
for the AFCO Committee
The Com position of
the European
Parliament

Directorate General for Internal Policies of the Union

PE583.117- February2017

DIRECTORATE GENERAL FOR INTERNAL POLICIES
POLICY DEPARTMENT C: CITIZENS' RIGHTS AND
CONSTITUTIONAL AFFAIRS
CONSTITUTIONAL AFFAIRS
THE COMPOSITION OF THE EUROPEAN
PARLIAMENT
WORKSHOP
3O January 2017
Compilation: Two briefings and one in-depth
analysis
PE 583 117 EN
Policy Department C: Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
____________________________________________________________________________________________
ABOUT THE PUBLICATION
These research papers were requested by the European Parliament's Committee on
Constitutional Affairs and were commissioned, overseen and published by the Policy
Department for Citizens’ Rights and Constitutional Affairs.
Policy departments provide independent expertise, both in-house and externally, to support
European Parliament committees and other parliamentary bodies in shaping legislation and
exercising democratic scrutiny over EU external and internal policies.
To contact the Policy Department for Citizens’ Rights and Constitutional Affairs or to
subscribe to its newsletter please write to: poldep-citiz[email protected]
Research Administrator Responsible
Ioannis PAPAGEORGIOU
Policy Department C: Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
European Parliament
B-1047 Brussels
E-mail: poldep-citizens@europarl.europa.eu
Editorial Assistant
Christina KATSARA
AUTHORS
Professor Geoffrey GRIMMETT, University of Cambridge
Professor Dr. Friedrich PUKELSHEIM, University of Augsburg
Professor Victoriano RAMÍREZ GONZÁLEZ, University of Granada
Dr Wojciech OMCZYŃSKI, Jagiellonian University, Cracow
Professor Karol ŻYCZKOWSKI, Jagiellonian University, Cracow
LINGUISTIC VERSIONS
Original: EN
Manuscript completed in February 2017
© European Union, 2017
This document is available on the internet at:
http://www.europarl.europa.eu/supporting-analyses
The Composition of the European Parliament
CONTENTS
LINKING THE PERMANENT SYSTEM OF THE DISTRIBUTION OF SEATS IN
THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT WITH THE DOUBLE-MAJORITY VOTING IN
THE COUNCIL OF MINISTERs 5
Prof. Dr. Friedrich PUKELSHEIM AND Prof. Geoffrey GRIMMETT
1. TWO PROPOSALS FOR THE ALLOCATION OF EP SEATS 5
2. FURTHER PROPOSALS 9
3. DEGRESSIVE PROPORTIONALITY 9
4. POPULATION CRITERION 10
5. INTER-INSTITUTIONAL BALANCE 10
6. RECOMMENDATIONS 11
7.SEAT ALLOCATION TABLES FOR THE 2019 EP 12
THE r-DP METHODS TO ALLOCATE THE EP SEATS TO MEMBER STATES 23
Prof. Victoriano RAMÍREZ GONZÁLEZ
1. INTRODUCTION 23
2. NON-DEGRESSIVITY AND OTHER FORMS OF ILLOGICAL BEHAVIOUR IN
CURRENT EP COMPOSITION 25
3. WHY DOES THE MINIMUM CORRESPOND TO 6 SEATS AND THE MAXIMUM TO
96? 26
4. WHY MUST THE REPRESENTATION IN THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT NOT BE
PROPORTIONAL? 26
5. THE FAMILY OF r-DP METHODS 27
6. THE COMPOSITION OF THE EP AFTER BREXIT 32
7. CONCLUSIONS 35
Policy Department C: Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
4
DEGRESSIVE PROPORTIONALITY IN THE EUROPEAN UNION 37
Dr. Wojciech SŁOMCZYŃSKI and Prof. Karol ŻYCZKOWSKI
1.ALLOCATING SEATS IN THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT 37
2.RECOMMENDED SOLUTIONS FOR THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT 42
3.THE SYSTEM OF VOTING IN THE COUNCIL OF THE EU 47
The Composition of the European Parliament
5
LINKING THE PERMANENT SYSTEM OF THE DISTRIBUTION
OF SEATS IN THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT WITH THE
DOUBLE-MAJORITY VOTING IN THE COUNCIL OF
MINISTERS
Prof. Dr. Friedrich PUKELSHEIM and Prof. Geoffrey
GRIMMETT
KEY FINDINGS
This paper proposes the adoption of the Cambridge Compromise which is a
transparent allocation method for determining the composition of the European
Parliament (EP). The method is responsive to population changes and impartial to
politics as well as objective, fair and durable. An alternative method is the
Cambridge Compromise with power-adjusted populations, called Power
Compromise for short. The latter is more flexible with respect to the 2014 alloca-
tion, but at the cost of some transparency, arising through the involvement of an
additional power parameter.
The EP composition must obey the operational principle of degressive
proportionality whereby the Member States’ representation ratios, that is, the
population figure divided by the number of seats before rounding, are decreasing
when passing from a more populous Member State to a less populous Member State.
The same population figures should be used for the EP composition and for the
qualified majority voting rule in the Council.
The Jagiellonian Compromise is a qualified majority voting rule for the Council
providing a more principled method than the current double-majority voting rule.
Our principal recommendation is twofold: the adoption of the Cambridge
Compromise, and the (independent) adoption of the Jagiellonian Compromise. While
each of these two recommendations stands alone, their coordinated adoption as a
pair will bring a balance to the dual structure of Parliament and Council.
Seat allocation tables for the 2019 EP are shown for a Union including the UK.
For a Union without the UK, three scenarios are adjoined: with 751 EP seats (maxi-
mum size), with 678 EP seats (without the 73 UK seats), and with 723 EP seats.
The last is the smallest EP size for which the Power Compromise assigns to every
Member State at least as many seats as in its 2014 allocation.
1. TWO PROPOSALS FOR THE ALLOCATION OF EP SEATS
The European Council Decision of 2013 establishing the composition of the EP states in its
Art.4 that the decision shall be revised with the aim of establishing a system to allocate the
seats between Member States in an objective, fair, durable and transparent way:
1
This Decision shall be revised sufficiently far in advance of the beginning of the 2019-2024
parliamentary term on the basis of an initiative of the European Parliament presented before the
end of 2016 with the aim of establishing a system which in future will make it possible, before each
fresh election to the European Parliament, to allocate the seats between Member States in an
objective, fair, durable and transparent way, translating the principle of degressive proportionality
1
OJ L 181, 29.6.2013, pp. 5758 (www.uni-augsburg.de/bazi/OJ/2013L181p57.pdf).
Policy Department C: Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
6
as laid down in Article 1, taking account of any change in their number and demographic trends in
their population, as duly ascertained thus respecting the overall balance of the institutional system
as laid down in the Treaties.
We propose two allocation methods that satisfy the requirements well: the Cambridge
Compromise,
2
and the Power Compromise.
3
The operational details of the two
procedures are presented first. Thereafter follow assessments of the methods’ merits from
the viewpoint of primary and secondary Union law.
Cambridge compromise
The Cambridge Compromise may be paraphrased as follows:
Every Member State is assigned a common number of base seats. The remaining
seats are allocated proportionately to population figures, using the divisor method
with upward rounding and subject to a maximum allocation. In the case of the
current EP, the number of base seats is 5, so that the least populous Member State
finishes with 6 seats, and the proportional allocation is capped in order to produce a
maximum of 96 seats.
For instance, in Table 1 the Cambridge Compromise proceeds as follows:
Every Member State is assigned 5 base seats, plus one seat per 846 000 citizens
or part thereof, with a maximum cap of 96 seats.
The currently smallest State, Malta, ends with a final tally of 6 seats (with only 4 base
seats, Malta would finish with 5 seats; with 6 base seats, it would finish with 7 seats). The
initial assignment of 5 base seats to each of the 28 Member States utilises a total of 140
seats, leaving 611 seats for the proportional allocation.
The remaining 611 seats are allocated using the divisor method with upward rounding. The
allocation key to be determined is the so-called divisor (846 000).
4
For example, when
dividing the Austrian population 8 711 500 by 846 000, the resulting quotient is 10.3. This
quotient is rounded upwards to obtain the number of proportionality seats (11). Thus
Austria is allocated a total of 16 seats: 5 base seats plus 11 proportionality seats. A similar
calculation is carried out for the other Member States. In the case of Germany, the quotient
5 + 97.003 = 102.003 exceeds the capping and is replaced by the 96 seat maximum.
Tables 1, 3, 5 illustrate the Cambridge Compromise, with 5 base seats in each case.
2
G.R. Grimmett / J.-F. Laslier / F. Pukelsheim / V. Ramírez González / R. Rose / W. Słomczyński / M. Zachariasen /
K. Życzkowski: The Allocation Between the EU Member States of the Seats in the European Parliament Cam-
bridge Compromise. Note. European Parliament, Directorate-General for Internal Policies, Policy Department C:
Citizen's Rights and Constitutional Affairs, PE 432.760, March 2011 (www.uni-augsburg.de/pukelsheim/2011f.pdf).
3
G.R. Grimmett / K.-F. Oelbermann / F. Pukelsheim: A power-weighted variant of the EU27 Cambridge Compro-
mise. Mathematical Social Sciences 63, 2012, pp. 136-140 (www.uni-augsburg.de/pukelsheim/2012a.pdf). Power
adjustments have been proposed in the literature since quite some time. See, for example: (1) H. Theil: The
desired political entropy. American Political Science Review 63, 1969, pp. 521-525. (2) H. Theil / L. Schrage: The
apportionment problem and the European Parliament. European Economic Review 9, 1977, pp. 247-263.
(3) A. Moberg: The voting system in the Council of the European Union. The balance between large and small
countries. Scandinavian Political Studies 21, 1998, pp. 347-365. Reprinted in: A. Moberg: The Weight of Nations.
Four Papers on the Institutional Negotiations in the EU 19962007. Malmö, 2014 (www.uni-augsburg.de/ bazi/Mo-
berg2014.pdf). (4) F. Arndt: Distribution of seats at the European Parliament Democratic political equality, pro-
tection of diversity and the enlargement process. In: The Emerging Constitutional Law of the European Union
German and Polish Perspectives, Beiträge zum ausländischen öffentlichen Recht und Völkerrecht 163, 2003, pp.
93-115. (5) F. Arndt: Ausrechnen statt aushandeln: Rationalitätsgewinne durch ein formalisiertes Modell für die
Bestimmung der Zusammensetzung des Europäischen Parlaments (with an English summary). Zeitschrift für aus-
ländisches öffentliches Recht und Völkerrecht Heidelberg Journal of International Law 68, 2008, pp. 247-279.
4
An efficient way to determine the divisor is discussed, for example, in Sect. 4.6 of F. Pukelsheim: Proportional
Representation Apportionment Methods and Their Applications. With a Foreword by Andrew Duff MEP. Cham,
2014 (www.uni-augsburg.de/pukelsheim/2014a-FrontMatter.pdf).
The Composition of the European Parliament
7
Power Compromise
The Power Compromise is a variant of the Cambridge Compromise that refers not to original
population figures, but to power-adjusted population units. It may be worded as follows:
Every Member State is assigned a common number of base seats. The remaining
seats are allocated proportionately to adjusted population units (that is, the
population figures raised to a common power) using the divisor method with upward
rounding. In the case of the current EP, the number of base seats, the power, and
the divisor are determined so that the least populous Member State is allocated 6
seats, the most populous is allocated just 96 seats, and the size of the EP is 751.
For instance, in Table 2 the method proceeds as follows:
Every Member State is assigned 5 base seats, plus one seat per 254 500 adjusted
population units or part thereof, where the adjusted units are obtained by raising the
population figures to the power 0.93.
The power 0.93 is determined so that the most populous Member State is allocated just 96
seats.
5
The divisor 254 500 is determined so that the 28 Member States altogether are
allocated 751 seats. The base seat assignment in Table 2 is identical to that of Table 1,
namely 5. The presence of these allocation keys is dictated by the goal to satisfy the
requirements of primary and secondary Union law as discussed below.
Tables 2, 4, 6, 7 illustrate the Power Compromise. The number of base seats varies, with
Tables 2 and 6 using 5 base seats, and Tables 4 and 7 using 4 base seats.
In all seven Tables, the number of seats remaining for proportional allocation depends on
the numbers of base seats (4 or 5) and of Member States (28 or 27), and on the EP size
under consideration (751 or 678 or 723 seats).
Assessment by primary Union law
Primary Union Law, as set forth in the Treaty on European Union (TEU), lays conditions
upon possible allocation methods.
6
Of particular relevance are the following requirements
which we rearrange and paraphrase to ease cross-referencing in this briefing.
1. Citizens are directly represented in the EP (Art. 10(2) TEU).
2. The EP shall be composed of representatives of the Union’s citizens (Art. 14(2)
TEU).
3. Representation of citizens shall be degressively proportional (Art. 14(2) TEU).
4. The size of the EP shall not exceed 751 seats (Art. 14(2) TEU).
5. Every Member State shall be allocated at least 6 seats (Art. 14(2) TEU).
6. Every Member State shall be allocated at most 96 seats (Art. 14(2) TEU).
There is a potential ambiguity in the term ‘‘Member State’’ over whether it refers to govern-
ment or to people. When “Member State” is interpreted to mean “government”, Art. 10(2)
TEU decrees that the appropriate representative body is the European Council and the
Council, rather than the EP. As far as the composition of the EP is concerned, the term
“Member State” means people, that is, a Member State’s citizenry.
