Marshall used.
Marshallian economics is primarily about policy, not
theory. It sees institutions as well as political and social di-
mensions of reality as important, and it shows you how
economics ties in to those dimensions.
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 10 04/10/18 4:01 PM
Often, it isnt because it is an implicit, not normally measured cost. Similarly with
firms—owners often think that they are making a profit from a business, but if they
add the value of their time to their cost, which economists argue they should, then their
profit often becomes a loss. They might have earned more simply by taking a job
somewhere else. Implicit costs should be included in opportunity costs. Sunk costs,
however, are often included in making decisions, but should not be. These costs are
called illusionary sunk costs—costs that show up in financial accounts but that econo-
mists argue should not be considered in a choice because they are already spent. They
will not change regardless of what the person making the decision chooses. For exam-
ple, once you have bought a book (that cant be resold), what you paid for that book is
sunk. Following economic reasoning, that sunk cost shouldnt enter into your decision
on whether to read it. An important role of the opportunity cost concept is to remind
you that the costs relevant to decisions are often different from the measured costs.
The costs relevant to decisions are often
different from the measured costs.
The relevance of opportunity cost isnt limited to your individual decisions. Oppor-
tunity costs are also relevant to governments decisions, which affect everyone in
society. A common example is what is called the guns-versus-butter debate. The
Chapter 1 Economics and Economic Reasoning 11
resources that a society has are limited; therefore, its decision to use those resources to
have more guns (more weapons) means that it will have less butter (fewer consumer
goods). Thus, when society decides to spend $50 billion more on an improved health
care system, the opportunity cost of that decision is $50 billion not spent on helping
the homeless, paying off some of the national debt, or providing for national defense.
Q-4 John, your study partner, has
just said that the opportunity cost of
studying this chapter is about 1/38 the
price you paid for this book, since the
chapter is about 1/38 of the book. Is he
right? Why or why not?
The opportunity cost concept has endless implications. It can even be turned upon itself.
For instance, thinking about alternatives takes time; that means that there’s a cost to being
reasonable, so its only reasonable to be somewhat unreasonable. If you followed that argu-
ment, youve caught the economic bug. If you didnt, dont worry. Just remember the oppor-
tunity cost concept for now; I’ll infect you with economic thinking in the rest of the book.
Economic Forces, Social Forces,
and Political Forces
The opportunity cost concept applies to all aspects of life and is fundamental to under-
standing how society reacts to scarcity. When goods are scarce, those goods must be
rationed. That is, a mechanism must be chosen to determine who gets what.
Q-5 Ali, your study partner, states
that rationing health care is immoral—
that health care should be freely
available to all individuals in society.
How would you respond?
Economic and Market Forces
Lets consider some specific real-world rationing mechanisms. Dormitory rooms are
often rationed by lottery, and permission to register in popular classes is often rationed
by a first-come, first-registered rule. Food in the United States, however, is generally
rationed by price. If price did not ration food, there wouldnt be enough food to go
around. All scarce goods must be rationed in some fashion. These rationing mecha-
nisms are examples of economic forces, the necessary reactions to scarcity.
When an economic force operates
through the market, it becomes a
market force.
One of the important choices that a society must make is whether to allow these
economic forces to operate freely and openly or to try to rein them in. A market force
is an economic force that is given relatively free rein by society to work through the
market. Market forces ration by changing prices. When there’s a shortage, the price
goes up. When there’s a surplus, the price goes down. Much of this book will be devoted
to analyzing how the market works like an invisible hand, guiding economic forces to
coordinate individual actions and allocate scarce resources. The invisible hand is the
price mechanism, the rise and fall of prices that guides our actions in a market.
Economic reality is controlled by
threeforces:
1. Economic forces (the invisible hand).
2. Social forces.
3. Political forces.
Social and Political Forces
Societies cant choose whether or not to allow economic forces to operate—economic
forces are always operating. However, societies can choose whether to allow market forces
to predominate. Social forcesforces that guide individual actions even though those
actions may not be in an individual’s selfish interest, and political forces—legal direc-
tives that direct individuals’ actions—play a major role in deciding whether to letmarket
forces operate. Economic reality is determined by a contest among these various forces.
Lets consider a historical example in which social forces prevented an economic
force from becoming a market force: the problem of getting a date for Saturday night
back when people actually dated (or called the pairing off of two individuals a “date”).
If a school (or a society) had significantly more heterosexual people of one gender than
the other (lets say more men than women), some men would find themselves without a
date—that is, men would be in excess supply—and would have to find something else
to do, say study or go to a movie by themselves. An “excess supply” person could solve
the problem by paying someone to go out with him or her, but that would have changed
the nature of the date in unacceptable ways. It would be revolting to the person who
offered payment and to the person who was offered payment. That unacceptability is an
Social, cultural, and political forces can
play a significant role in the economy.
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 11 10/5/18 4:24 PM
12
REALWORLD APPLICATION
Winston Churchill and Lady Astor
There are many stories about Nancy Astor,
the first woman elected to Britain’s Parlia-
ment. A vivacious, fearless American woman,
she married into the English aristocracy and,
during the 1930s and 1940s, became a bright
light on the English social and political
scenes, which were already quite bright.
One story told about Lady Astor is that
she and Winston Churchill, the unorthodox
genius who had a long and distinguished
political career and who was Britain’s prime
minister during World War II, were sitting in a
pub having a theoretical discussion about
morality. Churchill suggested that as a
thought experiment Lady Astor ponder the
following question: If a man were to promise her a huge
amount of money—say a million pounds—for the privi-
lege, would she sleep with him? Lady Astor did ponder
the question for a while and finally answered, yes, she
Lady Astor
©Bettmann/Getty Images
would, if the money were guaranteed.
Churchill then asked her if she would sleep
with him for five pounds. Her response
was sharp: “Of course not. What do you
think I am—a prostitute?” Churchill re-
sponded, “We have already established that
fact; we are now simply negotiating about
price.
One moral that economists might draw
from this story is that economic incentives, if
high enough, can have a powerful influence
on behavior. But an equally important moral
of the story is that noneconomic incentives
also can be very strong. Why do most people
feel it’s wrong to sell sex for money, even if
they might be willing to do so if the price were high
enough? Keeping this second moral in mind will signifi-
cantly increase your economic understanding of real-
world events.
Q-6 Your study partner, Joan, states
that market forces are always operative.
Is she right? Why or why not?
example of the complex social and cultural norms that guide and limit our activities.
People dont try to buy dates because social forces prevent them from doing so.
2
Often political and social forces work together against the invisible hand. For exam-
ple, in the United States there arent enough babies to satisfy all the couples who desire
them. Babies born to particular sets of parents are rationed—by luck. Consider a group of
parents, all of whom want babies. Those who can, have a baby; those who cant have one,
but want one, try to adopt. Adoption agencies ration the available babies. Who gets a baby
depends on whom people know at the adoption agency and on the desires of the birth
mother, who can often specify the socioeconomic background (and many other character-
istics) of the family in which she wants her baby to grow up. Thats the economic force in
action; it gives more power to the supplier of something thats in short supply.
If our society allowed individuals to buy and sell babies, that economic force would
be translated into a mark
et force. The invisible hand would see to it that the quantity of
babies supplied would equal the quantity of babies demanded at some price. The market,
not the adoption agencies, would do the rationing.
3
2
Pairing habits of young adults have changed in ways that have made “dating” somewhat of a
historical social convention. The new social conventions that guide such pairing functions do not
eliminate the problem of excess individuals, but they do obscure it and create multiple dimensions
of “excess.” Thinking about how they do so is a useful exercise.
3
Even though its against the law, some babies are nonetheless “sold” on a semilegal market, also called
a gray market. Recently, the “market price” for a healthy baby was about $30,000. If selling babies were
legal (and if people didnt find it morally repugnant to have babies in order to sell them), the price would
be much lower because there would be a larger supply of babies. (It was not against the law to sell
human eggs in the early 2000s, and one human egg was sold for $50,000. The average price was much
lower; it varied with donor characteristics such as SAT scores and athletic accomplishments.)
©Rachel Epstein/PhotoEdit
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 12 04/10/18 4:01 PM
Chapter 1 Economics and Economic Reasoning 13
Most people, including me, find the idea of selling babies
repugnant. But why? Its the strength of social forces reinforced
by political forces. One can think of hundreds of examples of
such social and political forces overriding economic forces.
What is and isnt allowable differs from one society to
another. For example, in North Korea, many private businesses
are against the law, so not many people start their own busi-
nesses. In the United States, until the 1970s, it was against the
law to hold gold except in jewelry and for certain limited uses
such as dental supplies, so most people refrained from holding
gold. Ultimately a country’s laws and social norms determine
whether the invisible hand will be allowed to work.
People don’t charge friends
interest to borrow money.
©Syda Productions/Shutterstock
Social and political forces are active in all parts of your life.
You don’t practice medicine without a license; you dont sell
body parts or certain addictive drugs. These actions are against the law. But many
people do sell alcohol; that’s not against the law if you have a permit. You don’t charge
your friends interest to borrow money (youd lose friends); you dont charge your chil-
dren for their food (parents are supposed to feed their children); many sports and media
stars dont sell their autographs (some do, but many consider the practice tacky); you
dont lower the wage you’ll accept in order to take a job from someone else (you’re no
scab). The list is long. You cannot understand economics without understanding the
limitations that political and social forces place on economic actions.
In summary, what happens in a society can be seen as the reaction to, and interac-
tion of, t
hree sets of forces: (1) economic forces, (2) political and legal forces, and
(3)social and cultural forces. Economics has a role to play in sociology and politics,
just as sociology and politics have roles to play in economics.
What happens in society can be seen
asa reaction to, and interaction of,
economic forces with other forces.
Using Economic Insights
Economic insights are based on generalizations, called theories, about the workings of
an abstract economy as well as on contextual knowledge about the institutional struc-
ture of the economy. In this book I will introduce you to economic theories and mod-
els. Theories and models tie together economists’ terminology and knowledge about
economic institutions. Theories are inevitably too abstract to apply in specific cases,
and thus a theory is often embodied in an economic modela framework that places
the generalized insights of the theory in a more specific contextual setting—or in an
economic principlea commonly held economic insight stated as a law or principle.
To see the importance of principles, think back to when you learned to add. You didnt
memorize the sum of 147 and 138; instead, you learned a principle of addition. The
principle says that when adding 147 and 138, you first add 7 + 8, which you memo-
rized was 15. You write down the 5 and carry the 1, which you add to 4 + 3 to get 8.
Then add 1 + 1 = 2. So the answer is 285. When you know just one principle, you
know how to add millions of combinations of numbers.
Web Note 1.4
Hip Hop Economics
Theories, models, and principles are continually “brought to the data” to see if the
predictions of the model match the data. Increases in computing po
wer and new statis-
tical techniques have given modern economists a far more rigorous set of procedures
to determine how well the predictions fit the data than was the case for earlier econo-
mists. This has led to a stronger reliance on quantitative empirical methods in modern
economics than in earlier economics.
Modern empirical work takes a variety of forms. In certain instances, economists
study questions by running controlled laborat
ory experiments. That branch of economics
is called experimental economicsa branch of economics that studies the economy
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 13 10/5/18 4:25 PM
14 Introduction Thinking Like an Economist
through controlled experiments. These include laboratory experiments—experiments
in which individuals are brought into a computer laboratory and their reactions to
various treatments are measured and analyzed; field experiments—experiments in which
treatments in the real world are measured and analyzed; computer experiments—
experiments in which simulated economies are created within the computer and results
of various policies are explored; and natural experiments—naturally occurring events
that approximate a controlled experiment where something has changed in one place
but has not changed somewhere else.
An example of a natural experiment occurred when New Jersey raised its minimum
wage and neighboring state Pennsylvania did not. Economists Alan Kruger and David
Card compared the effects on unemployment in both states and found that increases in
the minimum wage in New Jersey did not significantly affect employment. This led to
a debate about what the empirical evidence was telling us. The reason is that in such
natural experiments, it is impossible to hold “other things constant,” as is done in labo-
ratory and field experiments, and thus the empirical results in economics are more
subject to dispute.
While economic models are less general than theories, they are still usually too
general to apply in specific cases. Models lead to theorems (propositions that are
logically true based on the assumptions in a model). To arrive at policy precepts
(policy rules that conclude that a particular course of action is preferable), theo-
rems must be combined with knowledge of real-world economic institutions and
value judgments determining the goals for which one is striving. In discussing
policy implications of theories and models, it is important to distinguish precepts
from theorems.
Theories, models, and principles must
be combined with a knowledge of real-
world economic institutions to arrive at
specific policy recommendations.
Economic analysis changes as technology changes. In recent years, data availabil-
ity and computational power have increased exponentially, and this has changed the
way economists study problems. Economists fresh out of graduate school are much
more likely than older economists to “let the data speak,” which means to use comput-
ing power to look for stable statistical relationships in the data and then use those
relationships to guide their policy. Modern economists are highly involved with the
development of systems that can perform tasks that people previously believed
required human intelligence such as the ability to learn from the past, find meaning,
and reason, known as artificial intelligence and deep learning systems. In many ways,
the algorithmic approach to problems underlying these systems reflects economists’—
such as Herbert Simon and Friedrich von Hayek—theories of how an economy works
and how systems process information.