The Cambridge Compromise complies perfectly well with requirements 1 and 2. The initial
assignment of base seats to a Member State secures the representation of its citizenry as a
whole. The subsequent proportional allocation of the remaining seats represents the
5
Generally there are several powers that guarantee 96 seats for the most populous Member States. For the data in
Table 2 five powers serve the purpose: 0.93, 0.932, 0.935, 0.937, 0.94. The smallest power (0.93) conforms best
to the principle of degressive proportionality. Powers larger than 0.93 involve the transfer of a seat from a less
populous Member State to a more populous Member State: for 0.932 from Lithuania to Poland, for 0.935 from
Poland to United Kingdom, for 0.937 from the Netherlands to Poland, and for 0.94 from Portugal to Italy. The
selection of the smallest power is expressed by saying that the most populous Member State realizes “just96
seats. An efficient algorithm to determine the power is described in Grimmett et al., note 3; see also Sect. 12.8 of
Pukelsheim, note 4. The algorithm is implemented in the free software Bazi (www.uni-augsburg.de/bazi/).
6
OJ C 326, 26.10.2012, pp. 1345 (http://www.uni-augsburg.de/bazi/OJ/2012C326p13.pdf).
Policy Department C: Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
8
citizens as individuals. Degressive proportionality (requirement 3) will be dealt with in
greater detail in Section 3 below. Requirements 46 are numerical restrictions which are
clearly fulfilled.
In contrast, it is harder to fit the Power Compromise within the framework of require-
ments 1 and 2. Requirement 1 calls for a direct representation of citizens. At the stage of
proportional allocation, the Power Compromise allocates the remaining seats in a manner
proportional to “population units” which are a power of the population figures. That is,
direct population figures are replaced by transformed quantities. While the invocation of a
transformation signals a deviation from the principle of direct representation, it may be
justified by the principle of degressive representation.
There is a tension between the principles of direct representation (requirement 1) and of
degressive representation (requirement 3), each of which is stipulated by primary Union
law. Requirement 1 supports an allocation proportional to population, whereas require-
ment 3 favours an allocation giving some priority to smaller states. The Cambridge
Compromise may be viewed as prioritizing direct representation over degressivity. In
contrast, the Power Compromise allows greater degressivity, but at some cost to direct
representation.
The two methods yield seat allocations that become increasingly identical as the power
parameter becomes closer to unity. They coincide when the power equals unity, and this
could occur in the future. For instance, if in Table 2 the German population were to decline
by five million to 77 064 489 (with other populations unchanged), the Power Compromise
yields power 1 and is hence identical to the Cambridge Compromise. This possibility of
future coincidence of the two methods mitigates the marginal disregard by the Power
Compromise of the principle of direct representation.
Assessment by secondary Union law
The extended deliberations of the EP on its composition have led to detailed specifications
that have found their way into Art. 1 of the 2013 European Council Decision mentioned
above:
7. Any more populous Member State shall be allocated at least as many seats as any
less populous Member State.
8. The least populous Member State shall be allocated 6 seats.
9. The most populous Member State shall be allocated 96 seats.
10. The principle of degressive proportionality shall require decreasing representation
ratios when passing from a more populous Member State to a less populous Member
State, where the representation ratio of a Member State is defined to be the ratio of
its population figure relative to its number of seats before rounding.
These requirements are satisfied by the Cambridge Compromise as well as by the Power
Compromise. Tables 1–7 include columns labelled “Repr. Ratio” in witness of degressive
proportionality (requirement 10).
Requirement 9 insists on allocations that achieve the maximum of 96 seats. The
requirement can be met with the current data, but it has the potential to breed conflict. For
instance, if in Table 1 the German population were to be seven million fewer, namely
75 064 489 (with other population figures unchanged), the Cambridge Compromise would
allocate 94 seats to Germany. A forced allocation of 96 seats would violate degressive
proportionality (requirement 3). Council has reasoned that requirements 8 and 9 reflect as
closely as possible the spectrum of populations-sizes of Member States, but this reasoning
is invalid in general.
The Cambridge Compromise results in an increased bunching of Member States near the
maximum of 96 seats (as permitted by requirement 9). While this does not threaten
degressive proportionality, it disadvantages citizens of any capped Member State relative to
The Composition of the European Parliament
9
those of other large States. In contrast, the seat allocation of the Power Compromise is
smoother across its entire range, and in particular at the upper end.
2. FURTHER PROPOSALS
In the literature one can find other proposals on how to determine the composition of the
EP. The topic received renewed attention during the 2003 Convention on the Future of
Europe. Since then the Treaty of Lisbon entered into force and the 2013 European Council
decision decreed further details. The parts that are relevant for the composition of the EP
are enunciated in requirements 110 above. Of course past literature could not anticipate
these later requirements. Therefore one has to be careful when relating past sample
allocations with current settings.
Some authors proposed to refer the allocation not only to population figures, but also to
gross domestic product.
7
We believe that this reference base can no longer be upheld in
view of requirements 12. The Members of the EP represent human beings, not economic
performance.
Other approaches make use of adjusted population units as does the Power Compromise,
but in a different fashion. Rather than raising a population figure N to a power c (in
Table 2: N
c
= N
0.93
) they advocate other transformations. The parabolic method subtracts a
multiple of the squared population: N cN
2
; the hyperbolic method subtracts a multiple of
the inverse population N c/N.
8
The coefficient c is contingent on the type of transforma-
tion chosen and must be calculated from the given population figures.
The challenge is not mathematical multitude, but constitutional adequacy. The
more sophisticated the adjustment function, the harder is the proof of its closeness to the
principles of primary and secondary Union law, and the more opaque is the method.
Moreover the Cambridge Compromise and the Power Compromise yield seat allocations
which for many data sets sandwich the allocations of other methods. For this reason we
restrict our briefing to these two methods which can be firmly justified by the legal
principles of the Union.
3. DEGRESSIVE PROPORTIONALITY
The oxymoron of “degressive proportionality” has a long tradition in the debates of
the EP. One may have degressive representation, proportional representation, or
progressive representation just as one may have degressive taxation, proportional taxation,
or progressive taxation. “Degressive proportionality”, however, is a paradoxical concept.
The notion is presented as a manifestation of solidarity in a 2007 text adopted by the EP:
9
The more populous States agree to be under-represented in order to allow the
less populous States to be represented better.
The 2007 resolution included an attempted specification of degressive proportionality, which
has since been recognized as a potential contradiction. Meanwhile the abstract principle of
degressive proportionality (requirement 3) has been given a concrete specification capable
of practical implementation (requirement 10).
The implementation of degressive proportionality is challenging because the meanings of
“citizens” in requirements 2 and 3 differ significantly even though both requirements appear
7
C. Bertini / G. Gambarelli / I. Stach: Apportionment strategies for the European Parliament. Homo Oeconomicus
22, 2005, pp. 589-604.
8
See, for example, V. Ramírez / A. Palomares / M.L. Márquez: Degressively proportional methods for the allotment
of the European Parliament Seats amongst the EU Member States. In: B. Simeone / F. Pukelsheim (Editors):
Mathematics and Democracy Recent Advances in Voting Systems and Collective Choice. Berlin, 2006, pp. 205
220. Or W. Słomczyński / K. Życzkowski: Mathematical aspects of degressive proportionality. Mathematical Social
Sciences 63, 2012, pp. 94-101. Note that the latter authors introduce in their equation (10) a base + power
allocation method which is close to, but not identical with the Power Compromise of the present briefing.
9
OJ C 227 E, 4.9.2008, pp. 132-138, no. 5 (http://www.uni-augsburg.de/bazi/OJ/2008C227Ep132.pdf).
Policy Department C: Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
10
in the same section of Art. 14 TEU. Reference to “Union citizens” (requirement 2) appears
to place all citizens on an equal footing. However, the principle of degressive
proportionality (requirement 3) discriminates the “citizens” by Member States. The citizens
of more populous Member States agree to be under-represented in order to allow the
citizens of less populous Member States to be represented better.
The Cambridge Compromise achieves degressive proportionality without distorting the
meaning of “citizens” beyond the minimum. It does so in each of its two stages. The first
stage of assigning base seats treats all Member States alike. This is extremely degressive
since it neglects population figures entirely. The second stage of proportional allocation of
the remaining seats embodies a mild form of degressivity through the use of upward round-
ing. Upward rounding is known to introduce a slight bias in favour of the less populous
Member States.
10
This type of bias reinforces the effect of degressive proportionality.
In contrast the Power Compromise achieves degressive proportionality by interpreting the
term “citizens” in a rather broad sense. The method replaces lucent population figures
which count concrete citizens by arcane population units which measure abstract units.
In Table 2, Malta’s population of 434 403 citizens is transformed to 175 082 population
units. Does this mean that only forty percent of the citizenry is accounted for?
11
Or forty
percent of each citizen? Neither interpretation seems profitable; the interim power-
adjustments remain obscure. Their justification lies in the final result which thereby
achieves a higher degree of degressivity.
4. POPULATION CRITERION
How does one determine the number of citizens in a Member State? Whom does one count?
These questions are fundamental to requirements 13. They demand quick practical
answers, while also inviting more principled reflections.
Available population figures are those decreed annually by Council Decision for the qualified
majority voting (QMV) rule in the Council of Ministers. The figures for the calendar year
2017 provide the input data for our tables.
12
The corresponding columns are labelled
“QMV2017”.
Since the Council and the EP are constitutional organs of the European Union with joint
governance responsibility, we are compelled to the recommendation that the two institu-
tions employ the same population data.
We return to the questions above. Presumably everybody would endorse the aim that
Every individual who qualifies as a “citizen” in the sense of requirements 13 shall
be counted at least once and at most once. That is, he or she shall be counted
exactly once.
This modest aim is challenging to achieve, considering that the data are gathered by a host
of domestic statistical offices before being communicated to Eurostat. To this end it seems
efficient and appropriate to continue to base all population figures on the internationally
(UN) approved notion of “total resident population”.
5. INTER-INSTITUTIONAL BALANCE
Population figures feature not only in the seat allocation of the EP, but also in the qualified
majority voting rule of the Council. A group of Member States constitutes a qualified
majority provided the group consists of at least 55 percent of all Member States (that is, at
10
See Chap. 7 in Pukelsheim, note 4. The counterpart of the divisor method with upward rounding is the divisor
method with downward rounding. The latter is also known as the D’Hondt method. The D’Hondt method is biased
in favour of stronger parties at the expense of weaker parties, which explains much of its widespread usage.
11
175 082 is 40.3 percent of 434 403.
12
OJ L 348, 12.12.2016, pp. 2729 (www.uni-augsburg.de/bazi/OJ/2016L348p27.pdf). See www.uni-augsburg.de/
bazi/literature.html#QMV-Pop for links to the QMV population figures prior to 2017.
The Composition of the European Parliament
11
least 16 Member States out of 28) and the Member States in the group represent at least
65 percent of the Union’s population. This decision rule is known as the double-majority
voting rule.
There is an established mathematical framework for the evaluation of fairness within a
qualified majority voting system. It focuses on two quantities: the decision power of a
Member State, and the indirect decision power of a Union citizen.
13
The indirect
decision power of a Union citizen is determined from the decision power of his or her
Member State by dividing the latter by the square root of the Member State’s population
figure. It transpires that the double-majority voting rule leads to an uneven distribution of
the indirect decision powers of the Union citizens. Citizens from middle-sized Member
States have slightly less power than citizens from Member States that are smaller (due to
the 55 percent clause) or larger (due to the 65 percent clause).
14
The Jagiellonian Compromise is a qualified majority voting rule that awards all Union
citizens an equal indirect decision power. It assigns to each Member State a voting weight
that is defined to be the square root of its population figure. Furthermore it introduces a
quota. The Jagiellonian quota is defined to be the average of the square root of the popu-
lation total and the sum of the voting weights.
15
According to the Jagiellonian Compromise
a group of Member States qualifies as a majority provided the sum of their voting weights
meets or exceeds the quota.
In terms of conceptual analysis the Jagiellonian Compromise is unique in its transparency.
It turns out that the decision power of a Member State is practically the same as its
normalized voting weight, that is, its voting weight divided by the voting weight total.
16
As
a consequence the indirect decision power of every citizen attains the same value. Numeri-
cally this cannot be but a tiny quantity in a Union of half a billion of citizens. The principal
conclusion is conceptual:
The Jagiellonian Compromise awards to all Union citizens the same and equal
power to participate, indirectly via their governments, in Council’s decisions.
Table 8 illustrates the application of the Jagiellonian Compromise to the current Council,
Table 9 to a Council without UK.
6. RECOMMENDATIONS
We believe that the Union’s institutions will be served best by the adoption of the Cam-
bridge Compromise for the composition of the EP, and the Jagiellonian Compromise for the
qualified majority voting rule in the Council. These are two independent recommendations.
There is added strength in the above recommendations when viewed as a pair. The Cam-
bridge Compromise would transfer some of the representative weight from middle-sized
Member States to smaller and larger Member States. The Jagiellonian Compromise would
transfer some of the decision power from smaller and larger Member States to middle-sized
13
In repeated decision-making systems the term “a priori decision power” denotes the probability that the partici-
pant’s vote is critical for adopting an act. For large populations the indirect decision power of a citizen behaves
proportionally to the quotient of the decision power of his or her Member State and the square root of the Member
State’s population figure. See, for example, equation (8) in D. Leech / H. Aziz: The double majority voting rule of
the EU Reform Treaty as a democratic ideal for an enlarging Union: An appraisal using voting power analysis. In:
M. Cichocki / K. Życzkowski (Editors): Institutional Design and Voting Power in the European Union. London, 2010,
pp. 5973. For the double-majority voting rule, the decision powers of the Member States were kindly provided by
Dan Felsenthal (Jerusalem) and Dennis Leech (London).
14
See also Figure 14.1 in F. Pukelsheim: Putting citizens first: Representation and power in the European Union. In
Cichocki / Życzkowski, note 13, pp. 235–253 (www.uni-augsburg.de/pukelsheim/2010a.pdf).
15
W. Słomczyński / K. Życzkowski: Penrose voting system and optimal quota. Acta Physica Polonica B 37, 2006,
pp. 31333143 (chaos.if.uj.edu.pl/~karol/pdf/SZapp06.pdf).
16
For the Jagiellonian Compromise, the Member States’ decision powers were calculated using the program ipgenf on
the website Computer Algorithms for Voting Power Analysis of Dennis Leech and Richard Leech (homepages.
warwick.ac.uk/~ecaae/). However, this specific decision rule makes computers superfluous since a Member State’s
decision power is practically equal to the normalized voting weight (=voting weight / total of all voting weights).
Sample calculation in Table 8 for Austria: 2 952 / 99 012 = 2.98 percent.
Policy Department C: Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
12
Member States. The transfer directions have a balancing effect, and thus the pair is in
equilibrium. Each of these transfers is soundly rooted in the constitutional directive to put
citizens first.
If the full Cambridge Compromise is viewed as being too insensitive to the current composi-
tion of the EP, the Power Compromise may be considered as an interim measure. If the
latter were to be adopted for the 2019 allocation, our recommendation of the Jagiellonian
Compromise would still stand.
We recommend that the adopted allocation method be firmly rooted in primary and second-
ary Union law, and that such consideration should receive prominent emphasis. Neither the
Cambridge Compromise nor the Power Compromise requires a change to primary Union law.
Moreover both methods are compatible with the establishment of a joint constituency, as
supported by the EP in a 2015 vote.
17
7. SEAT ALLOCATION TABLES FOR THE 2019 EP
Seven tables are presented to illustrate how the Cambridge Compromise (CC) and the
Power Compromise (PC) apply to various scenarios.
Table 1 (CC-28-751) and Table 2 (PC-28-751) deal with the current Union of 28 Member
States that is, including the UK and maintain the current EP size of 751 seats.
Table 3 (CC-27-751) and Table 4 (PC-27-751) deal with a Union of 27 Member States that
is, without the UK and an EP of continuing size of 751 seats.
Table 5 (CC-27-678) and Table 6 (PC-27-678) are based on the assumption that, upon
Brexit, the 73 UK seats are left vacant. This option reduces the EP size to 678 seats.
All tables include a final column exhibiting the differences between the proposed seat
allocations and the 2014 status quo seats. These differences are sometimes appreciable.
We emphasize that the 2014 allocation is a patchwork without systematic rationale, and
that it fails to satisfy the principle of degressive proportionality. It is a challenging
undertaking to achieve a progression towards a representative equilibrium among Union
citizens. Once a start is made and the inherited unevenness is reduced, future re-
allocations are solely reflective of natural population dynamics.
Of the six tables, only Table 4 (PC-27-751) does not imply any reduction in the number of
seats of a Member State assigned to it in 2014. That is, no Member State has to relinquish
any of its current seats. We note that a no-loss situation emerges also with fewer seats.
The smallest EP size to achieve this effect, with the Power Compromise and with the 2017
population figures, is 723 seats.
Table 7 (PC-27-723) displays the allocation of 723 EP seats between the 27 Member States
(without UK) that emerges when using the Power Compromise.
17
European Parliament resolution of 11 November 2015 on the reform of the electoral law of the European Union
(2015/2035(INL)) (www.uni-augsburg.de/bazi/OJ/20xxCyyEpzz.pdf).
.
The Composition of the European Parliament
13
Table 1: Cambridge Compromise, including UK
CC-28-751
QMV2017
Seats
Repr.Ratio
2014
Diff.
Germany
82 064 489
96
854 838
96
0
France
66 661 621
84
795 520
74
10
United Kingdom
65 341 183
83
794 562
73
10
Italy
61 302 519
78
791 392
73
5
Spain
46 438 422
60
775 373
54
6
Poland
37 967 209
50
761 194
51
-1
Romania
19 759 968
29
696 830
32
-3
The Netherlands
17 235 349
26
679 286
26
0
Belgium
11 289 853
19
615 419
21
-2
Greece
10 793 526
18
607 802
21
-3
Czech Republic
10 445 783
18
602 157
21
-3
Portugal
10 341 330
18
600 410
21
-3
Sweden
9 998 000
17
594 483
21
-4
Hungary
9 830 485
17
591 487
20
-3
Austria
8 711 500
16
569 480
18
-2
Bulgaria
7 153 784
14
531 642
17
-3
Denmark
5 700 917
12
485 653
13
-1
Finland
5 465 408
12
476 899
13
-1
Slovakia
5 407 910
12
474 698
13
-1
Ireland
4 664 156
11
443 648
11
0
Croatia
4 190 669
10
421 024
11
-1
Lithuania
2 888 558
9
343 289
11
-2
Slovenia
2 064 188
8
277 447
8
0
Latvia
1 968 957
8
268 713
8
0
Estonia
1 315 944
7
200 739
6
1
Cyprus
848 319
7
141 322
6
1
Luxembourg
576 249
6
101 432
6
0
Malta
434 403
6
78 789
6
0
Sum (Divisor)
510 860 699
751
751
±33
Notes:
Cambridge Compromise:
Every Member State is assigned 5 base seats, plus one seat per 846 000 citizens or part thereof, with a
maximum cap of 96 seats.
Allocation Keys:
There are two allocation keys: the number of base sets (5) and the divisor (846 000). They are determined so
that so the least populous Member state is allocated 6 seats and the size of the EP is 751 seats.
Sample calculations for Malta:
Quotient = Base seats+(QMV2017/Divisor) = 5+0.5 = 5.5, rounded upwards to 6 seats
Representation Ratio = QMV2017/Quotient = 434 403 / (5 + 434 403 / 846 000) = 78 789
Maximum cap active only for Germany:
Quotient for Germany 5+97.003 = 102.003 is discarded and capped at 96 seats.
Verification of degressive proportionality:
Representation ratios decrease when passing from more populous to less populous Member States.
Column “Diff.” exhibits deviations of proposed “Seats” from “2014” seats. Altogether 33 seats are transferred
between middle-sized and larger or smaller Member States.
Policy Department C: Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
14
Table 2: Power Compromise, including UK
Notes:
Power Compromise:
Every Member State is assigned 5 base seats, plus one seat per 254 500 adjusted population units or part
thereof, where the adjusted units are obtained by raising the population figures to the power 0.93.
Allocation Keys:
There are three allocation keys: the number of base seats (5), the power (0.93), and the divisor (254 500).
They are determined so that the least populous Member State is allocated 6 seats, the most populous Member
State is allocated just 96 seats, and the size of the EP is 751 seats.
Sample calculations for Malta:
Adjusted population units = 434 403
0.93
= 175 082
Quotient = Base seats+(Adjusted/Divisor) = 5+0.7 = 5.7, rounded upwards to 6 seats
Representation Ratio = QMV2017/Quotient = 434 403 / (5 + 434 403
0.93
/ 254 500) = 76 373
Maximum cap is automatic since it is built into determination of power 0.93.
Verification of degressive proportionality:
Representation ratios decrease when passing from more populous to less populous Member States.
Column “Diff.” exhibits deviations of proposed “Seats” from “2014” seats. Altogether 21 seats are transferred
between middle-sized and larger or smaller Member States.
PC-28-751
QMV2017
Adjusted
Quotient
Seats
Repr.Ratio
2014
Diff.
Germany
82 064 489
22 917 350
5+90.05
96
863 396
96
0
France
66 661 621
18 888 808
5+74.2
80
841 482
74
6
United Kingdom
65 341 183
18 540 605
5+72.9
78
839 310
73
5
Italy
61 302 519
17 472 492
5+68.7
74
832 302
73
1
Spain
46 438 422
13 495 719
5+53.03
59
800 271
54
5
Poland
37 967 209
11 190 515
5+43.97
49
775 306
51
-2
Romania
19 759 968
6 096 509
5+23.95
29
682 441
32
-3
The Netherlands
17 235 349
5 368 719
5+21.1
27
660 481
26
1
Belgium
11 289 853
3 622 431
5+14.2
20
586 988
21
-1
Greece
10 793 526
3 474 097
5+13.7
19
578 720
21
-2
Czech Republic
10 445 783
3 369 885
5+13.2
19
572 648
21
-2
Portugal
10 341 330
3 338 536
5+13.1
19
570 776
21
-2
Sweden
9 998 000
3 235 335
5+12.7
18
564 460
21
-3
Hungary
9 830 485
3 184 892
5+12.5
18
561 283
20
-2
Austria
8 711 500
2 846 338
5+11.2
17
538 277
18
-1
Bulgaria
7 153 784
2 369 836
5+9.3
15
499 854
17
-2
Denmark
5 700 917
1 918 795
5+7.5
13
454 638
13
0
Finland
5 465 408
1 844 969
5+7.2
13
446 178
13
0
Slovakia
5 407 910
1 826 911
5+7.2
13
444 056
13
0
Ireland
4 664 156
1 592 058
5+6.3
12
414 384
11
1
Croatia
4 190 669
1 441 198
5+5.7
11
393 016
11
0
Lithuania
2 888 558
1 019 608
5+4.01
10
320 726
11
-1
Slovenia
2 064 188
745 962
5+2.9
8
260 265
8
0
Latvia
1 968 957
713 904
5+2.8
8
252 265
8
0
Estonia
1 315 944
490 784
5+1.9
7
189 934
6
1
Cyprus
848 319
326 257
5+1.3
7
135 041
6
1
Luxembourg
576 249
227 702
5+0.9
6
97 757
6
0
Malta
434 403
175 082
5+0.7
6
76 373
6
0
Sum (Keys)
510 860 699
(0.93)
(254 500)
751
751
±21
The Composition of the European Parliament
15
Table 3: Cambridge Compromise, without UK and with 751 EP seats
Notes:
Cambridge Compromise:
Every Member State is assigned 5 base seats, plus one seat per 703 400 citizens or part thereof, with a
maximum cap of 96 seats.
Allocation Keys:
There are two allocation keys: the number of base sets (5) and the divisor (703 400). They are determined so
that so the least populous Member state is allocated 6 seats and the size of the EP is 751 seats.
Sample calculations for Malta:
Quotient = Base seats+(QMV2017/Divisor) = 5+0.6 = 5.6, rounded upwards to 6 seats
Representation Ratio = QMV2017/Quotient = 434 403 / (5 + 434 403 / 703 400) = 77 329
Maximum cap active for Germany and France:
Quotient for Germany 5+116.7 = 121.7 is discarded and capped at 96 seats.
Quotient for France 5+94.8 =99.8 is discarded and capped at 96 seats.
Verification of degressive proportionality:
Representation ratios decrease when passing from more populous to less populous Member States.
Column “Diff.” exhibits deviations of proposed “Seats” from “2014” seats. In addition to the reallocation of 73
former UK seats, 6 seats are transferred between middle-sized and larger or smaller Member States.
CC-27-751
QMV2017
Quotient
Seats
Repr.Ratio
2014
Diff.
Germany
82 064 489
5+116.7
96
854 838
96
0
France
66 661 621
5+94.8
96
694 392
74
22
Italy
61 302 519
5+87.2
93
665 235
73
20
Spain
46 438 422
5+66.02
72
653 879
54
18
Poland
37 967 209
5+53.98
59
643 766
51
8
Romania
19 759 968
5+28.1
34
597 121
32
2
The Netherlands
17 235 349
5+24.5
30
584 191
26
4
Belgium
11 289 853
5+16.1
22
536 325
21
1
Greece
10 793 526
5+15.3
21
530 530
21
0
Czech Republic
10 445 783
5+14.9
20
526 225
21
-1
Portugal
10 341 330
5+14.7
20
524 889
21
-1
Sweden
9 998 000
5+14.2
20
520 355
21
-1
Hungary
9 830 485
5+13.98
19
518 057
20
-1
Austria
8 711 500
5+12.4
18
501 097
18
0
Bulgaria
7 153 784
5+10.2
16
471 565
17
-1
Denmark
5 700 917
5+8.1
14
435 025
13
1
Finland
5 465 408
5+7.8
13
427 989
13
0
Slovakia
5 407 910
5+7.7
13
426 214
13
0
Ireland
4 664 156
5+6.6
12
401 015
11
1
Croatia
4 190 669
5+5.96
11
382 439
11
0
Lithuania
2 888 558
5+4.1
10
317 195
11
-1
Slovenia
2 064 188
5+2.9
8
260 151
8
0
Latvia
1 968 957
5+2.8
8
252 456
8
0
Estonia
1 315 944
5+1.9
7
191 526
6
1
Cyprus
848 319
5+1.2
7
136 693
6
1
Luxembourg
576 249
5+0.8
6
99 025
6
0
Malta
434 403
5+0.6
6
77 329
6
0
Sum (Divisor)
445 519 516
(703 400)
751
678
79-6
Policy Department C: Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
16
Table 4: Power Compromise, without UK and with 751 EP seats
Notes:
Power Compromise:
Every Member State is assigned 4 base seats, plus one seat per 14 360 adjusted population units or part
thereof, where the adjusted units are obtained by raising the population figures to the power 0.773.