The Invisible Hand Theorem
Knowing a theory gives you insight into a wide variety of economic phenomena even
though you dont know the particulars of each phenomenon. For example, much of
economic theory deals with the pricing mechanism and how the market operates to
coordinate individuals’ decisions. Economists have come to the following theorems:
When the quantity supplied is greater than the quantity demanded, price has a
tendency to fall.
When the quantity demanded is greater than the quantity supplied, price has a
tendency to rise.
Q-7 There has been a superb
growing season and the quantity
of tomatoes supplied exceeds the
quantity demanded. What is likely
tohappen to the price of tomatoes?
Using these generalized theorems, economists have developed a theory of markets
that leads to the further theorem that, under certain conditions, markets are efficient.
That is, the market will coordinate individuals’ decisions, allocating scarce resources
efficiently. Efficiency means achieving a goal as cheaply as possible. Economists call
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 14 04/10/18 4:01 PM
Chapter 1 Economics and Economic Reasoning 15
this theorem the invisible hand theorema market economy, through the price
mechanism, will tend to allocate resources efficiently.
Theories, and the models used to represent them, are enormously efficient methods
of conveying information, but they’re also necessarily abstract. They rely on simplify-
ing assumptions, and if you don’t know the assumptions, you don’t know the theory.
The result of forgetting assumptions could be similar to what happens if you forget that
youre supposed to add numbers in columns. Forgetting that, yet remembering all the
steps, can lead to a wildly incorrect answer. For example,
If you don’t know the assumptions, you
don’t know the theory.
147
+138
1,608 is wrong.
Knowing the assumptions of theories and models allows you to progress beyond
gut reaction and better understand the strengths and weaknesses of various economic
theories and models. Lets consider a central economic assumption: the assumption
that individuals behave rationally—that what they choose reflects what makes them
happiest, given the constraints. If that assumption doesnt hold, the invisible hand
theorem doesn’t hold.
Presenting the invisible hand theorem in its full beauty is an important part of any
economics course. Presenting the assumptions on which it is based and the limitations
of the invisible hand is likewise an important part of the course. I’ll do both through-
out the book.
Economic Theory and Stories
Economic theory, and the models in which that theory is presented, often developed as
a shorthand way of telling a story. These stories are important; they make the theory
come alive and convey the insights that give economic theory its power. In this book
Ipresent plenty of theories and models, but they’re accompanied by stories that provide
the context that makes them relevant.
Theory is a shorthand way of telling
astory.
At times, because there are many new terms, discussing theories takes up much of
the presentation time and becomes a bit oppressive. Thats the nature of the beast. As
Albert Einstein said, “Theories should be as simple as possible, but not more so.
When a theory becomes oppressive, pause and think about the underlying story that
the theory is meant to convey. That story should make sense and be concrete. If you
cant translate the theory into a story, you dont understand the theory.
Economic Institutions
To know whether you can apply economic theory to reality, you must know about eco-
nomic institutions—laws, common practices, and organizations in a society that affect
the economy. Corporations, governments, and cultural norms are all examples of eco-
nomic institutions. Many economic institutions have social, political, and religious
dimensions. For example, your job often influences your social standing. In addition,
many social institutions, such as the family, have economic functions. I include any insti-
tution that significantly affects economic decisions as an economic institution because
you must understand that institution if you are to understand how the economy functions.
To apply economic theory to reality,
you’ve got to have a sense of economic
institutions.
Economic institutions sometimes seem to operate in ways quite different than eco-
nomic theory predicts. For example, economic theory says that prices are determined
by supply and demand. However, businesses say that they set prices by rules of
thumb—often by what are called cost-plus-markup rules. That is, a firm determines
what its costs are, multiplies by 1.4 or 1.5, and the result is the price it sets. Economic
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 15 04/10/18 4:01 PM
16
REALWORLD APPLICATION
Economists and Market Solutions
Economic reasoning is playing an
increasing role in government policy.
Consider the regulation of pollution.
Pollution became a policy concern in the
1960s as books such as Rachel Carson’s
Silent Spring were published. In 1970, in
response to concerns about the environ-
ment, the Clean Air Act was passed. It
capped the amount of pollutants (such as
sulfur dioxide, carbon monoxide, nitrogen
dioxides, lead, and hydrocarbons) that firms could emit.
This was a “command-and-control” approach to regulation,
which brought about a reduction in pollution, but also
brought about lots of complaints by firms that either found
the limits costly to meet or couldn’t afford to meet them
and were forced to close.
Enter economists. They proposed an alternative ap-
proach, called cap-and-trade, that achieved the same
overall reduction in pollution but at a lower overall cost. In
the plan they proposed, government still set a pollution
cap that firms had to meet, but it gave individual firms
some flexibility. Firms that reduced emissions by less than
the required limit could buy pollution permits from other
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 16 04/10/18 4:01 PM
©Design Pics/Kelly Redinger
firms that reduced their emissions by
more than their limit. The price of the
permits would be determined in an
“emissions permit market.” Thus, firms
that had a low cost of reducing pollution
would have a strong incentive to reduce
pollution by more than their limit in order
to sell these permits, or rights to pollute,
to firms that had a high cost of reducing
pollution and therefore could reduce
their pollution by less than what was required. The net re-
duction was the same, but the reduction was achieved at a
lower cost.
In 1990 Congress adopted economists’ proposal and
the Clean Air Act was amended to include tradable emis-
sions permits. An active market in emissions permits de-
veloped, and it is estimated that the tradable permit
program has lowered the cost of reducing sulfur dioxide
emissions by
$1 billion a year while, at the same time, re-
ducing emissions by more than half, to levels significantly
below the cap. Other cap-and-trade programs have devel-
oped as well. You can read more about the current state of
tradable emissions at www.epa.gov/airmarkets.
theory says that supply and demand determine whos hired; experience suggests that
hiring is often done on the basis of whom you know, not by market forces.
These apparent contradictions have two complementary explanations. First, eco-
nomic the
ory abstracts from many issues. These issues may account for the differ-
ences. Second, there’s no contradiction; economic principles often affect decisions
from behind the scenes. For instance, supply and demand pressures determine what
the price markup over cost will be. In all cases, however, to apply economic theory to
reality—to gain the full value of economic insights—youve got to have a sense of
economic institutions.
Economic Policy Options
Economic policies are actions (or inaction) taken by government to influence eco-
nomic actions. The final goal of the course is to present the economic policy options
facing our society today. For example, should the government restrict mergers between
firms? Should it run a budget deficit? Should it do something about the international
trade deficit? Should it decrease taxes?
I saved this discussion for last because there’s no sense talking about policy options
unless you know some economic terminology, some economic theory, and some
thing
about economic institutions. Once you know something about them, youre in a posi-
tion to consider the policy options available for dealing with the economic problems
our society faces.
Chapter 1 Economics and Economic Reasoning 17
Policies operate within institutions, but policies also can influence the institutions
within which they operate. Lets consider an example: welfare policy and the institu-
tion of the two-parent family. In the 1960s, the United States developed a variety of
policy initiatives designed to eliminate poverty. These initiatives provided income to
single parents with children, and assumed that family structure would be unchanged by
these policies. But family structure changed substantially, and, very likely, these poli-
cies played a role in increasing the number of single-parent families. The result was
the programs failed to eliminate poverty. Now this is not to say that we should not have
programs to eliminate poverty, nor that two-parent families are always preferable to
one-parent families; it is only to say that we must build into our policies their effect on
institutions.
To carry out economic policy effectively,
one must understand how institutions
might change as a result of the
economic policy.
Q-8 True or false? Economists
should focus their policy analysis on
institutional changes because such
policies offer the largest gains.
Objective Policy Analysis
Good economic policy analysis is objective; that is, it keeps the analysts value
judgments separate from the analysis. Objective analysis does not say, “This is the
way things should be,” reflecting a goal established by the analyst. That would
besubjective analysis because it would reflect the analyst’s view of how things
should be. Instead, objective analysis says, “This is the way the economy works,
and if society (or the individual or firm for whom youre doing the analysis) wants
to achieve a particular goal, this is how it might go about doing so.” Objective
analysis keeps, or at least tries to keep, an individual’s subjective views—
valuejudgments—separate. That doesnt mean that policy analysis involves no
value judgments; policy analysis necessarily involves value judgments. But an
objective researcher attempts to make the value judgments being used both trans-
parent and not his own, but instead value judgments an “impartial spectator” (using
Adam Smiths terminology) would use.
To make clear the distinction between objective and subjective analysis, econ-
omists have divided economics into three categories: positive economics, norma-
tive economics, and the art of economics. Positive economics is the study of what
is, and how the economy works. It explores the pure theory of economics, and it
discovers agreed-upon empirical regularities, often called empirical facts. Eco-
nomic theorists then relate their theories to those facts. Positive economics asks
such questions as: How does the market for hog bellies work? How do price
restrictions affect market forces? These questions fall under the heading of eco-
nomic theory.
Positive economics is the study of what
is, and how the economy works.
As I stated above, economic theory does not provide definitive policy recommen-
dations. It is too abstract and makes too many assumptions that don’t match observed
behavior. In positive economic theory, one looks for empirical facts and develops
theorems—propositions that logically follow from the assumptions of one’s model.
Theorems and agreed-upon empirical facts are almost by definition beyond dispute
and serve as the foundation for economic science. But these theorems don’t tell us
what policies should be followed.
Q-9 John, your study partner, is a
free market advocate. He argues that
the invisible hand theorem tells us that
the government should not interfere
with the economy. Do you agree?
Whyor why not?
To decide on policy, economists integrate normative judgments with insights
from positive economics. Normative economics is the study of what the goals of the
economy should be. Normative economics asks such questions as: What should the
distribution of income be? What should tax policy be designed to achieve? In dis-
cussing such questions, economists must carefully delineate whose goals they are
discussing. One cannot simply assume that one’s own goals for society are society’s
goals. For example, lets consider an ongoing debate in economics. Some econo-
mists are worried about climate change; they believe that high consumption in rich
societies is causing climate change and that the high consumption is a result of
Normative economics is the study
ofwhat the goals of the economy
should be.
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 17 10/5/18 4:25 PM
18 Introduction Thinking Like an Economist
interdependent wants—people want something only because other people have it—
buthaving it isnt necessarily making people happier. These economists argue that
society’s normative goal should include a much greater focus on the implications
ofeconomic activities for climate change, and the distribution of income, than is
currently the case. Discussion of these goals falls under the category of normative
economics.
In debating normative issues, economists defer to philosophers for guidance on
what the goals of society should be. But that hasn’t always been the case. The founder
of economics, Adam Smith, was himself a moral philosopher, and economic policy
analysis developed within a utilitarian moral philosophy that saw the normative goal
of policy as being “the greatest good for the greatest number.” This goal required
economists to consider policy in terms of the consequences of that policy, not on the
basis of its inherent morality. It also required them to consider policy not from a per-
spective that was good for any particular group, but from the perspective of a fair
composite of society. When conducting policy analysis they had to bend over back-
wards to maintain impartiality.
Focus on such impartiality led early economists to argue against both slavery and
the oppression of women at a time when those positions were highly unpopular and
seen as radical. It also led them to argue in favor of the significant coordination of
society by the market, which they felt would bring about greater happiness for a greater
number than would the alternative of significant government coordination. Their sup-
port of markets was based on their moral philosophy, not just their science.
Adam Smith was part of this moral tradition, and before he wrote his economic
treatise, The Wealth of Nations, he wrote a philosophical treatise, The Theory of Moral
Sentiments, which provided a normative foundation for his economics. In it, Smith cre-
ated a tool that he argued was useful in shedding light on what was meant by the vague
and somewhat contradictory “greatest good for the greatest number.” That tool was the
impartial spectator tool in which each person places himself in the position of a
third-person examiner and judges a situation from everyone’s perspective, not just his
own. Then, having done that, he does his best to come to a policy that he could argue
would achieve the greatest good for the greatest number.
To use the impartial spectator tool, each
person places himself in the position of
a third-person examiner and judges a
situation from everyone’s perspective,
not just his own
Economists did not expect people to arrive at definitive policy conclusions based
on this tool. But they did see the tool as providing a framework within which people
could discuss policy in terms of what was best for society as a whole, not what was
best for themselves, or their friends. This tool would focus arguments about policy on
their impact on people in the community, rather than on abstract debates about the
morality of policy, which generally led nowhere. That approach to morality was an
important part of policy economics, and was how economists moved from the theo-
rems developed in science to policy precepts.
Some economists hoped that they would be able to determine the goals of policy
scientifically, but they quickly decided that that was impossible. They came to
believe that utility—a general measure of people’s welfare used in policy analysis—
is neither scientifically measurable nor comparable between individuals. It is for that
reason that economic science does not lead to any particular policy conclusions. To
move to policy conclusions, one must supplement science with moral philosophical
insights developed in self-reflective considerations and heartfelt discussions with
others about what is meant by the greatest good for the greatest number. Policy
economists have to picture themselves as walking in the shoes of every person ever-
where, not just their own.
The art of economics, also called political economy, is the application of the
knowledge learned in positive economics to achieve the goals one has determined in
normative economics. It looks at such questions as: To achieve the goals that society
The art of economics is the application
of the knowledge learned in positive
economics to achieve the goals
determined in normative economics.
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 18 10/5/18 4:25 PM
19
REALWORLD APPLICATION
Economics and Climate Change
A good example of the central role that
economics plays in policy debates is the
debate about climate change. Almost all
scientists are now convinced that cli-
mate change is occurring and that hu-
man activity such as the burning of fossil
fuel is one of the causes. The policy
question is what to do about it. To an-
swer that question, most governments
have turned to economists. The first part
of the question that economists have
considered is whether it is worth doing anything, and in a
well-publicized report commissioned by the British gov-
ernment, economist Nicholas Stern argued that, based
upon his cost/benefit analysis, yes it is worth doing some-
thing. The reason: Because the costs of not doing any-
thing would likely reduce output by 20 percent in the
future, and those costs (appropriately weighted for when
they occur) are less than the benefits of policies that can
be implemented.
The second part of the question is: What policies to im-
plement? The policies he recommended were policies that
changed incentives—specifically, policies that raised the
costs of emitting greenhouse gases and decreased the
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 19 04/10/18 4:01 PM
©AP Photo/Alden Pellett
costs of other forms of production. Those
recommended policies reflected the
economist’s opportunity cost framework
in action: If you want to change the re-
sult, change the incentives that individu-
als face.
There is considerable debate about
Stern’s analysis—both with the way he
conducted the cost/benefit analysis and
with his policy recommendations. Such
debates are inevitable when the data are
incomplete and numerous judgments need to be made. I
suspect that these debates will continue over the coming
years with economists on various sides of the debates.
Economists are generally not united in their views about
complicated policy issues since they differ in their norma-
tive views and in their assessment of the problem and of
what politically can be achieved; that’s because policy is
part of the art of economics, not part of positive econom-
ics. But the framework of the policy debate about climate
change is the economic framework. Thus, even though
political forces will ultimately choose what policy is fol-
lowed, you must understand the economic framework to
take part in the debate.
wants to achieve, how would you go about it, given the way the economy works?
4
Most policy discussions fall under the art of economics. The art of economics branch
is specifically about policy; it is designed to arrive at precepts, or guides for policy.
Precepts are based on theorems and empirical facts developed in positive economics
and goals developed in normative economics. The art of economics requires econo-
mists to assess the appropriateness of theorems to achieving the normative goals in the
real world. Whereas once the assumptions are agreed upon, theorems derived from
models are not debatable, precepts are debatable, and economists that use the same
theorems can hold different precepts. For example, a model may tell us that rent con-
trols (a legal maximum on rent) will cause a shortage of housing. That does not mean
that rent controls are necessarily bad policies, since rent controls may also have some
desirable effects. The precept that rent controls are bad policy is based upon a judg-
ment about the importance of those other effects, and one’s normative judgments
4
This three-part distinction was made back in 1891 by a famous economist, John Neville Keynes,
father of John Maynard Keynes, the economist who developed macroeconomics. This distinction
was instilled into modern economics by Milton Friedman and Richard Lipsey in the 1950s. They,
however, downplayed the art of economics, which J. N. Keynes had seen as central to understanding
the economists role in policy. In his discussion of the scope and method of economics, Lionel
Robbins used the term political economy rather than Keynes’ term the art of economics.
Web Note 1.5
The Art of Economics
Q-10 Tell whether the following
fivestatements belong in positive
economics, normative economics,
orthe art of economics.
1. We should support the market
because it is efficient.
2. Given certain conditions, the market
achieves efficient results.
3. Based on past experience and our
understanding of markets, if one
wants a reasonably efficient result,
markets should probably be
reliedon.
4. The distribution of income should
beleft to markets.
5. Markets allocate income according
to contributions of factors of
production.
20 Introduction Thinking Like an Economist
about the benefits and costs of the policy. In this book, when I say that economists tend
to favor a policy, I am talking about precepts, which means that alternative perspec-
tives are possible even among economists.
In each of these three branches of economics, economists separate their own
value judgments from their objective analysis as much as possible. The qualifier “as
much as possible” is important, since some value judgments inevitably sneak in. We
are products of our environment, and the questions we ask, the framework we use,
and the way we interpret the evidence all involve value judgments and reflect our
backgrounds.
Maintaining objectivity is easiest in positive economics, where you are working
with abstract models to understand how the economy works. Maintaining objectivity
is harder in normative economics. You must always be objective about whose norma-
tive values you are using. It’s easy to assume that all of society shares your values, but
that assumption is often wrong.
Maintaining objectivity is hardest in the art of economics because it can suffer
from the problems of both positive and normative economics. Because noneconomic
forces affect policy, to practice the art of economics we must make judgments about
how these noneconomic forces work. These judgments are likely to reflect our own
value judgments. So we must be exceedingly careful to be as objective as possible in
practicing the art of economics.
Policy and Social and Political Forces
When you think about the policy options facing society, you’ll quickly discover that
the choice of policy options depends on much more than economic theory. Politicians,
not economists, determine economic policy. To understand what policies are chosen,
you must take into account historical precedent plus social, cultural, and political
forces. In an economics course, I don’t have time to analyze these forces in as much
depth as I’d like. Thats one reason there are separate history, political science, sociology,
and anthropology courses.
While it is true that these other forces play significant roles in policy decisions,
specialization is necessary. In economics, we focus the analysis on the invisible
hand, and much of economic theory is devoted to considering how the economy
would operate if the invisible hand were the only force operating. But as soon as we
apply theory to reality and policy, we must take into account political and social
forces as well.
An example will make my point more concrete. Most economists agree that hold-
ing down or eliminating tariffs (taxes on imports) and quotas (numerical limitations on
imports) makes good economic sense. They strongly advise governments to follow a
policy of free trade. Do governments follow free trade policies? Almost invariably
they do not. Politics leads society in a different direction. If you’re advising a policy
maker, you need to point out that these other forces must be taken into account, and
how other forces should (if they should) and can (if they can) be integrated with your
recommendations.
Conclusion
Tons more could be said to introduce you to economics, but an introduction must
remain an introduction. As it is, this chapter should have:
1.
Introduced you to economic reasoning.
2. Surveyed what we’re going to cover in this book.
3. Given you an idea of my writing style and approach.
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 20 04/10/18 4:01 PM
Chapter 1 Economics and Economic Reasoning 21
We’ll be spending long hours together over the coming term, and before entering
into such a commitment its best to know your partner. While I wont know you, by the
end of this book you’ll know me. Maybe you wont love me as my mother does, but
you’ll know me.
This introduction was my opening line. I hope it also conveyed the importance and
relevance of economics. If it did, it has served its intended purpose. Economics is
tough, but tough can be fun.
Summary
The three coordination problems any economy must
solve are what to produce, how to produce it, and
forwhom to produce it. In solving these problems,
societies have found that there is a problem of
scarcity. (LO1-1)
Economics can be divided into microeconomics and
macroeconomics. Microeconomics is the study of
individual choice and how that choice is influenced
by economic forces. Macroeconomics is the study
ofthe economy as a whole. It considers problems
such as inflation, unemployment, business cycles,
andgrowth. (LO1-1)
Economic reasoning structures all questions in a
cost/benefit framework: If the marginal benefits of
doing something exceed the marginal costs, do it.
Ifthe marginal costs exceed the marginal benefits,
dont doit. (LO1-2)
Sunk costs are not relevant in the economic decision
rule. (LO1-2)
The opportunity cost of undertaking an activity is the
benefit you might have gained from choosing the
next-best alternative. (LO1-2)
There ain’t no such thing as a free lunch”
(TANSTAAFL) embodies the opportunity cost
concept. (LO1-2)
Economic forces, the forces of scarcity, are always
working. Market forces, which ration by changing
prices, are not always allowed to work. (LO1-3)
Economic reality is controlled and directed by three
types of forces: economic forces, political forces,
andsocial forces. (LO1-3)
Under certain conditions, the market, through its
pricemechanism, will allocate scarce resources
efficiently. (LO1-4)
Theorems are propositions that follow from the
assumptions of a model; precepts are the guides for
policies based on theorems, normative judgments,
andempirical observations about how the real world
differs from the model. (LO1-4)
Economics can be subdivided into positive economics,
normative economics, and the art of economics. Positive
economics is the study of what is, normative economics
is the study of what should be, and the art of economics
relates positive to normative economics. (LO1-5)
Key Terms
art of economics
economic decision rule
economic force
economic model
economic policy
economic principle
economics
efficiency
experimental economics
impartial spectator tool
implicit costs
invisible hand
invisible hand theorem
macroeconomics
marginal benefit
marginal cost
market force
microeconomics
normative economics
opportunity cost
political forces
positive economics
precepts
scarcity
social forces
sunk cost
theorems
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 21 04/10/18 4:01 PM
22 Introduction Thinking Like an Economist
Questions and Exercises
1. Why does the textbook author focus on coordination
rather than on scarcity when defining economics?
(LO1-1)
2. State whether the following are primarily microeconomic
or macroeconomic policy issues: (LO1-1)
a. Should U.S. interest rates be lowered to decrease the
amount of unemployment?
b. Will the fact that more and more doctors are selling
their practices to managed care networks increase the
efficiency of medical providers?
c. Should the current federal income tax be lowered to
reduce unemployment?
d. Should the federal minimum wage be raised?
e. Should Sprint and Verizon both be allowed to build
local phone networks?
f. Should commercial banks be required to provide loans
in all areas of the territory from which they accept
deposits?
3. List two microeconomic and two macroeconomic
problems. (LO1-1)
4. Calculate, using the best estimates you can: (LO1-2)
a. Your opportunity cost of attending college.
b. Your opportunity cost of taking this course.
c. Your opportunity cost of attending yesterday’s lecture
in this course.
5. List one recent choice you made and explain why you
made the choice in terms of marginal benefits and
marginal costs. (LO1-2)
6. You rent a car for $29.95. The first 100 miles are free,
buteach mile thereafter costs 10 cents. You plan to
driveit 200 miles. What is the marginal cost of driving
the car? (LO1-2)
7. Economists Henry Saffer of Kean University, Frank J.
Chaloupka of the University of Illinois at Chicago, and
Dhaval Dave of Bentley College estimated that the gov-
ernment must spend $4,170 on drug control to deter one
person from using drugs and that the cost one drug user
imposes on society is $897. Based on this information
alone, should the government spend the money on drug
control? (LO1-2)
8. What is the opportunity cost of buying a $20,000
car? (LO1-2)
9. Suppose you currently earn $60,000 a year. You are con-
sidering a job that will increase your lifetime earnings by
$600,000 but that requires an MBA. The job will mean
also attending business school for two years at an annual
cost of $50,000. You already have a bachelor’s degree, for
which you spent $160,000 in tuition and books. Which of
the above information is relevant to your decision on
whether to take the job? (LO1-2)
10. Suppose your college has been given $5 million. You
havebeen asked to decide how to spend it to improve
yourcollege. Explain how you would use the economic
decision rule and the concept of opportunity costs to
decide how to spend it. (LO1-2)
11. Give two examples of social forces and explain how
theykeep economic forces from becoming market
forces. (LO1-3)
12. Give two examples of political or legal forces and
explain how they might interact with economic
forces. (LO1-3)
13. Individuals have two kidneys, but most of us need
onlyone. People who have lost both kidneys through
accident or disease must be hooked up to a dialysis
machine, which cleanses waste from their bodies. Say a
person who has two good kidneys offers to sell one of
them tosomeone whose kidney function has been totally
destroyed. The seller asks $30,000 for the kidney,
andthe person who haslost both kidneys accepts the
offer. (LO1-3)
a. Who benefits from the deal?
b. Who is hurt?
c. Should a society allow such market transactions?
Why?
14. What is an economic model? What besides a
modeldoeconomists need to make policy
recommendations? (LO1-4)
15. Does economic theory prove that the free market system
is best? Why? (Difficult) (LO1-4)
16. Distinguish between theorems and precepts.
Isit possible for two economists to agree about
theorems butdisagree about precepts? Why or why
not? (LO1-4)
17. What is the difference between normative and positive
statements? (LO1-5)
18. State whether the following statements belong in
positive economics, normative economics, or the art
ofeconomics. (LO1-5)
a. In a market, when quantity supplied exceeds quantity
demanded, price tends to fall.
b. When determining tax rates, the government
shouldtake into account the income needs of
individuals.
c. Given society’s options and goals, a broad-based tax
isgenerally preferred to a narrowly based tax.
d. California currently rations water to farmers at subsi-
dized prices. Once California allows the trading of
water rights, it will allow economic forces to be a
market force.
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 22 21/11/18 11:09 AM
Chapter 1 Economics and Economic Reasoning 23
Questions from Alternative Perspectives
1. Is it possible to use objective economic analysis as a basis
for government planning? (Austrian)
2. In “Rational Choice with Passion: Virtue in a Model of
Rational Addiction,” Andrew M. Yuengert of Pepperdine
University argues that there is a conflict between reason
and passion.
a. What might that conflict be?
b. What implications does it have for applying the
economic model? (Religious)
3. Economic institutions are “habits of thought” that
organize society.
a. In what way might patriarchy be an institution and
how might it influence the labor market?
b. Does the free market or patriarchy better explain why
98 percent of secretaries are women and 98 percent of
automobile mechanics are men? (Feminist)
4. In October of 2004, the supply of flu vaccine fell by over
50percent when a major producer of the vaccine was shut
down. The result was that the vaccine had to be rationed,
with a priority schedule established: young children, people
with weakened immunity, those over 65, etc. taking priority.
a. Compare and contrast this allocation outcome with a
free market outcome.
b. Which alternative is more just? (Institutionalist)
5. The textbook model assumes that individuals have enough
knowledge to follow the economic decision rule.
a. How did you decide which college you would attend?
b. Did you have enough knowledge to follow the
economic decision rule?
c. For what type of decisions do you not use the
economic decision rule?
d. What are the implications for economic analysis if
most people dont follow the economic decision rule
inmany aspects of their decisions? (Post-Keynesian)
6. Radical economists believe that all of economics, like all
theorizing or storytelling, is value-laden. Theories and
stories reflect the values of those who compose them
and tell them. For instance, radicals offer a different
analysis than most economists of how capitalism works
and what ought to be done about its most plaguing prob-
lems: inequality, periodic economic crises with large-
scale unemployment, and the alienation of the workers.
a. What does the radical position imply about the
distinction between positive economics and normative
economics that the text makes?
b. Is economics value-laden or objective and is the dis-
tinction between positive and normative economics
tenable or untenable? (Radical)
Issues to Ponder
1. At times we all regret decisions. Does this necessarily
mean we did not use the economic decision rule when
making the decision?