Allocation Keys:
There are three allocation keys: the number of base seats (4), the power (0.773), and the divisor (14 360).
They are determined so that the least populous Member State is allocated 6 seats, the most populous Member
State is allocated just 96 seats, and the size of the EP is 751 seats.
Sample calculations for Malta:
Adjusted population units = 434 403
0.773
= 22 808
Quotient = Base seats+(Adjusted/Divisor) = 4+1.6 = 5.6, rounded upwards to 6 seats
Representation Ratio = QMV2017/Quotient = 434 403 / (4 + 434 403
0.773
/ 14 360) = 65 880
Maximum cap is automatic since it is built into determination of power 0.773.
Verification of degressive proportionality:
Representation ratios decrease when passing from more populous to less populous Member States.
Column “Diff.” exhibits deviations of proposed “Seats” from “2014” seats. With the reallocation of 73 former UK
seats no Member State has to relinquish any of its 2014 seats.
PC-27-751
QMV2017
Adjusted
Quotient
Seats
Repr.Ratio
2014
Diff.
Germany
82 064 489
1 311 119
4+91.3
96
849 331
96
0
France
66 661 621
1 116 493
4+77.8
82
802 940
74
8
Italy
61 302 519
1 046 455
4+72.9
77
784 646
73
4
Spain
46 438 422
844 299
4+58.8
63
725 593
54
9
Poland
37 967 209
722 575
4+50.3
55
684 163
51
4
Romania
19 759 968
436 157
4+30.4
35
556 946
32
3
The Netherlands
17 235 349
392 421
4+27.3
32
531 580
26
6
Belgium
11 289 853
282 962
4+19.7
24
455 719
21
3
Greece
10 793 526
273 297
4+19.03
24
447 895
21
3
Czech Republic
10 445 783
266 466
4+18.6
23
442 225
21
2
Portugal
10 341 330
264 404
4+18.4
23
440 491
21
2
Sweden
9 998 000
257 592
4+17.9
22
434 679
21
1
Hungary
9 830 485
254 250
4+17.7
22
431 781
20
2
Austria
8 711 500
231 575
4+16.1
21
411 255
18
3
Bulgaria
7 153 784
198 864
4+13.8
18
378 570
17
1
Denmark
5 700 917
166 857
4+11.6
16
342 188
13
3
Finland
5 465 408
161 504
4+11.2
16
335 588
13
3
Slovakia
5 407 910
160 189
4+11.2
16
333 942
13
3
Ireland
4 664 156
142 877
4+9.9
14
311 267
11
3
Croatia
4 190 669
131 530
4+9.2
14
295 295
11
3
Lithuania
2 888 558
98 652
4+6.9
11
242 860
11
0
Slovenia
2 064 188
76 085
4+5.3
10
200 078
8
2
Latvia
1 968 957
73 358
4+5.1
10
194 440
8
2
Estonia
1 315 944
53 724
4+3.7
8
150 319
6
2
Cyprus
848 319
38 263
4+2.7
7
110 547
6
1
Luxembourg
576 249
28 376
4+1.98
6
82 522
6
0
Malta
434 403
22 808
4+1.6
6
65 880
6
0
Sum (Keys)
445 519 516
(0.773)
(14 360)
751
678
73-0
The Composition of the European Parliament
17
Table 5: Cambridge Compromise, without UK and with 678 EP seats
Notes:
Cambridge Compromise:
Every Member State is assigned 5 base seats, plus one seat per 827 000 citizens or part thereof, with a
maximum cap of 96 seats.
Allocation Keys:
There are two allocation keys: the number of base sets (5) and the divisor (827 000). They are determined so
that so the least populous Member state is allocated 6 seats and the size of the EP is 678 seats.
Sample calculations for Malta:
Quotient = Base seats + (QMV2017/Divisor) = 5+0.5 = 5.5, rounded upwards to 6 seats
Representation Ratio = QMV2017/Quotient = 434 403 / (5 + 434 403 / 827 000) = 78 621
Maximum cap active only for Germany:
Quotient for Germany 5+99.2 = 104.2 is discarded and capped at 96 seats.
Verification of degressive proportionality:
Representation ratios decrease when passing from more populous to less populous Member States.
Column “Diff.” exhibits deviations of proposed “Seats” from “2014” seats. Altogether 29 seats are transferred
between middle-sized and larger or smaller Member States.
CC-27-678
QMV2017
Quotient
Seats
Repr.Ratio
2014
Diff.
Germany
82 064 489
5+99.2
96
854 838
96
0
France
66 661 621
5+80.6
86
778 698
74
12
Italy
61 302 519
5+74.1
80
774 742
73
7
Spain
46 438 422
5+56.2
62
759 383
54
8
Poland
37 967 209
5+45.9
51
745 778
51
0
Romania
19 759 968
5+23.9
29
683 888
32
-3
The Netherlands
17 235 349
5+20.8
26
666 982
26
0
Belgium
11 289 853
5+13.7
19
605 303
21
-2
Greece
10 793 526
5+13.1
19
597 932
21
-2
Czech Republic
10 445 783
5+12.6
18
592 469
21
-3
Portugal
10 341 330
5+12.5
18
590 777
21
-3
Sweden
9 998 000
5+12.1
18
585 038
21
-3
Hungary
9 830 485
5+11.9
17
582 136
20
-3
Austria
8 711 500
5+10.5
16
560 807
18
-2
Bulgaria
7 153 784
5+8.7
14
524 076
17
-3
Denmark
5 700 917
5+6.9
12
479 331
13
-1
Finland
5 465 408
5+6.6
12
470 802
13
-1
Slovakia
5 407 910
5+6.5
12
468 656
13
-1
Ireland
4 664 156
5+5.6
11
438 367
11
0
Croatia
4 190 669
5+5.1
11
416 265
11
0
Lithuania
2 888 558
5+3.5
9
340 118
11
-2
Slovenia
2 064 188
5+2.5
8
275 372
8
0
Latvia
1 968 957
5+2.4
8
266 766
8
0
Estonia
1 315 944
5+1.6
7
199 651
6
1
Cyprus
848 319
5+1.03
7
140 782
6
1
Luxembourg
576 249
5+0.7
6
101 153
6
0
Malta
434 403
5+0.5
6
78 621
6
0
Sum (Divisor)
445 519 516
(827 000)
678
678
±29
Policy Department C: Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
18
Table 6: Power Compromise, without UK and with 678 EP seats
Notes:
Power Compromise:
Every Member State is assigned 5 base seats, plus one seat per 211 700 adjusted population units or part
thereof, where the adjusted units are obtained by raising the population figures to the power 0.92.
Allocation Keys:
There are three allocation keys: the number of base seats (5), the power (0.92), and the divisor (211 700).
They are determined so that the least populous Member state is allocated 6 seats, the most populous Member
State is allocated just 96 seats, and the size of the EP is 678 seats.
Sample calculations for Malta:
Adjusted population units = 434 403
0.92
= 153 766
Quotient = Base seats+(Adjusted/Divisor) = 5+0.7 = 5.7, rounded upwards to 6 seats
Representation Ratio = QMV2017/Quotient = 434 403 / (5 + 434 403
0.92
/ 211 700)= 75 860
Maximum cap is automatic since it is built into determination of power 0.92.
Verification of degressive proportionality:
Representation ratios decrease when passing from more populous to less populous Member States.
Column “Diff.” exhibits deviations of proposed “Seats” from “2014” seats. Altogether 18 seats are transferred
between middle-sized and larger or smaller Member States.
PC-27-678
QMV2017
Adjusted
Quotient
Seats
Repr.Ratio
2014
Diff.
Germany
82 064 489
19 099 537
5+90.2
96
861 842
96
0
France
66 661 621
15 774 870
5+74.5
80
838 351
74
6
Italy
61 302 519
14 604 277
5+68.99
74
828 572
73
1
Spain
46 438 422
11 311 684
5+53.4
59
794 735
54
5
Poland
37 967 209
9 398 444
5+44.4
50
768 643
51
-1
Romania
19 759 968
5 153 750
5+24.3
30
673 377
32
-2
The
Netherlands
17 235 349
4 544 713
5+21.5
27
651 184
26
1
Belgium
11 289 853
3 079 450
5+14.5
20
577 596
21
-1
Greece
10 793 526
2 954 679
5+13.96
19
569 371
21
-2
Czech
Republic
10 445 783
2 866 987
5+13.5
19
563 337
21
-2
Portugal
10 341 330
2 840 601
5+13.4
19
561 478
21
-2
Sweden
9 998 000
2 753 722
5+13.01
19
555 208
21
-2
Hungary
9 830 485
2 711 246
5+12.8
18
552 057
20
-2
Austria
8 711 500
2 425 970
5+11.5
17
529 270
18
-1
Bulgaria
7 153 784
2 023 825
5+9.6
15
491 336
17
-2
Denmark
5 700 917
1 642 363
5+7.8
13
446 851
13
0
Finland
5 465 408
1 579 839
5+7.5
13
438 544
13
0
Slovakia
5 407 910
1 564 542
5+7.4
13
436 461
13
0
Ireland
4 664 156
1 365 436
5+6.4
12
407 355
11
1
Croatia
4 190 669
1 237 373
5+5.8
11
386 417
11
0
Lithuania
2 888 558
878 672
5+4.2
10
315 670
11
-1
Slovenia
2 064 188
645 014
5+3.05
9
256 522
8
1
Latvia
1 968 957
617 586
5+2.9
8
248 691
8
0
Estonia
1 315 944
426 283
5+2.01
8
187 627
6
2
Cyprus
848 319
284 626
5+1.3
7
133 710
6
1
Luxembourg
576 249
199 417
5+0.9
6
96 979
6
0
Malta
434 403
153 766
5+0.7
6
75 860
6
0
Sum (Keys)
445 519 516
(0.92)
(211 700)
678
678
±18
The Composition of the European Parliament
19
Table 7: Power Compromise, without UK and with 723 EP seats
PC-27-723
QMV2017
Adjusted
Quotient
Seats
Repr.Ratio
2014
Diff.
Germany
82 064 489
2 717 742
4+91.2
96
862 305
96
0
France
66 661 621
2 295 150
4+76.99
81
823 058
74
7
Italy
61 302 519
2 143 976
4+71.9
76
807 448
73
3
Spain
46 438 422
1 710 690
4+57.4
62
756 493
54
8
Poland
37 967 209
1 452 310
4+48.7
53
720 182
51
2
Romania
19 759 968
854 032
4+28.6
33
605 221
32
1
The
Netherlands
17 235 349
764 204
4+25.6
30
581 571
26
4
Belgium
11 289 853
541 796
4+18.2
23
509 126
21
2
Greece
10 793 526
522 350
4+17.5
22
501 496
21
1
Czech
Republic
10 445 783
508 627
4+17.1
22
495 947
21
1
Portugal
10 341 330
504 488
4+16.9
21
494 246
21
0
Sweden
9 998 000
490 828
4+16.5
21
488 536
21
0
Hungary
9 830 485
484 132
4+16.2
21
485 682
20
1
Austria
8 711 500
438 829
4+14.7
19
465 336
18
1
Bulgaria
7 153 784
373 885
4+12.5
17
432 455
17
0
Denmark
5 700 917
310 873
4+10.4
15
395 116
13
2
Finland
5 465 408
300 391
4+10.1
15
388 255
13
2
Slovakia
5 407 910
297 819
4+9.99
14
386 539
13
1
Ireland
4 664 156
264 066
4+8.9
13
362 735
11
2
Croatia
4 190 669
242 056
4+8.1
13
345 766
11
2
Lithuania
2 888 558
178 868
4+6.0003
11
288 848
11
0
Slovenia
2 064 188
136 110
4+4.6
9
240 977
8
1
Latvia
1 968 957
130 983
4+4.4
9
234 569
8
1
Estonia
1 315 944
94 393
4+3.2
8
183 625
6
2
Cyprus
848 319
66 057
4+2.2
7
136 475
6
1
Luxembourg
576 249
48 237
4+1.6
6
102 569
6
0
Malta
434 403
38 336
4+1.3
6
82 180
6
0
Sum (Keys)
445 519 516
(0.813)
(29 810)
723
678
45-0
Notes:
Power Compromise:
Every Member State is assigned 4 base seats, plus one seat per 29 810 adjusted population units or part
thereof, where the adjusted units are obtained by raising the population figures to the power 0.813.
Allocation Keys:
There are three allocation keys: the number of base seats (4), the power (0.813), and the divisor (29 810).
They are determined so that the least populous Member state is allocated 6 seats, the most populous Member
State is allocated just 96 seats, and the size of the EP is 723 seats.
Sample calculations for Malta:
Adjusted population units = 434 403
0.813
= 38 336
Quotient = Base seats+(Adjusted/Divisor) = 4+1.3 = 5.3, rounded upwards to 6 seats
Representation Ratio = QMV2017/Quotient = 434 403 / (4 + 434 403
0.813
/ 29 810) = 82 180
Maximum cap is automatic since it is built into determination of power 0.813.
Verification of degressive proportionality:
Representation ratios decrease when passing from more populous to less populous Member States.
Column “Diff.” exhibits deviations of proposed “Seats” from “2014” seats. With the reallocation of 45 of the former
UK seats no Member State has to relinquish any of its 2014 seats.