2. Economist Steven Landsburg argues that if one believes in
the death penalty for murderers because of its deterrent ef-
fect, using cost/benefit analysis we should execute computer
hackers—the creators of worms and viruses—because the
deterrent effect in cost saving would be greater than the de-
terrent effect in saving lives. Estimates are that each execu-
tion deters eight murders, which, if one valued each life at
about $7 million, saves about $56 million; he estimates that
executing hackers would save more than that per execution,
and thus would be the economic thing to do.
a. Do you agree or disagree with Landsburg’s argument?
Why?
b. Can you extend cost/benefit analysis to other areas?
3. Adam Smith, who wrote The Wealth of Nations, and who
isseen as the father of modern economics, also wrote The
Theory of Moral Sentiments. In it he argued that society
would be better off if people werent so selfish and were
more considerate of others. How does this view fit with the
discussion of economic reasoning presented in the chapter?
4. A Wall Street Journal article asked readers the following
questions. Whats your answer?
a. An accident has caused deadly fumes to enter the school
ventilation system where it will kill five children. You
can stop it by throwing a switch, but doing so will kill
one child in another room. Do you throw the switch?
b. Say that a doctor can save five patients with an organ
transplant that would end the life of a patient who is
sick, but not yet dead. Does she do it?
c. What is the difference between the two situations
described in a and b?
d. How important are opportunity costs in your decisions?
5. Economics is about strategic thinking, and the strategies
can get very complicated. Suppose Marge kisses Mike
and asks whether he liked it. Shed like Mike to answer
“yes” and shed like that answer to be truthful. But Mike
knows that, and if he likes Marge, he may well say that he
liked the kiss even if he didnt. But Marge knows that, and
thus might not really believe that Mike liked the kiss—
he’s just saying “yes” because that’s what Marge wants to
hear. But Mike knows that Marge knows that, so some-
times he has to convey a sense that he didnt like it, so that
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 23 04/10/18 4:01 PM
24 Introduction Thinking Like an Economist
Marge will believe him when he says that he did like it.
But Marge knows that . . . You get the picture.
a.
Should you always be honest, even when it hurts
someone?
b. What strategies can you figure out to avoid the
problem of not believing the other person?
6. Go to two stores: a supermarket and a convenience store.
a.
Write down the cost of a gallon of milk in each.
b. The prices are most likely different. Using the termi-
nology used in this chapter, explain why that is the
case and why anyone would buy milk in the store with
the higher price.
c. Do the same exercise with shirts or dresses in Walmart
(or its equivalent) and Saks (or its equivalent).
7.
About 100,000 individuals in the United States are waiting
for organ transplants, and at an appropriate price many indi-
viduals would be willing to supply organs. Given those facts,
should human organs be allowed to be bought and sold?
8. Name an economic institution and explain how it affects
economic decision making or how its actions reflect
economic principles.
9. Tyler Cowen, an economist at George Mason University,
presents an interesting case that pits the market against legal
and social forces. The case involves payola—the payment of
money to disc jockeys for playing a songwriter’s songs. He
reports that Chuck Berry was having a hardtime getting his
music played because of racism. To counter this, he offered a
well-known disc jockey, Alan Freed, partial songwriting
credits, along with partial royalties, on any Chuck Berry
song of his choice. Freed chose Maybellene, which he played
and promoted. It went on to be a hit, Chuck Berry went on to
be a star, and Freed’s estate continues to receive royalties.
a.
Should such payments be allowed? Why?
b. How did Freed’s incentives from the royalty payment
differ from Freed’s incentives if Chuck Berry had just
offered him a flat payment?
c. Name two other examples of similar activities—one
that is legal and one that is not.
10.
Name three ways a limited number of dormitory rooms
could be rationed. How would economic forces determine
individual behavior in each? How would social or legal
forces determine whether those economic forces become
market forces?
11. Prospect theory suggests that people are hurt more by
losses than they are uplifted by gains of a corresponding
size. If that is true, what implications would it have for
economic policy?
12.
Is a good economist always objective? Explain your answer.
13. Why are modern economists more likely to “let the data
speak” than are earlier economists?
Answers to Margin Questions
1.
(1) Macroeconomics; (2) Microeconomics; (3) Microeco-
nomics; (4) Macroeconomics. (LO1-1)
2. Since the price of both stocks is now $15, it doesnt mat-
ter which one you sell (assuming no differential capital
gains taxation). The price you bought them for doesnt
matter; it’s a sunk cost. Marginal analysis refers to the
future gain, so what you expect to happen to future prices
of the stocks—not past prices—should determine which
stock you decide to sell. (LO1-2)
3. A cost/benefit analysis requires that you put a value on a
good, and placing a value on a good can be seen as de-
meaning it. Consider love. Try telling an acquaintance
that youd like to buy his or her spiritual love, and see
what response you get. (LO1-2)
4. John is wrong. The opportunity cost of reading the chap-
ter is primarily the time you spend reading it. Reading the
book prevents you from doing other things. Assuming that
you already paid for the book, the original price is no
longer part of the opportunity cost; it is a sunk cost.
Bygones are bygones. (LO1-2)
5. Whenever there is scarcity, the scarce good must be
rationed by some means. Free health care has an
opportunity cost in other resources. So if health care is not
rationed, to get the resources to supply that care, other
goods would have to be more tightly rationed than they
currently are. It is likely that the opportunity cost of
supplying free health care would be larger than most
societies would be willing to pay. (LO1-3)
6.
Joan is wrong. Economic forces are always operative;
market forces are not. (LO1-3)
7. According to the invisible hand theorem, the price of
tomatoes will likely fall. (LO1-4)
8. False. While such changes have the largest gain, they also
may have the largest cost. The policies economists should
focus on are those that offer the largest net gain—benefits
minus costs—to society. (LO1-5)
9. He is wrong. The invisible hand theorem is a positive theo-
rem and does not tell us anything about what policy to adopt.
To do so would be to violate Hume’s dictum that a “should”
cannot be derived from an “is.” This is not to say that gov-
ernment should or should not interfere; whether government
should interfere is a very difficult question. (LO1-5)
10. (1) Normative; (2) Positive; (3) Art; (4) Normative;
(5)Positive. (LO1-5)
Design elements: Web Note icon: ©McGraw-Hill Education; Real-World Application icon: ©McGraw-Hill Education; A Reminder icon: ©McGraw-Hill Education;
Added Dimension icon: ©McGraw-Hill Education; Thinking Like a Modern Economist icon: ©NeydtStock/Shutterstock
coL25585_ch01_002-024.indd 24 21/11/18 11:10 AM
CHAPTER
30
Financial Crises, Panics,
and Unconventional
Monetary Policy
It is well enough that people of the nation do not
understand our banking and monetary system, for if
they did, I believe there would be a revolution before
tomorrow morning.
—Henry Ford
After reading this chapter,
you should be able to:
LO30-1 Explain why financial crises
are dangerous and why
most economists see a
role for the central bank as
a lender of last resort.
LO30-2 Explain the role of leverage
and herding in financial
bubbles and how central
bank policy can contribute
to a financial bubble.
LO30-3 Explain why regulating
the financial sector and
preventing financial crises
is so difficult.
LO30-4 Discuss monetary policy in
the post–financial crisis
period.
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 681 04/12/18 10:47 AM
©Chris Hondros/Getty Images
In 2008, the world financial system nearly stopped working. Banks were on the
verge of collapse, the stock market dropped precipitously, and the U.S. econ-
omy fell into a serious recession and possible structural stagnation. In response,
central banks and governments across the world took extraordinary steps—
buying banks, buying financial assets, guaranteeing deposits, and guaranteeing
loans to try to calm the crisis. Initially central banks thought that the problems
would be temporary, but after the initial short-term problems were handled,
longer-term problems emerged; economies throughout the world were faced
with sluggish growth and higher unemployment than they found acceptable,
and central banks feared that if they returned to conventional monetary policy,
the economies would crash. In response, what started as a highly unconven-
tional monetary policy became the new normal, with very low and even negative
interest rates, quantitative easing, and worry about inflation being too low, the
682 Macroeconomics Finance, Money, and the Economy
new standard features of monetary policy. Only a decade later are central banks around
the world moving back to a more traditional monetary policy. In this chapter, we con-
sider unconventional monetary policy and the problems involved with unwinding it,
and moving back to a more conventional monetary policy. Specifically, we consider:
(1) financial panics and the Fed’s role as a lender of last resort, (2) the difficulty of
preventing financial crises and the structural problems they create, (3) the problems of
regulating the financial sector, and (4) the debate about unconventional monetary pol-
icies and how best to unwind them.
The Central Bank’s Role in a Crisis
Why is there so much concern about the financial sector and fear about a credit crisis?
Firms in the financial sector got themselves into this mess; they should get out of it on
their own. After all, the financial sector is only a small part of the entire economy. The
answer why is simple: We worry about the financial sector not because it is big or
small, but because all the other sectors need the financial sector to do business. While
oil is a relatively minor part of a working engine, it is absolutely essential. While the
failure of other big sectors such as the auto industry would be painful, it would not
bring all other sectors crashing down as a financial-sector collapse would. Thats why
one of the roles of a central bank is to be a lender of last resortlending to banks and
other financial institutions when no one else will.
Q-1 Why do we worry about the
financial sector more than the
automobile sector?
When credit is not available, the real economy can quickly come to a halt. It’s not
like the slow effect of a contractionary demand shock. It is fast, like a heart attack. The
fear in October 2008 was that the financial crisis on Wall Street could cause the entire
economy to seize, spreading the problem from Wall Street (the financial sector) to
Main Street (the real sector), creating not a recession but a depression like the Great
Depression of the 1930s.
Think about what would happen if your credit dried up. Say that even though
youre every bit as trustworthy as before, you suddenly find you can no longer borrow
money. No more spending with a credit card. Paying for some of your expenses might
still work just fine—you could buy groceries with cash at the local grocery store. Oth-
ers would be more difficult. Without credit, youd have to pay all your bills before you
get the product. No more loans to buy a car; you’ll have to save $20,000 first. No more
checks since businesses couldn’t be assured the check would clear. Some things would
be downright impossible; forget about buying anything on the Internet. Paying for col-
lege? No problem . . . if youve already saved up enough to pay up front and in full.
Credit is a necessary part of the U.S.
economy.
The situation is even worse for companies. While they might not use credit cards,
just like you, they borrow for their short-term needs, such as buying the raw materials
for production and paying their workers. If their credit line disappears, companies
would essentially be forced to close because they couldnt pay their workers. When
workers lose their jobs, they will cut their spending, causing other workers to lose their
jobs as well. A downward spiral of output will result. That’s why a severe financial
crisis can bring the entire real economy to a halt.
Luckily that didnt happen. As soon as the crisis hit, the Fed put aside its standard
cautious approach to monetary policy and undertook a wide variety of unprecedented
actions. It acted as the lender of last resort—providing loans to financial institutions
that it determined were solventhaving sufficient assets to cover their long-run
liabilities—but were not sufficiently liquidhaving assets that could readily be
converted into cash and money at non-fire-sale prices. Without liquid assets banks
couldnt pay their short-run liabilities, such as interest on money they had borrowed.
In the financial crisis, the Fed acted as a
lender of last resort loaning to solvent,
but illiquid banks.
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 682 11/10/18 11:35 AM
Chapter 30 Financial Crises, Panics, and Unconventional Monetary Policy 683
To prevent a financial collapse, the Fed took the banks’ long-run illiquid assets such
as mortgages, business loans, and Treasury bonds as collateral, and loaned the banks
money to pay their short-run liabilities. By doing so the Fed provided liquidity to the
financial market.
Similarly, the Treasury dropped all its standard practices and bailed out financial
firms, and Congress instituted strong expansionary fiscal policy. The hope was that
such actions would be enough to prevent the financial meltdown that would turn a seri-
ous recession into a second Great Depression. The policy succeeded; the United States
and world economies avoided a financial meltdown.
Anatomy of a Financial Crisis
Even though every financial crisis is different, all generally have similar elements and
2008 was no exception. A financial crisis begins with the creation of an asset price
bubbleunsustainable rapidly rising prices of some type of asset (such as stocks or
houses). Price increases in a bubble are unsustainable because they do not reflect an
increase in the real productive value of the asset. In the early 2000s, the bubble was in
the housing market.
A bubble is an unsustainable rapidly
rising price of some type of asset.
The key to a bubble is extrapolative expectationsexpectations that a trend
will accelerate. It works like this: Initially, the market experiences a shock, which
causes prices to rise. In a standard aggregate supply/aggregate demand model, the
initial rise in price is the end of the story. The rise in prices brings the market back
into equilibrium. But in a financial bubble, the initial rise in price leads people to
expect further price increases. In anticipation of these price increases, people buy
goods and assets, causing aggregate demand to shift out to the right, which leads
prices to rise further, fulfilling expectations, and people to expect even more price
increases. In a bubble, expectations feed back on themselves, and prices rapidly
spiral upward. This is how it works:
Web Note 30.1
Bubble Analysis
In a bubble, expectations feed back on
themselves, and prices rapidly spiral
upward.
Rise in price → Expectations of a further rise in price → Rise in demand at the
current price → Rise in price → Expectations of a further rise in price . . . and so on
The Financial Crisis: The Bubble Bursts
In 2005, after rising precipitously for a number of years, housing
prices started to level off. Most standard economists talked about
prices settling into a permanently high plateau. But by 2006 hous-
ing prices began to fall precipitously—and it became clear that the
boom in housing prices in the early 2000s had been a financial bub-
ble. As soon as that was recognized, the bubble burst and everyone
wanted to get out of housing and housing-related assets before the
price of their houses fell further.
The bursting of the bubble involves the same process that
leads to the bubble—extrapolative expectations; it just works in
reverse. The price stops rising, which reverses the expectations
of rising prices into falling prices. People begin selling their
assets, which leads prices to fall even more. People expect prices
to fall even further, which leads more people to sell . . . and so
on. Those whose loans exceeded the value of their assets (commonly called being
underwater) are forced to sell or to default on their loans. Those defaults lead to
expectations of further price declines, which bring about further defaults.
The bursting of a bubble involves the
same process that leads to the bubble—
extrapolative expectations; it just works
in reverse.
Foreclosures rose considerably after the housing
bubble burst in 2006.
©Andy Dean Photography/Alamy
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 683 11/10/18 11:35 AM
684 Macroeconomics Finance, Money, and the Economy
Thinking Like a Modern Economist
Tulipmania, the South Sea Bubble, and Behavioral Economics
Financial bubbles have been a fixture in economies
for centuries. Two of the most famous financial bub-
bles are Tulipmania and the South Sea bubble.
The height of Tulipmania occurred in Holland
between November 1636 and February 1637. It cen-
tered on, you guessed it, tulips—a relatively newly
introduced popular flower. Over three months, tulip
bulb prices are estimated to have risen by several
thousand percent, all without any
tulips actually changing hands—tulips
don’t even grow between November
and February. Instead, speculators
tried to make money by buying and
reselling promises to deliver tulip
bulbs the following May, after they
had flowered. Contracts for some
particularly rare bulbs were report-
edly trading for prices equivalent to
20 years of a typical workman’s
wages, and for a full 12 acres of land.
Trading was purely speculative; peo-
ple bought tulip contracts with the full
intention of “flipping” them for a profit
well before May. The bubble burst in
February when people realized that
at the current prices, no one would
be willing to pay the outrageous
prices for an actual tulip.
Another financial bubble was the
South Sea bubble of the early 1700s.
The South Sea bubble started when
rumors spread that the South Sea
Company—a company granted a monopoly on trade
with South American colonies by the British govern-
ment—would be enormously profitable. When the
stock price of the South Sea Company doubled, oth-
ers noticed and wanted to get in on the profit, push-
ing the price up further. The price of its stock rose
almost tenfold between January and August of 1720.
(The rise was helped along by various shady dealings
between the company and members of the British
Parliament.)
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 684 11/10/18 11:35 AM
Source: Reprint of 1841/1852 editions of
Extraordinary Popular Delusions and the
Madness of Crowds by Charles Mackay,
LL.D.
How could people afford to buy this stock at such
high prices? They borrowed and were allowed to
leverage their purchases. (Pay me 10 percent now
and the remaining 90 percent next week.) As long as
the stock price was rising, that wasn’t a problem.
When it was time to pay the remaining 90 percent,
the stockholder could sell the stock at a higher price,
repay the loan, and pocket the difference.
But then, suddenly, the rumors
reversed. The stock prices started
falling and everyone called in their
loans. To pay their loans, people tried
to sell stock that no one wanted to
buy; stock prices plummeted and the
bubble burst even more quickly than
it had formed.
Behavioral economics and standard
economics explain these bubbles dif-
ferently. Standard economics works
hard to provide a rational explanation
for financial bubbles. It has a theory of
what might be called rational bubbles.
For example, some economists have
argued that the high prices of tulips
and of South Sea Company stock were
plausible in light of the scarcity and
novelty of certain bulbs and imperfect
information about the profitability of
trade with the Americas. If bubbles are
rational, they should be considered an
unavoidable aspect of modern society.
Modern behavioral economists
disagree. They argue that bubbles form precisely
because people aren’t fully rational in the way that
economists define rationality—they are subject to
herd mentality. That is, they are predictably irrational.
Moreover, economists argue that in an unpredictable
world, there is no one rational course of action, and
the future is always in some sense unknown. This
difference is important because if behavioral econo-
mists are right, then there is a potential role for policy
to reduce the severity and occurrence of bubbles.
Chapter 30 Financial Crises, Panics, and Unconventional Monetary Policy 685
Compared with the stock market crash of 1929, in 2007 housing prices declined
slowly. While financial assets can be sold quickly—at the click of a mouse—houses
cannot. Houses generally are listed with a real estate agent; buyers look at a number of
houses before deciding; then the price is negotiated. Even when people are not paying
their mortgage, banks cant just kick people out of their houses; they must foreclose,
and that process can take years.
Despite all the difficulties with the housing market, the financial crisis was not
directly precipitated by the housing market crisis. It was a crisis in the market for
mortgage-backed securities. Mortgage-backed securities are securities that are
derivatives of mortgages in which thousands of mortgages are packaged with other
mortgages into a bundle of mortgages and sold on the securities market. These securi-
ties are related to housing because their value depends on the value of mortgages,
which in turn depends on the ability of homeowners to pay their mortgages, which in
turn depends on housing prices.
When the housing market crashed and people stopped paying their mortgages,
these mortgage-backed securities lost much of their value. Panic ensued because, like
homeowners who had borrowed significant sums to buy their houses, many financial
institutions had purchased these securities with mostly borrowed money. Some used
leverage—the practice of buying an asset with borrowed money—to buy those securi-
ties and were leveraged at a 30-to-1 ratio, which meant that for every dollar they
invested, they had borrowed $30. As the market for mortgage-backed securities dried
up, the banks found themselves in a pickle. Those financial institutions that had loaned
money to banks wanted their cash, and the banks didnt have it. They had assets to pay
their lenders; they just werent liquid. They didnt have sufficient time to sell those
assets and didnt want to have to sell them at fire-sale prices. In economic jargon, the
banks were illiquid, not insolvent. That means that at non-fire-sale prices the banks
had sufficient assets to meet their long-term obligations but they didnt have funds to
meet their short-term obligations. Without some source of liquidity, they would all go
bankrupt. Without liquidity banks stopped lending, and the economy started falling
into a recession. To prevent that recession from turning into a depression, the Fed
stepped in as lender of last resort.
Leverage is the practice of buying an
asset with borrowed money.
The Fed as the Lender of Last Resort
The Fed engaged in a type of financial triage—taking care of the most damaged
banks with emergency measures, doing whatever it could to keep people and firms
buying and selling securities. The Fed and the U.S. government took unprece-
dented actions to try to prevent a modern version of the “bank run” that had thrown
the U.S. economy into the Great Depression of the 1930s. Ben Bernanke, the chair
of the Fed, knew what could happen—hed studied the 1930s and saw the paral-
lels. Fearing the worst, he put aside all conventional monetary theory and policy,
and started financial triage to prevent a complete meltdown of the U.S. financial
system.
The specifics were hotly debated; some economists and policy makers felt it was
too much, others felt it was too little, but just about all agreed that a policy in which the
Fed acts as the lender of last resort is good in principle. The important point is that all
these policies were emergency policies and have to be seen as such. Their goal was
clear—to prevent a financial meltdown. The political consensus was based on general
agreement that a financial meltdown would throw the economy into a depression. (We
will discuss problems with these emergency policies below.)
Just about all economists agreed that a
policy in which the Fed acts as the
lender of last resort is good in principle.
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 685 11/10/18 11:35 AM
686 Macroeconomics Finance, Money, and the Economy
The Role of Leverage and Herding in a Crisis
Financial bubbles are important in a discussion of Fed policy because bubbles are
most likely to occur when credit—financial instruments for borrowing—is easily
available. With easily available credit people can borrow to invest, increasing leverage.
The larger the percentage bought with borrowed funds, the larger the leverage. The
reason Fed policy is important to bubbles is that the Fed significantly influences credit
availability in an economy. So while the Fed’s quick action in dealing with the finan-
cial crisis is laudable, it may very well have played a significant part in creating the
bubble in the first place.
While the Fed’s quick action in dealing
with the financial crisis is laudable, it
may very well have played a significant
part in creating the bubble in the first
place.
Leverage
To understand the power of leverage, consider the decision of a person buying a stock.
Say you can buy a share of stock at $2 and you believe that its price will rise to $3
within a year. If you sell the stock after its price rises, you will earn a 50 percent
return. While a 50 percent return is pretty good, if you use leverage, you can do even
better. What if instead of buying a single $2 stock, you borrow $198 at 10 percent
interest and buy 100 shares for $200? When the stock price goes up to $3, you could
sell your stock for $300, pay back the $198 you borrowed plus $19.80 in interest, leav-
ing you with a profit of $80.20—about a 4,000 percent return! That’s the power of
leverage. When you can expect returns like that, why hold back? You’d want to get as
much money into the stock market as possible. With everyone buying more stocks,
their prices rise, and rise, and rise, very quickly.
Leverage works with all assets and is a central part of any bubble. Bubbles can
happen in houses, mortgages, bonds, paintings, baseball cards, antiques—you name it.
As long as the price is rising more than the rate of interest at which you can borrow,
leverage is a way to get rich quickly. Because expansionary monetary policy increases
the degree of leverage in the economy both by lowering interest rates and by making
credit more easily available, monetary policy can encourage the development of a
financial bubble.
Leverage works with all assets and is a
central part of any bubble.
Leverage contributes to a bubble by increasing the ability of people to finance the
purchase of goods, services, and financial instruments, despite what might otherwise
seem like high prices. It is here where the debate about potential output described in a
previous chapter comes in. In the standard macro model, which uses goods price rises
as a signal to estimate potential output, until an economy experiences rising inflation,
the economy is seen as not exceeding potential output. Because inflation remained low
throughout the early 2000s, the Fed increased the money supply substantially—far
more than suggested by the standard Taylor rule, as described in the previous chapter,
and far far more than would be needed if the economy were in a structural stagnation.
Both the Taylor rule and economists who believed the economy was experiencing
structural stagnation suggested that much tighter monetary policy in the early 2000s
was needed. What led the Fed to increase the money supply was the fact that increases
in the money supply did not push up goods prices, since they were held down by world
prices. Instead it made the U.S. economy awash in credit, which allowed enormous
increases in leverage in financial markets.
Leverage contributes to a bubble by
increasing the ability of people to
finance the purchase of goods, services,
and financial instruments, despite what
might otherwise seem like high prices.
Herding
The other part of the formation of a financial bubble involves what psychologists and
behavioral economists call herding. Herding is the human tendency to follow the
crowd. When people around you see how much others are profiting by buying and sell-
ing assets, they want to profit too. They become convinced that the price of the asset is
Q-2 What are two central
ingredients to the development of
a financial bubble?
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 686 11/10/18 11:35 AM
Chapter 30 Financial Crises, Panics, and Unconventional Monetary Policy 687
going to rise. When that happens, everyone buys more of the asset on credit, which
increases economywide risk enormously. That’s what happened in the housing market
in the 2000s.
Through the middle of the first decade of the 2000s, times were good in the housing
and construction markets, with housing prices rising nationally at historically high
rates. Flip That House and similar TV programs showcased people making tens of
thousands of dollars by buying a house with very little or no down payment, and
selling that house with enormous profit just months later. It seemed as if you could get
rich quick just by owning a house. Low interest rates and innovative mortgages
(mortgages with zero down payment and no proof of income or creditworthiness)
meant people who previously couldnt qualify for a mortgage could buy houses. Some
people bought five or six houses, which they couldnt afford, but which they planned
to sell before they had to repay the mortgage.
Web Note 30.2
Herding Tendencies
Homeownership rates rose to historic highs of nearly 70 percent. The feeling was
that you simply couldn’t lose on buying a house as an investment. As long as house
prices kept rising, flipping houses and stretching into a mortgage made sense. With
rising housing prices, people felt more wealthy—spending more and saving less
because their “houses were their savings.” When the value of your house is rising by
$30,000 a year, you can take out a home equity loan. Whether you save an extra $1,000
or not doesnt seem all that important. All these actions increased the risk of signifi-
cant problems occurring in the economy if housing prices didnt continue to rise, and
left the economy vulnerable to the housing bubble bursting.