Policy Department C: Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
20
Table 8 : Jagiellonian Compromise, including UK
Notes:
Jagiellonian Compromise:
A group of Member States constitutes a qualified majority provided the sum of their voting weights meets or
exceeds the quota 60 807.
System keys:
A Member State’s voting weight is the square root of its population figure, rounded to the nearest whole
number.
The quota 60 807 is the average of the square root of the population total (510 860 699
0.5
= 22 602.2) and the
sum of the voting weights (99 012), rounded upwards.
System merits:
The decision power of a Member State is identical to the percentage voting weight.
The indirect decision powers of all Union citizens are equal.
Column “Diff.” exhibits the deviations of the “Decision Power” of the proposed Jagiellonian Compromise from the
“DM2017” decision power of the double-majority voting rule in 2017. A total of 6.81 percent decision power is
transferred between middle-sized and larger or smaller Member States.
JagCom-28
QMV2017
Voting Weight
Decision Power
DM2017
Diff.
Germany
82 064 489
9 059
9.13
10.25
-1.12
France
66 661 621
8 165
8.25
8.44
-0.19
United Kingdom
65 341 183
8 083
8.17
8.29
-0.12
Italy
61 302 519
7 830
7.91
7.86
0.05
Spain
46 438 422
6 815
6.89
6.18
0.71
Poland
37 967 209
6 162
6.23
5.07
1.16
Romania
19 759 968
4 445
4.49
3.75
0.74
The Netherlands
17 235 349
4 152
4.19
3.49
0.70
Belgium
11 289 853
3 360
3.39
2.89
0.50
Greece
10 793 526
3 285
3.32
2.85
0.47
Czech Republic
10 445 783
3 232
3.26
2.81
0.45
Portugal
10 341 330
3 216
3.25
2.80
0.45
Sweden
9 998 000
3 162
3.19
2.77
0.42
Hungary
9 830 485
3 135
3.17
2.75
0.42
Austria
8 711 500
2 952
2.98
2.64
0.34
Bulgaria
7 153 784
2 675
2.70
2.48
0.22
Denmark
5 700 917
2 388
2.41
2.33
0.08
Finland
5 465 408
2 338
2.36
2.31
0.05
Slovakia
5 407 910
2 325
2.35
2.30
0.05
Ireland
4 664 156
2 160
2.18
2.23
-0.05
Croatia
4 190 669
2 047
2.07
2.18
-0.11
Lithuania
2 888 558
1 700
1.72
2.05
-0.33
Slovenia
2 064 188
1 437
1.45
1.97
-0.52
Latvia
1 968 957
1 403
1.42
1.96
-0.54
Estonia
1 315 944
1 147
1.16
1.89
-0.73
Cyprus
848 319
921
0.93
1.84
-0.91
Luxembourg
576 249
759
0.77
1.82
-1.05
Malta
434 403
659
0.66
1.80
-1.14
Sum
510 860 699
99 012
100.00
100.00
±6.81
Quota
60 807
61.41
The Composition of the European Parliament
21
Table 9 : Jagiellonian Compromise, without UK
Notes:
Jagiellonian Compromise:
A group of Member States constitutes a qualified majority provided the sum of their voting weights meets or
exceeds the quota 56 019.
System keys:
A Member State’s voting weight is the square root of its population figure, rounded to the nearest whole
number.
The quota 56 019 is the average of the square root of the population total (445 519 516
0.5
= 21 107.3) and the
sum of the voting weights (90 929), rounded upwards.
System merits:
The decision power of a Member State is identical to the percentage voting weight.
The indirect decision powers of all Union citizens are equal.
Column “Diff.” exhibits the deviations of the “Decision Power” of the proposed Jagiellonian Compromise from the
“DM2017” decision power of the double-majority voting rule in 2017. A total of 7.77 percent decision power is
transferred between middle-sized and larger or smaller Member States.
JagCom-27
QMV2017
Voting Weight
Decision Power
DM2017
Diff.
Germany
82 064 489
9 059
9.94
11.98
-2.04
France
66 661 621
8 165
8.98
9.95
-0.97
Italy
61 302 519
7 830
8.62
9.18
-0.56
Spain
46 438 422
6 815
7.51
7.62
-0.11
Poland
37 967 209
6 162
6.79
6.49
0.30
Romania
19 759 968
4 445
4.89
4.00
0.89
The Netherlands
17 235 349
4 152
4.57
3.71
0.86
Belgium
11 289 853
3 360
3.70
3.02
0.68
Greece
10 793 526
3 285
3.61
2.96
0.65
Czech Republic
10 445 783
3 232
3.55
2.92
0.63
Portugal
10 341 330
3 216
3.54
2.91
0.63
Sweden
9 998 000
3 162
3.48
2.87
0.61
Hungary
9 830 485
3 135
3.45
2.85
0.60
Austria
8 711 500
2 952
3.25
2.71
0.54
Bulgaria
7 153 784
2 675
2.94
2.53
0.41
Denmark
5 700 917
2 388
2.62
2.35
0.27
Finland
5 465 408
2 338
2.57
2.33
0.24
Slovakia
5 407 910
2 325
2.56
2.32
0.24
Ireland
4 664 156
2 160
2.37
2.23
0.14
Croatia
4 190 669
2 047
2.25
2.17
0.08
Lithuania
2 888 558
1 700
1.87
2.02
-0.15
Slovenia
2 064 188
1 437
1.58
1.92
-0.34
Latvia
1 968 957
1 403
1.54
1.90
-0.36
Estonia
1 315 944
1 147
1.26
1.83
-0.57
Cyprus
848 319
921
1.01
1.77
-0.76
Luxembourg
576 249
759
0.83
1.74
-0.91
Malta
434 403
659
0.72
1.72
-1.00
Sum
445 519 516
90 929
100.00
100.00
±7.77
Quota
56 019
61.61
Policy Department C: Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
22
The Composition of the European Parliament
THE r-DP METHODS TO ALLOCATE THE EP SEATS TO
MEMBER STATES
Prof. Victoriano RAMÍREZ GONZÁLEZ
KEY FINDINGS
The concept of degressive proportionality, (henceforth DP), introduced by the
Lamassoure-Severin report, has a very broad meaning. For example, allocating
26 seats for each of the 28 states fulfils the requirements of the Treaty of
Lisbon. Even if the least populous country gets a minimum 6 seats and the
most populous 96 seats, it is possible to set up many different allocations
which can also give a wide range of results for the same state.
This paper proposes limiting the DP concept because MEPs on some occasions
vote on the basis of national preferences and on other occasions vote on the
basis of ideological affinity. Depending on whether a greater influence of
national preferences or ideology is desired, we can use one from a series of
parametric methods. This paper proposes allocating half of the seats in the
EP in proportion to Member States’ populations (ideological affinity) the
other half in proportion to the square root of their populations (and
national preferences), rounding up with the Adams method and without
minimum or maximum limitations. The minimum and maximum limitations of 6
and 96, respectively, are included later in the formulas.
The current EP composition contains allocations to some states that contradict
DP, as for example, when comparing the seats allocated to Germany with
those allocated to France, UK or Spain. A new composition of the EP must
reverse this situation, whereby either Germany’s representation will have to
decrease or the other Member States’ increase (or both).
On the other hand, Hungary has 21 MEPs and Sweden has 20, but Hungary
has declined in population and Sweden has increased and surpassed Hungary,
so these allocations cannot be maintained in the future because they
contradict the Lisbon Treaty.
Likewise, Lithuania which currently has a population of less than 3 million and
Ireland with more than 4.5 million, both have 11 MEPs. This unbalanced
situation is unreasonable.
The formula to be adopted should not differ significantly from the current one,
with the exception of the previously noted inconsistencies.
1. INTRODUCTION
From the very beginning of the EP’s existence up until the present, the seat allocation for
each EU Member State has always been determined through negotiations, so that after
every Union enlargement, or when a state’s population changes significantly, new
negotiations are required.
The need for a formula to distribute seats has been frequently raised over the last decades.
For example, some scholars have noted that there is neither a formula to determine the
Policy Department for Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
24
vote weight of each State on the Council of the EU nor a formula to calculate the number of
seats in Parliament
1
.
The basic concept in degressive proportionality consists of assigning fewer seats to larger
states than their corresponding proportion, in order to assign more seats to smaller
states. Of course a country that is more populous than another cannot have fewer
representatives.
In 2007, the then EP vice-president Jacek Saryusz-Wolski proposed a meeting in order to
develop formulas for allocating EP seats and also to determine the members of the
European Commission. The meeting was organised by Marek A. Cichocki and Karol
Życzkowski in the Natolin European Centre in Warsaw. The contributions presented during
that meeting were published in a book and, though at that time the concept of degressive
proportionality was not rigorously defined, the book contains some papers that propose
degressively proportional distributions which meet the established limitations. This book
also contains other articles that recommend different voting systems for the Council of the
European Union
2
.
Also in 2007, two Members of the European Parliament Alain Lamassoure and Adrian
Severin rigorously defined the term “degressive proportionality” which is included in a
resolution of the EP
3
. Specifically, the meaning adopted was that the ratio between the
population and the number of seats of each Member State must be larger for the more
populous state, when any two states are compared.
However, this definition does not imply a particular method of seat allocation in the EP.
That is why, after the 2009 elections, Andrew Duff, MEP and member of the AFCO
Committee of the EP, tried to obtain a formula to distribute EP seats among EU Member
States. To this end, he promoted a meeting of electoral systems researchers at the
University of Cambridge. The result of this meeting was a Report for the EU called the
Cambridge Compromise (or CamCom)
4
. The Cambridge Compromise agrees on a
somewhat more flexible definition of degressive proportionality (considering the number of
seats before rounding, to obtain the ratio between population and seats). Finally, the Report
provided a simple, transparent and durable formula for the distribution of seats in the EP.
The journal Mathematical Social Science echoed the difficulty of the problem and published
a special issue
5
, in which many researchers presented new proposals for allocating seats in
the EP.
Many other articles have been written, before and after the cited events; however the EP’s
acceptance of a particular method is still pending. The composition of the EP for the period
2014-2019 had to be agreed by negotiation in which MEPs Gualtieri, R. and Trzaskowski, R.
proposed a criterion for seat distribution: "Nobody gains seats and nobody loses more than
one".
6
They also achieved a pragmatic solutionfor the 2014-2019 parliamentary term,
which was finally approved although it does not fully comply with the Lisbon Treaty
provisions.
1
Hosli, MO. and Machover, M (2004) The Nice Treaty and Voting Rules in the Council: A Reply to Moberg,
Journal of Common Market Studies 42(3): 497521.
2
Słomczyński, W. and Życzkowski K., 2010. Jagiellonian Compromise: an alternative voting system for the
Council of the European Union, in Cichocki MA and Życzkowski K. (eds) (2010) Design and Voting Power in the
European Union. Farnham: Ashgate Publishing Limited, pp. 43-57.
3
Lamassoure A. and Severin A. (2007): A proposal to amend the Treaty provisions concerning the composition of
the European Parliament. Brussels: Draft Explanatory statement, 31 August 2007. Available at:
http://www.europarl.europa.eu/sides/ getDoc.do?pubRef= //EP//NONSGML+REPORT+A6-2007-
0351+0+DOC+PDF+V0//EN.
4
Grimmett, G., Laslier, JF, Pukelsheim, F, Ramírez-González, V, Rose, R, Słomczyński, W, Zachariasen, M and
Życzkowski, K. (2011): The allocation between the EU Member States of the seats in the European Parliament
Cambridge Compromise. European Parliament Studies, PE 432.760.
5
Laslier JF (ed.) (2012) Special Issue around the Cambridge Compromise: Apportionment in Theory and Practice.
Elsevier, (Mathematical Social Science, 63)
6
Gualtieri, R. and Trzaskowski, R. (2013) Report on the composition of the European Parliament with view to the
2014 elections. Committee on Constitutional Affairs (2012/2309(INI))
The Composition of the European Parliament
25
In this briefing and after the introduction, section 2 describes how some assignments in the
current composition of the EP are contrary to the idea of DP and how others are not
reasonable. Section 3 provides arguments for removing constraints (maximum 96 seats and
minimum 6 seats). Section 4 defends and justifies the concept of degressive proportionality
in EP seat distribution. Section 5 proposes a parametric family of methods to obtain the
composition of the EP. These methods are based on a more precise and restrictive definition
of DP than the proposal in the "Cambridge Compromise". All methods belonging to this
parametric family give Malta fewer than six seats. However, as it is necessary to respect the
limits imposed by the Lisbon Treaty
7
, we have made an allocation with the minimum and
maximum requirements
9
, to obtain a method, called 0.5-DPL, which respects all
constraints. The results of the proposed method and those obtained with the "Cambridge
Compromise" method, the parabolic method and the power method, are compared with the
current distribution and we can observe that the 0.5-DPL method gives a closer
allotment to the current distribution. The proposed method is applicable to any other
scenario where there are changes in the states, in their population, in the minimum and
maximum requirements or in the size of the EP. Thus, in section 6 we give an example of a
possible composition of the EP after Brexit for which we have proposed an EP with 701
MEPs, maintaining the minimum 6 and maximum 96 for each state. We also include a table
with the allocation of seats following a possible EU enlargement and, finally, in section 7 we
present the main conclusions of this briefing
2. NON-DEGRESSIVITY AND OTHER FORMS OF ILLOGICAL
BEHAVIOUR IN CURRENT EP COMPOSITION
Currently, the population/seat ratio for the five most populous countries is:
Germany: 82064489/96=854838 Italy: 61302519/73=839761
France: 66661621/74=900833 Spain: 46438422/54=859971
UK: 65341183/73=895085
We can see that there is inverse degressivity when comparing Germany with France,
the UK and Spain, since they all have a higher population/seat ratio than Germany
although they are less populated. In particular Spain has almost 35 million fewer
inhabitants than Germany. Thus, this situation has to be reversed either by diminishing the
representation of Germany or by increasing the representation of the other countries (or
both).