But thats not all. Leverage by homeowners was nothing compared with the
leverage in the financial sector built on top of the housing market. As mentioned
previously, investment banks and hedge funds had figured out how to create securities
whose values were linked to the performance of these mortgages. These securities
were leveraging the already highly leveraged mortgages, creating a financial asset built
on double—and in many cases even triple or quadruple—leverage.
Excess leverage played a major role in
the financial crisis.
When the financial bubble burst, the U.S. economy was on the verge of a financial
meltdown. Luckily, that didn’t happen. By 2009 and 2010, it was clear that the U.S.
economy had avoided a financial meltdown, but the economy wasnt in good shape.
While it wasnt in a depression, it was stagnating. Unemployment was about 10 percent
and growth was anemic.
With the threat of a financial meltdown out of the way, economists turned to other
issues: Why had the financial system come so close to failing? Why didnt existing
regulations prevent the asset price bubble? What new regulations could keep another
bubble from occurring? What should the Fed do now to get the economy back on its
long-run growth path? Lets start by considering the regulation problem.
The Problem of Regulating the Financial Sector
An engineer who designs a bridge that almost collapses would be questioned thor-
oughly. How did the collapse happen and what can be done to see that it doesnt hap-
pen again? So it is appropriate to question economists: How did economists not only
let the economic collapse happen, but once the signs of a bubble were clear why didn’t
they warn society that a financial crisis was about to happen?
Economists answer these questions in various ways. Some emphasize that policy
makers were swayed by political interests and wrangling, not by empirical evidence
and economic theory. Politicians, not economists, are to blame for the financial crisis.
These economists point out that a number of economists recognized the problems and
suggested reforms, but policy makers failed to pass new regulations. Moreover, those
regulations that were instituted werent executed correctly. The then Fed chair Ben
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 687 11/10/18 11:35 AM
688 Macroeconomics Finance, Money, and the Economy
Bernanke expressed this view when he wrote, “The recent financial crisis was more a
failure of economic engineering and economic management than of what I have called
economic science.
Other economists are not as sure that economic theory can be absolved of
blame. The problem is that in standard economic theory, financial bubbles arent
supposed to happen. People are supposed to be rational and rational people dont
make such major mistakes. In standard economic thinking the prices of assets are
considered the best estimate of those future prices, which is called the efficient
market hypothesisall financial decisions are made by rational people and are
based on all relevant information that accurately reflects the value of assets today
and in the future. Rational people will recognize that asset prices are rising too
quickly.
The efficient market hypothesis
assumes that all financial decisions are
made by rational people and are based
on all relevant information that accu-
rately reflects the value of assets today
and in the future.
The efficient market hypothesis has an important implication for monetary policy:
Since bubbles cant happen, monetary policy makers didnt have to pay attention to
the rising housing prices that occurred in the early 2000s. It wasnt housing price
inflation; the real value of housing was rising. The efficient market hypothesis said
that asset markets, such as housing, could be left on autopilot. With asset prices set on
automatic, monetary policy could focus on goods market inflation as an indicator of
whether monetary policy was too expansionary. As mentioned above, in the standard
AS/AD model, when there was little inflation and no threat of accelerating inflation,
monetary policy could be expansionary. That was the view that guided conventional
macroeconomic theory. Policy makers didnt worry about the financial crisis because
conventional economic theory was telling them they didnt have to worry about it. So
for unconventional economists, conventional economists are to blame. Ben Bernanke
is wrong; it was a failure of economic science.
For unconventional economists,
economic science is to blame for the
financial crisis.
The events of 2008 changed the view that markets are rational for many economists,
including some of the leading advocates of the former conventional model. For
example, another previous Fed chair, Alan Greenspan, stated, “I made a mistake in
presuming that the self-interests of organizations, specifically banks and others, were
such that they were best capable of protecting their own shareholders and their equity
in the firms.” He continued by saying that his conventional worldview was “not
working.” He stated, “Thats precisely the reason I was shocked, because I have been
going for 40 years or more with very considerable evidence that it was working
exceptionally well.
It was at that point that alternative views about the problems in the economy started
to gain in acceptance. These alternative views held that while people were individually
rational, they could be collectively irrational, following herding behavior. This meant
that asset prices were subject to bubbles, and monetary policy and regulation would
have to be designed to prevent asset price bubbles as well as prevent goods market
inflation. This made conducting monetary policy and designing financial regulation
much more difficult. It is a process that requires institutional knowledge, judgment,
and educated common sense that is on the lookout for bubbles. Policy cannot be based
on fully predetermined rules.
When society can be collectively
irrational, as unconventional economists
believe to be the case, monetary policy
is much more difficult; it requires
institutional knowledge, judgment, and
educated common sense.
One of the commonsense implications of this alternative view was that when mon-
etary policy is too expansionary, and world prices are holding goods market inflation
down because of globalization, excess liquidity from monetary policy could be chan-
neled into asset price bubbles. This was the structural stagnationists viewpoint. Many
economists, including behavioral economists, heterodox economists, Post-Keynesian
economists, Austrian economists, and more, had been arguing that bubbles could and
did exist for years. One in particular, Hyman Minsky, a Post-Keynesian economist,
developed a psychological theory that predicted asset price bubbles as almost inevita-
ble in a capitalist economy.
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 688 11/10/18 11:35 AM
Chapter 30 Financial Crises, Panics, and Unconventional Monetary Policy 689
So a wide variety of economists of quite different political persuasions accepted
that bubbles were possible. Where they differed was in how bubbles should be dealt
with; these debates are continuing.
Regulation, Bubbles, and the Financial Sector
The assumption that the market on its own can be collectively irrational creates the
need for regulation, or an institutional structure that will prevent that collective irratio-
nality from developing. The question is how that should be done. After the financial
crisis led to a financial meltdown in 1929 and the Great Depression, the United States
instituted strong controls over the financial sector. These regulatory controls were
designed to prevent the financial markets from freezing up again in the future. Govern-
ment set up rules for banks—what they could and could not do; it also set up a system
of deposit insurancea system under which the federal government promises to
reimburse an individual for any losses due to bank failure—which would help prevent
future bank runs. These rules were strong and were meant to see that a financial crisis
would not happen again.
To implement the deposit insurance program, the government created the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC)a government institution that guarantees
bank deposits of up to $250,000. That guarantee discouraged bank runs, but it also cre-
ated a moral hazard problem—a problem that arises when people’s actions do not
reflect the full cost of their actions. Specifically, with deposit insurance, people could
put their money into a bank that offered high interest rates even though the bank made
excessively risky loans. If the bank ran out of money because its loans went bad, the
federal government would cover the loss. Depositors could earn high interest assured
they would not lose their money.
Q-3 What is a lender of last resort
and how does it relate to moral hazard?
To offset the moral hazard problem that deposit insurance would create, govern-
ment: (1) established strict regulations of banks, (2) separated banks from other finan-
cial institutions, and (3) designed systems so that necessary financial transactions that
were central to the operation of the economy stayed within banks. These were included
in a number of financial laws passed in the 1930s, the most important of which was
known as the Glass-Steagall Actan act of Congress passed in 1933 that established
deposit insurance and implemented a number of banking regulations including pro-
hibiting commercial banks from investing in the securities market. The intent was to
keep commercial banks from speculating in the stock market or in other risky financial
asset markets.
With the institution of these new regulations, the United States had a highly
regulated commercial banking system. The point of the regulations was to make
commercial banking boring—and therefore safe. People called commercial banking
the “3-6-3 business”—borrow at 3 percent, lend at 6 percent, and be on the golf course
by 3 p.m. Banks couldnt invest in equities and were prohibited from paying interest on
deposits. Both these restrictions reduced the ability of banks to engage in risky
behavior. These regulations were implemented as a result of the Depression, in the
belief that the government could never again let banks go under—they were too
important to fail. And if they were too important to fail, they had to be regulated to
address the moral hazard problems.
It isnt only deposit insurance that can create a moral hazard. Any type of guaran-
tee, or expectation of bailout, can do the same thing. An example can be seen by con-
sidering the effects of subsidizing loans for homeowners facing foreclosure, or even of
reducing the principal of loans that homeowners owe. Suppose that, in 2005, you had
prudently decided not to buy a house because you believed that houses were already
significantly overpriced. Your foolish friend, on the other hand, bought into the “house
Any type of guarantee, or expectation
of a bailout, can create a moral hazard.
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 689 11/10/18 11:35 AM
690 Macroeconomics Finance, Money, and the Economy
prices always rise” myth and decided to buy a big McMansion that he could not really
afford. You were prudent and your friend was foolish, and he’s underwater on his
house and facing foreclosure. Now suppose the government comes along and bails him
out, or lowers the balance on his loan since it doesn’t want him to face foreclosure.
Whats the outcome? He ends up with a nice house and you end up with nothing.
Whos foolish now?
The belief that the government will bail out people and firms when they make stu-
pid decisions helped create the crisis in the first place, and any bailout now will likely
lead people to expect a bailout in the future. They will then choose to follow riskier
strategies than they otherwise would have, potentially creating even larger problems in
the future. So the bailout rewards precisely the wrong type of behavior, and hence cre-
ates a moral hazard problem for future decisions. To offset those moral hazard prob-
lems, either strict regulation is needed, or the possibilities of bailouts have to be taken
off the table. For individuals, this regulation would mean strict requirements about
down payments and the income level needed to buy a home. For firms it would mean
financial regulations and limitations on what firms too important to fail can and cannot
do. Thats what the Glass-Steagall Act did.
The belief that the government will bail
out people and firms when they make
stupid decisions helped create the crisis
in the first place.
The Law of Diminishing Control
If we had regulations in the 1930s, why didn’t those regulations protect us in 2008?
An important reason is that over time the regulations designed in the 1930s became
less and less effective. The reason can be called the law of diminishing control,
which holds that any regulation will become less effective over time as individuals or
firms being regulated will figure out ways to circumvent those regulations through
innovation, technological change, and political pressure. This means that even if the
initial regulations do what they are supposed to do, over time they will become less
effective. In banking, the financial sector simply moved its risky operations, which
the regulations were meant to prevent, outside the banking sector. So while the
regulations contained risk by keeping the “core” of the banking system within a well-
regulated commercial banking sector, they did not contain risk in the broader financial
sector. It is a bit like the drinking laws for minors in the United States. On most
campuses, the laws dont stop underage drinking; they just push it into the dorms or
private homes.
Q-4 What causes diminishing control
of regulations?
Trying to regulate banks is a bit like
trying to regulate drinking by minors.
The regulation doesn’t stop it; it just
pushes the problem somewhere else.
New FiNaNcial iNstitutioNs aNd iNstrumeNts An example of finan-
cial innovation that circumvented bank regulation was the creation of NOW (nego-
tiable order of withdrawal) accounts in the 1970s. Under the Glass-Steagall Act
only commercial banks could offer checking accounts, but they couldnt pay inter-
est on those deposits. Savings banks had the benefit of being able to pay interest on
deposits, but couldnt offer checking accounts. In the 1970s, savings banks got
around the regulation by issuing what were called NOW accounts. With a NOW
account a customer could direct the savings bank to send funds to a third party.
These withdrawal notices looked almost identical to checks from a commercial
bank. But since the funds were legally considered to be savings accounts, savings
banks avoided regulations prohibiting interest on checking accounts. Money flowed
out of commercial banks and into savings banks. Other financial institutions devel-
oped products such as money market accounts and mutual fund accounts, which
also let depositors write checks on their accounts. These accounts included not just
cash but bonds and even stocks. Regulations no longer solved the problem of pre-
venting the financial sector from paying interest on the new accounts that were the
equivalent of checking accounts.
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 690 11/10/18 11:35 AM
Chapter 30 Financial Crises, Panics, and Unconventional Monetary Policy 691
regulatioNs covered Fewer FiNaNcial iNstrumeNts The develop-
ment of new financial instruments described above is just one example. Such changes
occurred in just about every aspect of the law. By the 1980s, it was clear that the Glass-
Steagall Act was no longer preventing activities it was meant to prevent. It simply
moved the practice outside the banking system and into other financial institutions.
By the 1980s it was clear that the Glass-
Steagall Act was no longer preventing
activities it was meant to prevent.
As new financial instruments developed, regulated commercial banks lost business
to unregulated financial institutions. Thus, what had been a protective umbrella over
the financial system that is necessary for a smoothly functioning economy provided
cover for a smaller and smaller segment of the financial industry. The commercial
banking system was still regulated, but the “financial oil” increasingly flowed through
the less regulated parts of the financial infrastructure. This shift was compounded by
the fact that financial markets were becoming global, and the U.S. regulations con-
trolled only U.S. financial institutions. Many U.S financial institutions could legiti-
mately threaten to move to those countries that offered the least regulation. (Think of
it as a child of divorced parents who plays one parent off the other to get the most
lenient rules.) This reduced the ability of the United States to strictly regulate many
financial institutions.
Political Pressure to reduce regulatioNs Politics is another reason
regulation becomes less effective; when regulation successfully eliminates or reduces
the problems, people begin to forget that the regulation was necessary in the first place.
Instead, the groups being regulated view regulations as unnecessary restrictions and
will lobby to dismantle them. With the Great Depression fresh in everyone’s memory,
people in the 1930s favored regulation to avert repeating the Depression. But as
decades passed and societal memories of the Great Depression faded, so did that view.
Regulation and regulators were increasingly viewed by many as undesirable hin-
drances to the free market and all its magic. That was the view that Alan Greenspan
referred to in the earlier quote. The belief that the market could self-regulate meant
that relatively low-paid regulators were faced with the nearly impossible task of bal-
ancing the pressures of innovation that made the regulations obsolete against the need
to get some regulation within an atmosphere that saw regulation as preventing the U.S.
economy from growing.
When regulation successfully eliminates
or reduces the problems, people begin to
forget that the regulation was necessary
in the first place.
Politics also had to deal with an inherent problem of regulation—the too-big-to-
fail problemthe problem that large financial institutions are essential to the work-
ings of an economy, requiring government to step in to prevent their failure. The
too-big-to-fail problem is another example of the moral hazard problem. If individuals
in the financial sector recognize the financial sector’s importance to the economy and
know that the government will be forced to bail them out, they change their behavior,
just like kids change their behavior when they know that their parents will bail them
out. They do stupid things. The problem with kids, and with large banks, is that when
you threaten them that you arent going to bail them out, the threat isn’t credible. It
takes resolve that I, and most governments, dont have. (Note to my children: Mom has
that resolve.) Unless one has that resolve, no threat will be credible, which means that
kids and businesses (with soft parents and soft governments) will continue to do stupid
things; they wont take the full consequences of their actions into account.
In response to the crisis, in 2010 the United States passed the Dodd-Frank Wall
Street Reform and Consumer Protection Acta new financial regulatory structure
to limit risk taking and require banks to report their holdings so that regulators could
assess risk-taking behavior. The Dodd-Frank law attempts to minimize the too-big-to-
fail problem. If a company is at risk of default, a process is put in place to liquidate the
corporation, limiting the impact on the economy. The hope is that these regulations
will protect the U.S. economy from future financial meltdowns. The law once again
Q-5 What did government do to
address the too-big-to-fail problem?
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 691 11/10/18 11:35 AM
692
REALWORLD APPLICATION
Cryptomania
The law of diminishing control tells us
that new ways of getting around regula-
tions will always be developing, reducing
the value of regulations over time. One
new development in finance involves
what are called cryptocurrencies—which
as I discussed in Chapter 28 are best
thought of as crypto assets, since they
don’t meet the requirement of being a
currency. They are more like a stock—a
bundle of rights that are specified when you buy the as-
set. With stocks you get a percentage of the profits. With
cryptocurrency you get a token, often with no specific
rights, or only a highly ambiguous set of rights to some
activity that is loosely related to the blockchain technol-
ogy that underlies cryptocurrencies. By calling these as-
sets a currency or a token, not a stock, the originators of
cryptocurrencies are attempting to avoid the regulation
that stock offerings must meet. That is now changing.
Governments have increased regulation of initial coin
offerings and are beginning to interpret them more as
stock offerings (which are highly regulated).
Just about all financial advisers advise their clients who
don’t have money to throw away to stay out of the crypto
asset market. But many clients don’t follow that advice,
and billions of dollars are generated by initial coin offer-
ings, with more offerings springing up every day. After all,
from the issuer’s perspective, if you can get someone to
give you $10,000 for a virtual token that costs, perhaps,
10 cents to make, offers little in the way of rights to the
buyer, and is largely unregulated, it’s a
good business deal for the issuer. Want
to buy a Colandercryptotext coin? Only
$200, and $200 will be devoted to think-
ing about how textbooks can incorpo-
rate blockchain technology. (Hint: Not a
good idea.)
©spaxiax/Shutterstock
Why do people buy crypto assets?
The answer is psychological. When a
person hears stories about how the
price of Bitcoin went from $14 to $20,000, and how
cutting-edge blockchain technology will change the
world he is tempted to get a “piece of the action.” Add to
that the mystical, seductive allure of the name
cryptocurrency—along with a sense of Bitcoin’s association
with the dark web (un-indexed portions of the web, much
of which is dedicated to illegal activities), and high-
pressure salespeople telling you that if you don’t buy
soon you will be left behind, and you can understand
why some investors are hooked, just as they have been
hooked in the past by the South Sea bubble and Tulipmania.
Some people, mainly the issuers, but also some
investors, will make money in crypto assets. Blockchain
technology is revolutionary and in the coming decades
likely will be useful in recording contracts. And even if
the company eventually flops, you can still make money
by buying crypto assets if the hype increases and you
find someone who will pay more for them than you paid.
But when the bubble bursts, people will push for
government regulation.
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 692 11/10/18 11:35 AM
limits banks’ ability to invest in securities, consolidates regulatory agencies to improve
their effectiveness, expands oversight to some nonbank financial institutions, and cre-
ates new tools for dealing with financial crises. Unfortunately, few economists believe
that the new law, even before the law of diminishing marginal control has set in, has
resolved the financial regulation problem. Legal and financial scholars on all sides of
the political spectrum have criticized the law as both insufficient to prevent another
financial crisis in some aspects and overly restrictive of financial institutions in others.
With the election of President Trump in 2016, the policy focus turned to deregulation.
The number of banks that were subject to Dodd-Frank requirements was decreased
significantly, and regulations on others were reduced.
Chapter 30 Financial Crises, Panics, and Unconventional Monetary Policy 693
General Principles of Regulation
Economics does not identify ideal regulations, but it does provide some general guide-
lines. The basic guideline is that along with the freedom to undertake activities in the
market comes the responsibility for ones actions. If firms (or kids) are not, and cannot
be, made responsible for the negative consequences of their actions, there is a role for
regulations to restrict the set of actions firms are permitted to take. Regulation is
necessary if a bailout is in the cards. (As I tell my kids—the golden rule of economics
is: Him who pays the bills makes the rules.)
The basic guideline of regulation is that
along with the freedom to undertake
activities in the market comes
responsibility for one’s actions.
Regulation is necessary if a bailout is in
the cards.
The question policy makers face in trying to design the rules and regulations for
our economy in the future is: Can a government influenced by special interests institute
the right type of regulation? Economists come to different answers on this question,
which is why they have different views of regulation.
Lets close our discussion of regulation with three general precepts about dealing
with financial crises that most economists would sign on to. They are:
Q-6 What are the three principles of
regulation?
Set as few bad precedents as possible. Policies that keep the economy alive
might create long-run problems. Recognize these problems, and try to offset
them as best you can.
Deal with moral hazard. If a firm or individual is to be unregulated, it should
be subject to the consequences of its actions. This leads to a corollary: If a firm
or individual is considered too big to fail, it has to be regulated. Notice that this
rule does not say that government should or should not regulate. It just says
that it has to be consistent.
Deal with the law of diminishing control. Regulation has to be considered a
process, not a one-time decision. The economy is a dynamic changing entity,
subject to the law of diminishing control, which means that when new business
practices and financial instruments change, rules must change. Expect innovation
and establish a method of changing those regulations to adapt to the changing
situation without weakening the regulations.
Monetary Policy in the Post–Financial Crisis Era
Now let us turn to the question: What monetary policy should the Fed follow after it
has fulfilled its lender of last resort role and avoided a financial crisis? In other words,
what is the Fed’s appropriate monetary policy role in a post–financial crisis era?
Coming out of a financial crisis, the Fed was carrying a large number of loans to
banks and other financial institutions that it made to provide the banks with liquidity.
As the threat of a financial meltdown subsided, that role had ended. The standard prac-
tice would be for the Fed to wind down policies as the lender of last resort, and revert
back to conventional monetary policies. A number of economists called on the Fed to
do precisely that. But with the economy in a deep recession, those policies would have
been highly politically unpopular because they would slow down the recovery.
After the financial crisis subsided, the
standard practice would have been for
the Fed to wind down its lender-of-last-
resort loans. It did not do that because
the economy was in a deep recession.
The argument for unwinding those positions despite the high unemployment was
that this was not your typical recession—it was structural stagnation that reflected
structural problems caused by globalization, and the 5 to 6 percent growth rate needed
until the economy returned to trend was not in the cards. The structural problems that
structural stagnationists see as the cause of the slow growth could not be solved by
monetary policy. To maintain expansionary monetary policy essentially meant
continuing the policies that caused the financial bubble in the first place by expanding
credit in the economy enormously. If the economy is in a structural stagnation,
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 693 11/10/18 11:35 AM
694 Macroeconomics Finance, Money, and the Economy
expanding credit beyond the initial triage policy necessary to save the economy from
imploding will only increase the likelihood of a further, possibly even more damaging,
bubble. This is the case even if that policy of monetary restraint will leave the economy
with higher unemployment than otherwise. If the problem facing the U.S. economy
was a structural stagnation, a primary policy focus would have to be on resolving the
structural problems before expansionary monetary policy is called for.
If the problem facing the U.S. economy is
a structural stagnation problem, a primary
policy focus has to be on resolving the
structural problems before expansionary
monetary policy is called for.
In this view, expansionary monetary policy not only would not resolve these struc-
tural problems; it would eliminate the impetus for the private sector to solve them as
well. Expansionary monetary policy in the face of these structural problems would be
analogous to giving painkillers to an addict, when what he needs is detox. According
to structural stagnationists, the appropriate policy would have been for the Fed to
return to conventional monetary policy as soon as possible, even though doing so
would slow the recovery, and possibly even put the economy back into a recession.
The Fed didnt follow that policy. Instead, it introduced a new unconventional monetary
policy thereby keeping the economy out of a recession, but creating the conditions for
a potential crisis in the future.
Economic theory does not provide definitive answers to what is the correct mone-
tary policy. The data are inevitably ambiguous and subject to various interpretations,
which means that policy has to be based on sensibilities and guesstimates.
The Fed continued running expansionary monetary policy after the United States
emerged from the financial crisis and the recession associated with it. The reasons were:
(1) inflation remained lower than desired; (2) economic growth remained sluggish
(during the upturn, growth was only 2 to 3 percent rather than the 5 to 6 percent they
were hoping for); and (3) there was a fear that ending the expansionary policy would
throw the economy into a recession and possibly even another financial crisis. Only in
2017, when unemployment had fallen to close to 4 percent, did the Federal Reserve
begin switching toward a more conventional monetary policy, and increasing interest
rates, but because of continued slow growth and fears of recession, they were moving
very slowly, and stood ready to reverse policy quickly. What had been seen as
unconventional monetary policy seemed to be becoming the new normal.
Unconventional Monetary Policy
The desire to continue running expansionary policy in the post–financial crisis period
presented a technical problem to the Fed. In its role as a lender of last resort, it had
already done all it could to expand the economy using the tools of conventional mon-
etary policy. The Fed funds rate was essentially zero and the banking system was
awash in reserves. The conventional expansionary monetary policy was not leading to
increases in money and credit; instead it just ended up as excess reserves in the banks
as we saw in the last chapter. To get around this problem, the Fed created a new set of
policies meant to stimulate the economy through unconventional means. These poli-
cies included:
Web Note 30.3
Rear-View Mirror
1. Quantitative easing,
2. Operation twist, and
3. A precommitment policy.
These are the tools of unconventional monetary policy. Lets consider each of these.
Three unconventional monetary policy
tools are:
1. Quantitative easing,
2. Operation twist, and
3. Precommitment policy.
Quantitative easing As you learned in the last chapter, conventional mone-
tary policy involves open market operations (the Fed buying and selling short-term
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 694 11/23/18 8:05 AM
Chapter 30 Financial Crises, Panics, and Unconventional Monetary Policy
695
bonds) to affect the bank reserves and therefore the money supply and the Fed funds
rate). But as we have discussed, in the aftermath of the financial crisis, standard open
market operations did not increase the money supply. The short-term interest rate
approached zero, and even after the Fed flooded the system with reserves, banks did
not make new loans; they simply held more excess reserves. Excess reserves shot up
and the money supply did not increase. If the goal is to stimulate the economy, that
presents a problem.
A way around that problem is quantitative easinga policy of buying a wide
range of financial assets from banks and other financial institutions in order to stimu-
late the economy. With quantitative easing, the Fed buys a much more diverse set of
assets, such as long-term government bonds and mortgage-backed securities, than it
does with conventional monetary policy. Because quantitative easing doesnt work
through increasing reserves, or short-term interest rates, it can be expansionary even if
excess reserves are high or if the short-term interest rate is at or near zero. The increase
in the money supply goes directly into the economy, bypassing the conventional
banking sector.
You can see the desired effect of quantitative easing by considering the
yield curve shown in Figure 30-1. As I discussed in the last chapter
,
conventional monetary policy pushes down on the short end of the yield
curve, with the expectation that in doing so, it will push down the long-run
interest rate as well, thereby shifting the entire curve down. Quantitative
easing pushes the upper end of the yield curve down directly, thereby
holding down the interest rate for investors and stimulating asset markets
and the economy.
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 695 11/23/18 8:06 AM
FIGURE 30-1 Quantitative Easing’s Effect
on the Yield Curve
Bond maturity
Interest rate (%)
Quantitative easing might also be called an asset price support system
because it holds the prices of financial assets higher, and long-term interest
rates lower, than they would have been. Thus, the almost trillion dollars of
mortgage-backed securities, which the Fed bought in its quantitative easing
program, held up the prices of those securities, significantly helping
financial institutions and others that held these securities while it lowered
long-term interest rates. It hurt savers, who received low interest rates.
When quantitative easing involves buying long-term nongovernmental
securities such as mortgage-backed securities, or other private assets, it is often
called credit easing or qualitative easing. Qualitative easing and credit easing
differ from quantitative easing because the primary goal of credit and qualitative eas-
ing is to change the quality—or mix—of assets it buys, and not to change the total
amount of assets. You can see the impact of quantitative easing and its variants on the
balance sheet of the Fed in Figure 30-2.