Another important example of inverse degressivity occurs when comparing Romania
with The Netherlands. The Netherlands should receive more seats or Romania’s
representation should be decreased.
On the other hand, the population of Hungary has decreased while Sweden’s has increased.
Currently Sweden has a larger population than Hungary, but, in the EP, Hungary has
21 MEPs and Sweden 20. Therefore this situation cannot be maintained.
The new composition of the EP should also lead to another major change in the unjustified
allocation of seats for Lithuania, as Lithuania has a population of less than 2.9 million
and currently has the same number of seats as Ireland whose population exceeds 4.6
million. It would be reasonable for Ireland to have about 3 seats more than Lithuania.
Apart from these considerations, the allocation obtained with the formula that is adopted
should give results close to present day ones for the rest of the Member States. The formula
should work well even if the constraints 6 and 96 were to be replaced by other numbers or
even if they were abolished altogether.
7
Consolidated versions of the Treaty on European Union and the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union
(Treaty of Lisbon). Official Journal of the European Union. C306:1-388, 2007. Available at: http://europa.eu/
lisbon_treaty/ full_text/index_en.htm
Policy Department for Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
26
3. WHY DOES THE MINIMUM CORRESPOND TO 6 SEATS AND THE
MAXIMUM TO 96?
The Lisbon Treaty stipulates that no state may obtain more than 96 seats or fewer than 6
seats. These maximum and minimum limitations were set in response to a political
agreement. However, no justification of these values was given and, moreover, if they were
justified it would be for a situation similar to that which existed in 2007. Also at that time,
the EP had fewer powers than at present and it is now necessary to question these
limitations. Moreover, the EU may be enlarged by accepting new States while other Member
States may wish to leave the EU. In any event, the population of Member States may
change from one election to the next, more so in some states than in others.
Therefore, the minimum and maximum limitations that the Lisbon Treaty imposes upon
Member States concerning their number of seats in the composition of the EP are not
guaranteed to last. Let us work on the assumption that a very small state, for example
having about 100,000 inhabitants, were to join the EU: how could assigning 6 seats to this
state be justified? If that were to happen, an MEP from this hypothetical small state would
represent fewer than 16,500 inhabitants in the Union, whereas an MEP from Malta would
represent 70,000 and a MEP from one of the most populous countries would represent
about one million. Such differences would be difficult to justify logically.
Moreover, the same goes for the maximum limitation of 96 seats. Let us imagine that
several of the most populated countries in the EU (but not Germany) decide to leave the
EU. In that case, if the size of EP remained as 751, then what purpose would imposing a
limit of 96 seats on Germany serve?
Initially, therefore, the proposed method shall not set maximum or minimum limits. At a
later stage, the formula can include the current limitations (of the Lisbon Treaty) or other
new limitations.
4. WHY MUST THE REPRESENTATION IN THE EUROPEAN
PARLIAMENT NOT BE PROPORTIONAL?
The voting behaviour of MEPs does not always follow the same pattern. Sometimes MEPs
join forces with their parliamentary group, while on other occasions they tend to vote more
in accordance with their nationality. On other times, finally, they follow neither of the
previous two patterns.
When MEPs vote according to their ideology, as in national parliaments, seat allocation
proportional to the people who elect them is justified.
However, when MEPs vote according to their nationality the most reasonable distribution is
obtained in proportion to the square root of states’ population, because in this case a similar
“citizen power” is obtained in proportion to the square root of their inhabitants (some
related works: Barbe
8
, Beisbart
9
, Penrose
10
, Moberg
11
and Cichocki and Życzkowski
12
).
Therefore, a proportional allocation of EP seats among Member States would be
unfair to the citizens of smaller states because their power of vote, when their
MEPs vote en bloc, is much smaller than the power of the citizens of the most
populous countries.
8
Barberá, S. and Jackson, M.O. (2006). “On the Weights of Nations: Assigning Voting Weights in a Heterogeneous
Union.” Journal of Polit. Econ. 114(2): 317 339.
9
Beisbart, C. and Bovens, L. (2007). “Welfarist Evaluations of Decision Rules for Boards of Representatives.” Soc.
Choice and Welfare 29: 581 608.
10
Penrose, Lionel S. 1946. “The Elementary Statistics of Majority Voting.” J. Royal Statis. Soc. 109:53 57.
11
Moberg, A. (2012) EP seats: the politics behind the math. Mathematical Social Scieces, 63, 78-84.
12
Cichocki M. A. and Życzkowski K. (eds) (2010) Design and Voting Power in the European Union. Farnham:
Ashgate Publishing Limited.
The Composition of the European Parliament
27
Moreover, the seat allocation in the EP in proportion to the square root of the
population of the states would give all EU citizens more equal power if all the
representatives of each state were to vote en bloc, but that is not so in many
cases and therefore it would also be unfair.
The proportional allocation according to the number of inhabitants assigns more
representatives to the most populous states than proportional distribution to the square root
of inhabitants, and the opposite occurs with the least populous states.
Thus, the most populous countries are interested in allocations closest to proportional
representation to inhabitants and the least populated countries are interested in an
allocation closest to proportional representation to the square root of inhabitants.
Therefore, there is no justification for a set distribution in the EP in which:
1. The most populous country obtains more seats than it would obtain with a
proportional allocation to its inhabitants.
2. The least populous country receives more seats than it would obtain with a
proportional allocation to the square root of the number of inhabitants.
The perfect method will never exist, but perhaps a method that combines proportional
representation to population with proportional representation to the square root
of the number of inhabitants is one of the most suitable outcomes for determining the
composition of the EP.
The question is: what combination between the two distributions should we use?
Thus, the more influence the distribution in proportion to the square root exercises, the
more degressive it will be.
Therefore, we can define the degree of DP, r, in terms of the proportion of seats
allocated to the states in proportion to the square root of their population. This
definition is clarified in the next section, which also contains the distribution tables
corresponding to different degrees of DP.
5. THE FAMILY OF r-DP METHODS
As discussed above, a part r of the seats in the EP will be distributed in proportion to the
square root of the population of each country and the other part (1-r) in proportion to its
population.
Thus, r is a parameter that can take any value in the interval [0-1]. The corresponding
method is denoted by r-DP and we shall say that this method has a degree of degressivity r.
The parametric r-DP method yields different sets of seat representation for states
in function of their degree of degressivity.
For example, r = 0.6 means to allocate 60% of seats in proportion to the square root of
population and, as (1-r) = 0.4, 40% of seats in proportion to the population.
Specifically, once the degree of degressivity r is fixed, the representation of state i, with
population p
i
would be proportional to its adjusted quota A(p
i
)=q
i
:
11
751*
751*(1 )
( ) (1)
i
i
ii
nn
ii
ii
rp
rp
A p q
pp



Thus, according to the populations shown in Table 1, the adjusted quotas are:
751*
751*(1 )
()
99010 510860699
i
i
ii
rp
rp
A p q

Policy Department for Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
28
and if we choose a degree of DP r = 0.6 (for example), then the adjusted quota for France
is
2
751*0.6 66661621 751*0.4 66661621
(66661621) 76.36
99010 510860699
Aq
The rounding of fractions will be in accordance with the Adams method (divisors method
with upward rounding
13
). So any Member State receives at least one seat.
Thus we obtain the value of k which verifies
1
751 (2)
n
i
j
kq


Where
x


is the integer number which is greater or equal to x. The value of k is always
somewhat less than 1, because the rounding of the fractions is upward.
And the allotment S
r
is:
1 2 28
, , ..., (3)
r
S kq kq kq
The question now is, what value to choose for r? Maybe it should not be a value either
close to zero or to one.
Degressivity of Sr
Each allotment S
r
is degressively proportional as stated in the Cambridge Compromise
An important result is:
[0,1]r
, the obtained distribution S
r
is degressively proportional as
indicated by the Cambridge Compromise, i.e. the ratios between populations and seats
(before rounding) are decreasing as we move from more populated states to less populated
ones.
1
2
11
751*
751*(1 )
( ) / (4)
i
ii
i
nn
i
i
ii
ii
rp
q r p
c
pc
p
p
pp



When r is fixed, c
1
and c
2
are constants in (4). So the ratio p
i
/q
i
is decreasing when p
i
decreases.
Some particular allocations obtained through different degrees of DP
Table 1 shows the results for various values of r ranging between 0 and 1. The last column
shows the current allocation. The Adams method has been used for rounding.
13
Pukelsheim, F. Proportional representation. Apportionment methods and their applications (2014), Springer.
The Composition of the European Parliament
29
Table 1: Composition of the EP with different degrees of DP and current
allotment
Country
Population
S
0.=
Pro.
S
0.40
S
0.50
S
0.60
S
1
=PSR
Current
Germany
82064489
119
98
93
88
68
96
France
66661621
97
82
79
76
61
74
United
Kingdom
65341183
95
81
78
74
61
73
Italy
61302519
89
77
74
71
59
73
Spain
46438422
68
61
59
58
51
54
Poland
37967209
55
52
51
50
46
51
Romania
19759968
29
31
31
32
34
32
The
Netherlands
17235349
25
28
28
29
31
26
Belgium
11289853
17
20
21
22
26
21
Greece
10793526
16
20
21
21
25
21
Czech Rep.
10445783
16
19
20
21
25
21
Portugal
10341330
15
19
20
21
24
21
Sweden
9998000
15
19
19
20
24
20
Hungary
9830485
15
18
19
20
24
21
Austria
8711500
13
17
18
19
23
18
Bulgaria
7153784
11
15
16
17
20
17
Denmark
5700917
9
13
13
14
18
13
Finland
5465408
8
12
13
14
18
13
Slovakia
5407910
8
12
13
14
18
13
Ireland
4664156
7
11
12
13
17
11
Croatia
4190669
7
10
11
12
16
11
Lithuania
2888558
5
8
9
10
13
11
Slovenia
2064188
3
7
7
8
11
8
Latvia
1968957
3
6
7
8
11
8
Estonia
1315944
2
5
6
6
9
6
Cyprus
848319
2
4
5
5
7
6
Luxembourg
576249
1
3
4
4
6
6
Malta
434403
1
3
3
4
5
6
Total
510860699
751
751
751
751
751
751
Source: Figures concerning the population of each Member State in accordance with Council Decision (EU,
Euratom) 2016/2353 of 8 December 2016 amending the Council's Rules of Procedure
(http://eurlex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/HTML/?uri=CELEX:32016D2353&from=EN)
Remarks 1
a. Obviously the S
0
and S
1
values, for proportional allocation to population and proportional allocation to the
square root of the population (respectively), are disposable, because they are far removed from the results
obtained by negotiations in the past. However, values of r close to 0.5 lead to allocations which are
very similar to the current ones for all countries except those affected by the minimum limitation,
inverse degressivity and Lithuania and Hungary as indicated in section 2.
b. In comparison with the last column, which contains the current allocation of seats, it can be observed that,
when the distribution tables are calculated with the three values r close to 0.5, France, UK, Spain and The
Netherlands are the only countries in each case which receive more seats than their current apportionment.
In part this is quite logical, because the present distribution is contrary to degressive proportionality among
the most populous states. For example France is the country in the EU whose MEPs represent most
inhabitants, and in the case of Spain its MEPs represent more inhabitants than MEPs from Italy or Germany,
even though Germany has almost double the population of Spain. By contrast, there are other countries in
the three distribution tables receiving fewer seats than they actually have in the EP. They are the three least
populated states (Malta, Luxembourg and Cyprus) together with Lithuania and Hungary.
Policy Department for Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
30
c. Perhaps the choice r = 0.5 is the one which is the most consistent with current allocation. However, Scully
et al
.
14
states that political and ideological affiliations explain 60 per cent of the variance in the personal
positions of MEPs on EU policy issues and the remaining 40 per cent is explained by national affiliations.
Thus, 0.4 is another important value of r that must be considered.
On the other hand, Dniestrzański
15
introduces a measure of degressivity MD(S) for distribution S, as
1
1
*
()
*
n
i
i
i
n
i
i
Hp
s
V
MD S
Hp
H
nV
Here,
V
is the total population of the European Union.
If we calculate the measure of degressivity MD(S
r
) for the five previous distributions we obtain the following
results:
r
0
0.40
0.50
0.60
1
MD(S
r
)
0.02
0.21
0.26
0.30
0.50
Therefore the degree of degressivity r established in this paper reproduces the same order as the degree of
degressivity established by Dniestrzański, but the values are different.
Although the values MD(S
r
) in these examples, are approximately r/2, this is not always the case.
In fact, the rate of Dniestrzański is more appropriate for measuring disproportionality than measuring degressive
proportionality, because the formula does not distinguish whether the represented countries are the most or the
least populated ones.
The proposed method
In view of the negotiations that led to the composition of the EP for the 2014-2019 term, we
consider that an appropriate method to distribute EP seats may be the one which has a
degree of degressivity r = 0.50, the 0.5-DP method, (50% of the seats in proportion to the
number of inhabitants and 50% in proportion to the square root of the number of
inhabitants), whose distribution is obtained by applying the expressions (1)-(3) with r = 0.5
and k = 0.982. It is contained in the fifth column of Table 1.