Q-7 How does quantitative easing
differ from conventional monetary
policy?
OperatiOn twist The Fed also added another unconventional tooloperation
twistselling short-term Treasury bills and buying long-term Treasury bonds without
creating more new money. Like credit easing, operation twist changes the composition
of the Fed’s portfolio; unlike credit easing it does not entail buying private securities.
Its purpose is not to reduce private bank risk, but to lower long-term interest rates.
That is, its purpose is to “twist” the yield curve. The tool was created to address
concerns that because quantitative easing increased the monetary base, it would lead
to inflation. With operation twist, the Fed offset its purchases of long-term bonds by
selling an equal amount of short-term bonds. In principle, selling short-term bonds
would raise short-term interest rates and twist the yield curve, making it flatter. You
Q-8 What effect did the Fed expect
operation twist to have on the yield
curve?
696 Macroeconomics Finance, Money, and the Economy
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 696 11/10/18 11:35 AM
FIGURE 30-2 Change in the
Fed’s Assets
In credit easing, the Fed reduces
its traditional security holdings
and replaces them with less
liquid and riskier assets.
Federal Reserve Assets (in trillions of dollars)
Years
2007 2015 2016 20172014 20182012 20132011201020092008
5
3
2
4
1
0
Long-term Treasury purchases
Federal agency debt
mortgage-backed securities
Lending to financial institutions
plus liquidity to key markets
Traditional security holdings
can see operation twist by again considering the intended effect on the yield
curve in Figure 30-3.
FIGURE 30-3 Effect of Operation Twist
on the Yield Curve
Long-term
interest rates
Interest rate (%)
down
Short-term
interest rates
up
3 mo 1 yr 5 yr 30 yr
Bond maturity
Operation twist places downward pressure on the long-term rate and upward
pressure on the short-term rate. In actuality, since banks were holding so many
excess reserves, the effect on the short-term rate was negligible, so only the long
part of the yield curve shifted down, relative to where it otherwise would have
been. But it did so without changing the money supply.
PrecommitmeNt Policy Even with these policies some economists
were concerned that the Fed was not doing enough to expand the economy.
After all, inflation was low and showed no signs of acceleration. Another
unconventional monetary policy that the Fed followed was the precommitment
policycommitting to continue a policy for a prolonged period of time. In 2011
the Fed promised to hold the Fed funds rate close to zero until the end of 2014.
It continued that policy through 2015, but in 2016, it announced that it would
consider slowly raising rates if it felt economic conditions warranted doing so.
Since then and into 2018, the Fed has gradually raised its target for the Federal
funds rate as the economy grew. Precommitment had major significance for
bond and stock investors. It meant that expansionary monetary policy would
continue for two years regardless of the health of the economy or the inflation rate. It
was designed to assure investors that the short-term rate would not rise, which would
have caused losses by investors who held low-interest-rate bonds.
Q-9 What three unconventional
tools did the Fed use to address the
crisis?
wiNdiNg dowN uNcoNveNtioNal moNetary Policy Unconventional
monetary policy was seen as a temporary set of policies that continued for longer than
expected because of the slow growth and low inflation following the recession. In
2017, as the U.S. economy picked up, economists’ thinking turned to how to unwind
Chapter 30 Financial Crises, Panics, and Unconventional Monetary Policy 697
the approximately $4.5 trillion of nontraditional assets that the Fed had accumulated in
its unconventional monetary policy without knocking the economy back into recession
or even further slowing the growth of the economy that many felt was too slow.
Q-10 Why is unwinding
unconventional monetary politically
difficult?
As long as inflation remained below target, there was little pressure on the Fed to
unwind its policies. By 2017, however, most economists felt that with unemployment
low and inflation close to its target rate, it was time for the unwinding to begin. In
October 2017 the Fed did so when it started selling off about $10 billion of its non-
traditional assets a month, a rate that, if followed, would take almost 30 years to unwind.
That pace reflected the Fed’s concern that it should unwind its position in the market
very carefully. The concern was that selling off those assets more quickly would lead to
a sudden fall in asset prices and would be politically unpopular and place the Fed in the
political limelight. So rather than operating in the background of providing a stable
structure for the economy, it would be exposed to greater political criticism.
Conclusion
As I stated earlier in the chapter, economic theory does not provide definitive guidance
on the appropriate monetary policy. The data are too ambiguous, and the interrelation-
ships so complex, that theory cannot provide much help. Thats why there is so much
debate about the appropriate monetary policy. All agree that in the long run, structural
adjustments to our economy are needed, and that unconventional monetary policy
does not offer long-run solutions. Those who oppose unconventional monetary policy
argue that we need to focus on the long run, not the short run.
It isn’t as if any group has a magic
answer to the macro problems that the
United States faces.
The problem with this view is that, as Keynes said back in the 1930s, in the long
run we are all dead. By that he meant not that we can stop worrying about the long run,
but that if the short-run problems are so severe that they will undermine the economy,
then there will be no long run unless we deal with those short-run problems. Deciding
about monetary policy involves making judgments about the severity of short-run
problems relative to long-run problems. Making such judgments involves sensibilities
that go far beyond economics, and thus economists can be expected to disagree, even
when they agree about the theory. What economic understanding can do is to sort out
some of the issues relevant to making those judgments.
Summary
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 697 11/10/18 11:35 AM
The financial sector provides the credit that all other
sectors need for both day-to-day and long-term needs.
If the financial sector were to collapse, all other
sectors would collapse along with it. (LO30-1)
The Fed has the resources and ability to lend to finan-
cial institutions and banks when no one else will,
thereby averting an economic crash. (LO30-1)
The elements of a financial crisis are: (1) asset prices
rise to unsustainable levels (a bubble develops),
(2) asset prices fall precipitously (the bubble bursts),
pushing the economy into a financial crisis, and
(3) the economy falls into a severe recession. (LO30-1)
Two ingredients of a bubble are herding and
leveraging. Herding creates the run-up in prices.
Leveraging increases people’s ability to herd,
which increases prices further. The Fed can create
a bubble with significant expansionary monetary
policy. (LO30-2)
Government regulations that guarantee bailouts for
banks and financial institutions create the moral hazard
698 Macroeconomics Finance, Money, and the Economy
problem, which leads banks and financial institutions to
take risks for which they dont have to pay. (LO30-3)
Regulations have limited impact on bank behavior
because of the law of diminishing control. (LO30-3)
Because the failure of large banks would have
disastrous effects on the real economy, they are
considered too big to fail, which leads to the moral
hazard problem. (LO30-3)
Three general principles of regulation are: (1) set as
few bad precedents as possible to limit the moral hazard
problem, (2) deal with moral hazard by requiring
banks to face the consequences of their actions, and
(3) change regulations as innovations emerge and
business practices change. (LO30-3)
Beginning in 2008, the Fed implemented unconven-
tional policies such as quantitative easing, operation
twist, and precommitment policy. The purpose was to
reduce the amount of risky assets held by banks,
encourage bank lending, and encourage private
borrowing. (LO30-4)
Key Terms
asset price bubble
deposit insurance
Dodd-Frank Wall Street
Reform and Consumer
Protection Act
efficient market
hypothesis
extrapolative
expectations
Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation
(FDIC)
Glass-Steagall Act
herding
law of diminishing
control
lender of last resort
leverage
liquid
mortgage-backed
securities
operation twist
precommitment policy
quantitative easing
solvent
too-big-to-fail problem
Questions and Exercises
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 698 11/23/18 8:07 AM
1. Why is the Fed’s role as lender of last resort an important
function of the Fed? (LO30-1)
2. What role did liquidity play in the financial crisis in
2008? What caused this lack of liquidity? (LO30-1)
3. What is the role of extrapolativ
e expectations in
increasing the price level and creating an asset price
bubble? (LO30-1
)
4. If you invest $200 in a stock, borrowing 90 percent of the
$200 at 10 percent interest, and the stock price rises by
20 percent, what is t
he return on your investment? (LO30-2)
5. Why did the Fed follow far more expansionary policy
than the Taylor rule suggested? (LO30-2)
6. In t
he standard AS/AD model, what role does a financial
bubble play in determining whether an economy exceeds
potential output? Explain your answer.
(LO30-2)
7. What is the efficient market hypothesis and how does it
relate to government regulation? (LO30-3)
8. What is the moral hazar
d problem and how does deposit
insurance lead to it? (LO30-3)
9. What are three reasons why t
he Glass-Steagall Act became
less and less effective? (LO30-3)
10. Why are large f
inancial institutions considered to be too
big to fail? What problem does it create? (LO30-3)
11. Why do some economists believ
e the Fed needs to unwind
monetary policies instituted during the recession? What is
the risk in doing so? (LO30-4
)
12. What distinguishes credit easing from quantitative easing?
What problem was each designed to address? (LO30-4)
13. What distinguishes operation twis
t from credit easing?
(LO30-4)
14. Demonstrate the different effects t
hat quantitative easing
and operation twist were expected to have on the yield
curve. Explain your answ
er. (LO30-4)
15. How was operation twist expected to avoid the criticisms
of quantitative easing? (LO30-4)
16. How would a precommitment policy address pr
oblems in
the economy? What is the risk of such a policy? (LO30-4)
Chapter 30 Financial Crises, Panics, and Unconventional Monetary Policy 699
Questions from Alternative Perspectives
1. Ron Paul, a 2012 and 2016 presidential candidate, be-
lieves that the Federal Reserve should be abolished and
our monetary system should be replaced by a gold stan-
dard. How does the experience of the past decade reflect
on that idea? (Austrian)
2. Hyman Minsky’s theory of fluctuations in output in a
capitalist economy was ignored by mainstream economics
but has proven to be much closer to reality than are theories
suggested by mainstream macroeconomists. What are some
reasons why his theory was ignored? (Post-Keynesian)
3. Post-Keynesian macroeconomist Paul Davidson has argued
that the central characteristic of the Keynesian view of
markets is nonergodicity, which in simple terms implies
the lack of an ability to know or forecast the future. How
does nonergodicity undermine the efficient market hy-
pothesis? (Post-Keynesian)
4.
If Greece makes its bonds legal payment for taxes, it will
be able to sell all the bonds it wants to without worrying
about discounts. What prevents the Greek government
from following this solution? (Post-Keynesian)
5. Many of the regulators and overseers of the government
bailout came from the same firms that brought about the
crisis in the first place. Can we expect reasonable regula-
tion when that is the case? (Radical)
Issues to Ponder
1. If a country goes bankrupt and cannot pay its debts, which
of its responsibilities should take precedence: paying
bondholders or paying the pensions of its employees?
2. If the U.S. economy were t
o go into another financial crisis
and additional monetary stimulus were needed to prevent a
financial collapse, what measures would you sugges
t the
government take?
3. If asset markets arent efficient, then it should be possible
for investors to consistently make money by betting that the
price of an asset will r
eturn to its “correct” value. That
doesn’t seem to be the case. Does that suggest that the
efficient market hypothesis is correct?
4. How can economists support a bailout packag
e when
they recognize that the bailout will create a moral hazard
problem?
5. If you had a son whom you had forbidden to drink and dr
ive,
threatening to throw him out of the house if he does drink
and drive, do you throw him out of the house if he does so?
6. In what sense is t
he most recent financial crisis a result of
deregulation?
Answers to Margin Questions
(Continued)
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 699 11/23/18 8:08 AM
1. The financial sector facilitates the running of the real
economy. The economy cannot function without the
financial sector. While the automobile industry will affect
the economy, it is not essential to it. (LO30-1)
2. Two central ingredients to a bubble are leveraging and
herding. (LO30-2)
3. The lender of last resort is an institution that promises to
lend to banks and financial institutions when no one else
will. It leads to the mor
al hazard problem because banks
will take greater risks kno
wing the government will cover
their losses. (LO30-3)
4. The effectiveness of regulations falls over time as banks
and financial institutions find ways to circumvent the
regulations and the perceived risk f
acing these institutions
diminishes. (LO30-3)
5. The government implemented new regulations that
limited risk taking by banks and financial institutions.
These ne
w regulations require that they repor
t their assets,
and they established a process of gradually dismantling
financial institutions that face insolvency. (LO30-3)
6. The three principles are: set as few bad precedents as
possible, deal with moral hazard, and deal with the law of
diminishing control. (LO30-3)
700 Macroeconomics Finance, Money, and the Economy
7.
Conventional monetary policy targets the Fed funds rate.
Quantitative easing targets the amount of money in the
economy by buying long-term bonds and
nongovernmental bonds, which adds money directly into
the economy. (LO30-4)
8. Operation twist was implemented to pull long-term
interest rates down and short-term interest rates up, that
is, invert the normal yield curve. (LO30-4)
9.
The three unconventional tools are: quantitative easing,
operation twist, and precommitment policy. (LO30-4)
10. Unwinding unconventional monetary policy is politically
difficult because it will push down asset prices and will
likely slow down the economy. (LO30-4)
Design elements: Web Note icon: ©McGraw-Hill Education; Real-World Application icon: ©McGraw-Hill Education; A Reminder icon: ©McGraw-Hill Education;
Added Dimension icon: ©McGraw-Hill Education; Thinking Like a Modern Economist icon: ©NeydtStock/Shutterstock
coL25585_ch30_681-700.indd 700 11/10/18 11:35 AM