The proposed method with the limitations of 6 and 96
To obtain the allotment with the proposed methods 0.5-DP while respecting the Treaty
limitations of 6 and 96 seats, we must find a value of k such that
1
median(6, ,96) 751 (5)
n
i
j
kq


We call it the 0.5-DPL method. The corresponding allocation is obtained using k = 0.974.
In Table 2, below, column 2 shows the assignments before rounding, column 3 contains the
rounded allotment and column 4the ratio of degressivity. Finally the degressivity for the
current allotment is shown in the last column of Table 2.
14
Scully, R., Hix, S. and Farrel, D. (2012) ‘National or European parlamentarians? Evidence from a New Survey of
the Members of the European Parliament’. Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. 50, No. 4, pp. 670683.
15
Dniestrzański, P., (2014), “Proposal for measure of degressive proportionality”. Elsevier, Procedia Social and
Behavioral Sciences 110, 140 147
The Composition of the European Parliament
31
Table 2: Degressivity of the proposed and current methods
Source: Own elaboration. From Estonia down to Malta we have used as divisor A(p) the value 6.
In the last column, whenever a quotient appears in bold it is because there is at least one
other quotient further down in the table that has a larger value (contrary to DP after
rounding).
Graphically, the proposed (blue points on the curve) and current (purple) allotments are
shown in the following graph.
Country
A(p)
0.5-DPL
Pop./A(p)
Pop./Current
Germany
92.22
93
889877
854838
France
77.88
78
855953
900833
United Kingdom
76.64
77
852573
895085
Italy
72.81
73
841952
839761
Spain
58.42
59
794906
859971
Poland
49.94
50
760256
744455
Romania
30.57
31
646384
617499
The Netherlands
27.67
28
622889
662898
Belgium
20.49
21
550993
537612
Greece
19.86
20
543481
513977
Czech Republic
19.42
20
537888
497418
Portugal
19.28
20
536376
492444
Sweden
18.84
19
530679
499900
Hungary
18.62
19
527953
468118
Austria
17.14
18
508256
483972
Bulgaria
15.01
16
476919
420811
Denmark
12.90
13
441932
438532
Finland
12.55
13
435491
420416
Slovakia
12.46
13
434022
415993
Ireland
11.32
12
412028
424014
Croatia
10.56
11
396844
380970
Lithuania
8.35
9
345935
262596
Slovenia
6.79
7
304453
258024
Latvia
6.59
7
298780
246120
Estonia
5.18
6
219324
219324
Cyprus
4.01
6
141386
141386
Luxembourg
3.22
6
96042
96042
Malta
2.76
6
72400
72400
751
Policy Department for Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
32
2 10
7
4 10
7
6 10
7
8 10
7
20
40
60
80
The curve corresponds to the adjusted quotas. Therefore, the allocations with the 0.5-DPL
method are on the curve, except those affected by the minimum 6.
The points distant from the curve correspond to the current distribution, mainly those that
correspond to Germany, the UK, France and Spain.
6. THE COMPOSITION OF THE EP AFTER BREXIT
Size of the new EP in 2019
The UK’s withdrawal from the EU frees up its 73 seats and makes it easier to adopt a
method which achieves DP, while also reducing EP size from the current size of 751 to 701,
as is shown in this paper: some of the current UK seats can be used to correct the present
inverse DP among the more populous countries to achieve DP. In such a situation, few
countries lose seats and, more importantly, the number of seats that would be lost is
not significant.
In any case, it might be politically prudent to reduce the size of the EP after the withdrawal
of the UK so that any possible future incorporation of new states does not lead to loss of
seats for current Member States.
This would also be useful, if a transnational list is established, which would not require a
reduction in the allocation of Member States’ seats.
A reduction of between 50 and 60 seats may be adequate to achieve both objectives.
Specifically we will simulate results corresponding to a reduction of 50 seats, so that the
EP’s size is 701 seats.
Comparative allotments in 2019
Table 3 shows the results of our proposed method with limitations 6 and 96 in comparison
with other important methods: the Power method (Po), the parabolic method (Pa)
16
and the
Cambridge Compromise method (CC).
16
Ramírez V., Palomares, A. Márquez, M. L. (2006), Degressively proportional methods for the allotment of the
European Parliament seats amongst the EU Member States. Mathematics and Democracy, pp. 205-220. Berlin:
Springer.
The Composition of the European Parliament
33
Table 3: Compositions of EP after Brexit with different methods
Country
S
0.5L
.
Po.
Pa.
CC
Current
Germany
96
96
96
96
96
France
82
81
83
90
74
Italy
77
76
77
83
73
Spain
62
60
62
65
54
Poland
53
51
53
54
51
Romania
32
31-
31-
31-
32
The Netherlands
29
28
28
27
26
Belgium
22
21
21
20-
21
Greece
21
21
20-
19-
21
Czech Republic
21
20-
20-
19-
21
Portugal
21
20-
20-
19-
21
Sweden
20
20
19-
18-
20
Hungary
20-
19-
19-
18-
21
Austria
18
18
17-
17-
18
Bulgaria
16-
16-
15-
15-
17
Denmark
14
14
14
13
13
Finland
14
14
13
12-
13
Slovakia
13
14
13
12-
13
Ireland
12
13
12
11
11
Croatia
11
12
12
11
11
Lithuania
9-
10-
10-
9-
11
Slovenia
7-
9
9
8
8
Latvia
7-
9
9
8
8
Estonia
6
8
8
7
6
Cyprus
6
7
7
7
6
Luxembourg
6
7
7
6
6
Malta
6
6
6
6
6
Total
701
701
701
701
678
Remarks 2 :
a. All allotments shown in Table 3, except the one in force (Current), respect the degressive proportionality
as in the Cambridge Compromise Report which has been established (before rounding).
b. The sum of the absolute differences between the seats allocated in the present-day distribution (Current)
and that obtained with each of the other four methods is:
28 28
11
28 28
0.5
11
63 ; 45
37 ; 35
i i i i
ii
i i Li i
ii
CC Cur Pa Cur
Po Cur S Cur




In the above differences, 23 seats come from the departure of the UK (701-678 = 23), which allows for the
correction of the inverse degressivity, mainly between Germany vis-a-vis France and Spain. In this way, few
states lose representation with respect to the 2014-2019 term.
Using the 0.5-DPL method only five states lose seats (six seats in total): Hungary, Bulgaria, Slovenia and
Latvia lose one seat each and Lithuania loses two seats.
Using the Power method only six states lose seats (seven seats in total): Romania, Czech Republic, Portugal,
Bulgaria and Lithuania lose one seat each, and Hungary loses two seats.
Using the Parabolic method only nine states lose seats (eleven seats in total): Romania, Greece, Czech
Republic, Portugal, Sweden, Austria and Lithuania lose one seat each, and Hungary and Bulgaria lose two seats
each.
Using the Cambridge Compromise method twelve states lose seats (twenty seats in total).
Policy Department for Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
34
So, in this sense we can say that the distribution S
0.5L
, which has been obtained using the 0.5-DPL method, is the
nearest to the current distribution
In addition, the 0.5-DPL method is the only one, of the four previous methods, which does not need limitations.
On the other hand, the entry into force of the Lisbon voting system in the Council from 1 November 2014 (that is
the double majority, with 55% of the EU Member States representing 65% of the EU population), favours both the
most populous states and the smaller states; so the middle-size states must be compensated through a fairer
representation in the EP and the most favourable method for these states is the 0.5-DPL method.
Enlargements of the EU in the 2019-2024 term
If we use the 0.5-DPL method to obtain the composition of the EP with 701 seats in the
2019-2024 term, then the value of k in (5) is k=0.977. So the S
0.5L
apportionment can also
be obtained by using the function
701*0.5
701*0.5
( ) 0.977 (6)
90926.6 445519516
p
p
Ap





Because, in the denominators of (1), the sum of the square root of the populations is
90926.6 and the sum of the populations is 445519516.
If a new state joins the EU during the period 2019-2014, its seat allocation is obtained by
replacing the value of p in (5) by its population, and rounding upwards. If the result is
greater than 96, we must allocate it 96 seats, if the result does not reach 6, we must assign
it 6 seats.
For example, if we assume that Turkey is admitted into the EU and that its population is
78214000, then its adjusted quota is
701*0.5 78214000 701*0.5*78214000
(78214000) 0.977 93.42
90926.6 445519516
A




And the rounding upwards of 93.42 gives 94 seats to Turkey.
However if Montenegro were the country that enters the EU, its adjusted quota is 3.44 and
it receives 6 seats. Table 4 shows the results for several countries.
Table 4: Enlargements of the EU during the 2019-2024 term
Country
p=Population
A(p)
S
0.5L
.
Turkey
78214000
93.42
94
Serbia
7103000
15.50
16
Bosnia and Herz.
3750000
10.18
11
Albania
2887000
8.61
9
F.Y.R.O.M.
2071000
7.01
8
Montenegro
620000
3.44
6
Source for the populations:https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/List_of_European_countries_by_population
If all the six previously mentioned States joined to the EU during the period 2019-2024, the
size of the EP would temporarily exceed the maximum of 751 seats by 94 seats.
In this case, for the period 2024-2029 there should be a readjustment to the 751 seats, and
the results with the 0.5-DPL method would be those that appear in Table 5.
In Table 5 we consider four scenarios for this hypothetical enlargement of the EU:
a) The limitations are 6-96,
b) The limitations change to 5-96 (as CamCom suggests),
c) The limitations change to 4-96 and
d) Without limitations.
The Composition of the European Parliament
35
Table 5: Enlargements of the EU. 2024-2029 term. 0.5-DPL method
Country
6-96
5-96
4-96
No Limitations
Current
Germany
86
87
87
87
96
Turkey
82
83
84
84
-
France
72
73
73
74
74
Italy
68
68
69
69
73
Spain
54
54
55
55
54
Poland
47
47
47
47
51
Romania
29
29
29
29
32
The Netherlands
26
26
26
26
26
Belgium
19
19
20
20
21
Greece
19
19
19
19
21
Czech Rep.
18
18
19
19
21
Portugal
18
18
18
18
21
Sweden
18
18
18
18
20
Hungary
18
18
18
18
21
Austria
16
16
16
16
18
Bulgaria
14
14
14
14
17
Serbia
14
14
14
14
-
Denmark
12
12
12
13
13
Finland
12
12
12
12
13
Slovakia
12
12
12
12
13
Ireland
11
11
11
11
11
Croatia
10
10
10
10
11
Bosnia-Herz
9
9
10
10
-
Albania
8
8
8
8
-
Lithuania
8
8
8
8
11
F.Y.R.O.M.
7
7
7
7
-
Slovenia
7
7
7
7
8
Latvia
7
7
7
7
8
Estonia
6
5
5
5
6
Cyprus
6
5
4
4
6
Montenegro
6
5
4
4
-
Luxembourg
6
5
4
3
6
Malta
6
5
4
3
6
Total
751
751
751
751
678
7. CONCLUSIONS
A formula is required to assign seats in the European Parliament to EU Member States
clearly and objectively.
At present, the distribution of EP seats among the 28 Member States diverges from the
Lisbon Treaty provisions because it violates the principle of degressive proportionality in the
sense proposed by Lamassoure and Severin, and also by the "Cambridge Compromise".
The withdrawal of UK from the EU is regrettable. But at least we may use some of the seats
that UK releases to increase the representation of those Member States affected by inverse
DP, without a significant reduction in the representation of many other Member States.
There are many allocations that conform to DP before rounding. In this paper we show a
parametric family of methods that respect the principle of DP. These methods have a
Policy Department for Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
36
scientific justification. Some methods differ from others in the degree of DP that they
achieve.
We chose a method with an intermediate degree of degressivity, the 0.5-DPL method,
which also has a political justification: the distribution of seats obtained by 0.5-DPL is
close to the current one, with the exception of the countries affected by inverse DP or
illogical allocation, as shown in section 2.
Regarding the size of the EP after Brexit, our recommendation is that it should be higher
than 678 (= 751-73), because, in that way, we can use seats released by the UK to correct
inverse DP. On the other hand, the size of the EP should not exceed by much the
number of 700 seats, since this would do very detrimental to Germany, as explained
in section 3. In fact, this paper also includes a critical analysis of the minimum and
maximum limits of 6 seats and 96 seats respectively for each Member State, and suggests
removing them in a future Treaty revision. To compare our method with other known
methods, we have taken the size of the EP to be 701 seats.
Then, the 0.5-DPL method allocates seats in the European Parliament, which in the case of
the 2014-2019 parliamentary term would be closer to the current distribution than other
methods such as the Cambridge Compromise, the parabolic and the power methods.
The 0.5-DPL method can be perfectly and succinctly described as follows: the quota
for each Member State is calculated by distributing half of the seats in proportion to the
square root of the population and the other half of the seats in proportion to the population
of that state. The obtained quota is rounded to integers using the Adams method, with a
minimum of 6 and a maximum of 96.
Therefore, the allocation with the 0.5-DPL method can be made with an elementary
calculator. This method is transparent, simple and durable.
Finally, the Jagiellonian Compromise is a very good system to assign voting weight to
each Member State in the Council. In addition, it is an easier method to be applied than the
doublemajority system. In the event that a country leaves the EU the size of the EP is
reduced according to the number of seats of the outgoing country, and the weight of the
votes in the Council must be recalculated.
The Composition of the European Parliament
DEGRESSIVE PROPORTIONALITY IN THE EUROPEAN
UNION
Dr. Wojciech SŁOMCZYŃSKI AND Prof. Karol ŻYCZKOWSKI
1. ALLOCATING SEATS IN THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT
According to the Treaty on European Union (EU) (in particular Article 14(2))
1
and the
Council of the European Union Decision of 28 June 2013 establishing the composition of the
European Parliament (EP)
2
, the apportionment of seats in the EP should be based on the
principle of degressive proportionality further technically specified in Article 1 of the
Decision as follows:
the allocation of seats in the European Parliament shall fully utilise the minimum and
maximum numbers set by the Treaty on European Union in order to reflect as closely
as possible the sizes of the respective populations of Member States,
1
Consolidated version of the Treaty on European Union, OJ C 326, 26.10.2012.
2
European Council Decision of 28 June 2013 establishing the composition of the European Parliament, OJ L 181,
29.6.2013, p. 5758.
KEY FINDINGS
Allocating seats in the European Parliament (EP) according to a selected
mathematical formula based on the populations of the Member States, allows us to
avoid potential problems which may occur with any change in the number of Member
States or with any considerable variation of their population.
There exists a plethora of mathematical systems for the seats apportionment that
agree with the bounds adopted by the Treaties and the rule of degressive
proportionality. One of the simplest is the base + prop scheme, known also as the
Cambridge Compromise.
The Modified Cambridge Compromise (base + power scheme) is better suited in the
case of the predicted exit of the United Kingdom from the EU than the original
Cambridge Compromise, and results in the minimum transfer of seats in the EP,
regardless of the size of the EP, with the rounding method adjusted to the size.
Brexit provides a unique opportunity to implement a smooth transition to a new
balanced allocation system in such a way that each Member State obtains at least
the current number of seats in the EP. Such solutions exist also for an appropriately
reduced size of the Parliament.
The minimum size of the EP for which such a smooth solution exists in case of the
Modified Cambridge Compromise is 721 (according to the current population data).
Transition to one of the systems mentioned above will increase the share of
representatives for a few of the largest Member States, and will reduce it for the
medium-sized ones. Thus, to preserve the overall balance of power in the European
Union, one should consider a simultaneous modification of the voting system in the
Council of the European Union. For this purpose we recommend the degressive
proportional system called the Jagiellonian Compromise that strengthens the voting
power of the medium-sized states.
Policy Department for Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
38
the ratio between the population and the number of seats of each Member State before
rounding to whole numbers shall vary in relation to their respective populations in
such a way that each Member of the European Parliament from a more populous
Member State represents more citizens than each Member from a less populous Member
State and, conversely, that the larger the population of a Member State, the greater its
entitlement to a large number of seats
3
.
Since we have analysed this principle thoroughly in the paper entitled «Mathematical
aspects of degressive proportionality» published four years ago
4
, here we shall present only
a brief résumé and refer the reader to the paper itself and the references therein for further
details.
Degressive proportionality
The notion of degressive proportionality
5
plays a crucial role in the current
apportionment scheme for the European Parliament. The principle of degressive
proportionality enshrined in the Lisbon Treaty was probably borrowed from discussions on
taxation rules, where the term appeared as early as the nineteenth century, when many
countries introduced income tax for the first time in their history. It was already included in
the debate on apportionment in the Parliament in the late 1980s
6
, but at first it was a rather
vague idea that gradually evolved into a formal legal (and mathematical) term in the
Lamassoure & Severin report
7
adopted by the European Parliament in 2007.
The notion hardly appears in the constitutional solutions of the apportionment problem
adopted either inside or outside the EU, where the proportional apportionment schemes
seem to be prevalent. However, one can find several cases in political practice where
degressively proportional solutions have been implemented, though not necessarily
precisely defined and not necessarily under this name.
Firstly, many allocation systems that reserve a minimum number of seats in a political
body, for all subunits represented, usually fail to be proportional, and so, some amount of
degressive proportionality seems to be a natural solution in this case. The most famous
example that comes to mind here is the Electoral College that formally elects the
President and Vice President of the United States of America, where each state is allocated
as many electors as it has Senators (equal base) and Representatives (proportional
representation, with at least one seat per state) in the United States Congress. The idea of
combining these two approaches to the apportionment problem was first put forward by one
of the Founding Fathers of the United States and future American President, James
Madison
8
in 1788.
Secondly, we can find at least two examples from European political practice: the
apportionment of seats both in the upper house of the German Parliament
9
(Bundesrat), and in the electoral body comprising the members of the twelve
Provincial Councils (Provinciale Staten) that elects the Senate (Eerste Kamer) of the
Dutch Parliament, that are also de facto though not de jure degressively proportional.
3
Cegiełka, K., 2013, Composition of the European Parliament in the 2009-2014 term. Didactics of Mathematics 9,
25-34.
4
Słomczyński, W., Życzkowski, K., 2012, Mathematical aspects of degressive proportionality. Mathematical Social
Sciences 63, 94101.
5
Pukelsheim, F., 2014, Proportional Representation Apportionment Methods and Their Applications. With
a Foreword by Andrew Duff MEP. Springer, Cham (CH), p. 166.
6
However, the concept does not appear in Balinski, ML. Young, HP. 1982, Fair representation in the European
Parliament. Journal of Common Market Studies 20, 361-373.
7
Lamassoure, A. - Severin, A., 2007, EP Resolution on ‘Proposal to amend the Treaty provisions concerning the
composition of the European Parliament’ adopted on 11 October 2007 (INI/2007/2169).
8
Madison, J., 1788, The conformity of the plan to republican principles. The Independent Journal, January 18,
Federalist Paper No. 39.
9
Allen, TJ., Taagepera, R., 2016, Seat allocation in federal second chambers. CSD Working Papers.
The Composition of the European Parliament
39
Thirdly, the distribution of votes in the Council of the European Union from the very
beginning of the European Communities until quite recent times, when the system of
‘double majority’ was introduced, has reflected the principle of degressive proportionality
10
.
There have also been suggestions in academic literature to apply this general principle to
the apportionment process in some other parliamentary or quasi-parliamentary bodies, such
as the projected Parliamentary Assembly of the United Nations
11
.
Degressively proportional apportionment an algorithm
There is a fundamental difference between proportional and degressive proportional
apportionment. While the former is a precisely defined mathematical concept, where only
the rounding procedure gives us some freedom of manoeuvre, the latter does not
provide us with a single solution, but instead offers an infinite number of options
from which to choose.
How to cope with such a plethora of options in a systematic way? One of the major
mathematical approaches to the problem of degressively proportional apportionment in the
European Parliament can be described by the following general scheme:
1. One has to choose a concrete characterisation of the size of a given Member State i
by a number p
i
(for example, equal to the total number of its inhabitants, citizens or
voters), which we call here population, and precisely define by which means the
required data should be collected and how often it should be updated. Then, one
needs to transform these numbers by an allocation function A belonging to a given
family (allocation scheme) indexed by some parameter d, whose range of
variability is determined by the requirement that the function fulfils constraints
imposed by the Treaties: is non-decreasing and degressively proportional.
2. Additionally, the allocation function A has to satisfy certain boundary conditions:
A(p) = m and A(P) = M, where the population of the smallest and the largest state
equals, respectively, p and P, with the smallest and the largest number of seats
predetermined as, respectively, m and M. (In the case of the EP these quantities are
explicitly determined by the Treaty and the Decision: m = 6 and M = 96.)
3. To assign integer number of seats for each Member State one has to round the
values of the allocation function, e.g. using one of three standard rounding
methods (upward, downward or to the nearest integer).
4. Finally, one has to choose the parameter d in such a way that the sum of the seat
numbers of all Member States equals the projected number of seats in the EP (S),
solving (if possible) in d the equation:
where N stands for the number of Member States, p
i
for the population of the i-th
state (i = 1, …, N), and [] denotes the rounded number.
Thus to prepare a degressive proportional apportionment of seats for the EP we have to set
three variables:
a. the number of seats in the EP S;
b. the allocation scheme A;
c. the rounding method [].
Knowing a), b) and c), we can choose the appropriate parameter d and, consequently,
a concrete allocation function resulting in the distribution of seats in the EP associated with
the given variables. Though usually there is a whole interval of parameters satisfying this
10
Best, E., 2004, What is really at stake in the debate over votes? EIPAScope 1, p. 14-23.
11
Bummel, A., 2010, The composition of a parliamentary assembly at the United Nations. Background Paper No. 3.
Berlin: Committee for a Democratic UN; see also von Bogdandy, A., 2012, The European Lesson for International
Democracy: The Significance of Articles 912 EU Treaty for International Organizations. The European Journal of
International Law 23, 315-334.
Policy Department for Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
40
requirement, nonetheless, in a generic case, the distribution of seats established in this
way is unique. This technique bears a resemblance to divisor methods in the
proportional apportionment problem used first by Thomas Jefferson
12
in 1792.
Please note that in the Lamassoure and Severin definition of degressive proportionality it
was postulated that this property holds for the number of seats after rounding the values
of the allocation function to whole numbers. However, one can show that there exist such
distributions of population that there is no solution to the apportionment problem satisfying
such defined degressive proportionality
13
. Consequently, Grimmett et al. recommended
14
to
weaken this condition and to amend the definition of degressive proportionality assuming
that the property holds for the number of seats before rounding.
Proposed forms of allocating schemes
In our papers published several years ago
15
we gathered together and analysed seven
natural allocation schemes, i.e., seven one-parameter families of allocation functions
16
,
and studied their properties with the implementation to the apportionment for the EP under
three rounding procedures (downward, to the nearest integer, upward):
base + prop,
piecewise linear,
quadratic (parabolic),
base + power,
homographic,
linear + hyperbolic,
min-max proportional.
All seven families mentioned above share a common element: the linear (affine)
allocation function. This is undoubtedly the simplest allocation function one can imagine.
However, under present circumstances, it would lead to a smaller parliament than the
current one, but its size can serve as an indicator to estimate how many seats we can
allocate freely besides the linear (or, more precisely, affine) distribution.
Note that all these solutions have been already discussed in the academic literature. The
base + prop scheme, which seems to be the simplest of all these methods, was first
analysed by Pukelsheim
17
and became the basis for the proposal, called ‘Cambridge
Compromise’, elaborated in January 2011 by a group of mathematicians and political
12
Balinski, ML., Young, HP., 1978, The Jefferson method of apportionment. SIAM Review 20, 278284.
13
Ramírez-González, V., 2010, Degressive proportionality. Composition of the European Parliament. The parabolic
method. In: Cichocki, M., Życzkowski, K. (Eds.), Institutional Design and Voting Power in the European Union.
Ashgate, London (called further [CŻ10]), p. 215–234.
14
Grimmett, G., Laslier, J.-F., Pukelsheim, F., Ramírez-González, V., Rose, R., Słomczyński, W., Zachariasen, M.,
Życzkowski, K., 2011, The allocation between the EU member states of the seats in the European Parliament.
Cambridge Compromise. European Parliament Studies, PE 432.760.
15
Słomczyński, W., Życzkowski, K., 2010, On bounds for the allocation of seats in the European Parliament. In:
[CŻ10], p. 269-281; Słomczyński, Życzkowski, 2012, op. cit.; see also Cegiełka, K., Łyko, J., 2014, Application of
Hamilton’s and divisor methods to degressively proportional allocation functions. Procedia - Social and Behavioral
Sciences 110, 103112.
16
The detailed formulae can be found in Słomczyński & Życzkowski 2012, op. cit. Here, we would like to recall only
one of them:
A
d
(t) = (M(t
d
p
d
) + m(P
d
t
d
))/(P
d
- p
d
)
for the base + power allocation function with the exponent d, where m and M denote the number of seats for the
smallest and the largest Member State, with population p and P, respectively, and p t P. This formula
(combined with the appropriate rounding) was used for computing the numbers in Tables 1 and 2 (columns: MCC
and L), with m = 6, M = 96, p = 434 403 and P = 82 064 489, where t stands for the population of a given
country. The calculation of the exponent d is based on the algorithm described in details in the preceding
subsection. The values of exponents are given in the tables.
17
Pukelsheim, F., 2007, A Parliament of degressive representativeness? Preprint No. 015/2007, Institut für
Mathematik, Universität Augsburg.
The Composition of the European Parliament
41
scientists
18
, and discussed later by the Committee on Constitutional Affairs (AFCO) of the
EP. The piecewise linear scheme was proposed for the first time by the authors of this
briefing
19
and, independently, by Ramírez González et al.
20
under the name of the Linear
Spline Method. On the other hand, the quadratic (parabolic) scheme was advocated by
Ramírez González and his co-workers in a series of papers
21
. The base + power scheme
has been studied by many authors from Ramírez González et al.
22
to Grimmett et al.
23
,
although it can be traced to the paper of Theil and Schrage
24
from 1977. Note that a similar
method was proposed for solving the taxation problem as early as the nineteenth century
by the Dutch economist Cohen-Stuart
25
. The homographic scheme functions introduced by
the authors
26
, were also studied under the name of projective quotas by Serafini
27
. The
linear + hyperbolic scheme was used both in the apportionment problem for the EP
28
, as
well as in the tax schedule proposed by the Swedish economist Cassel at the beginning of
the twentieth century
29
. Finally, the proportional apportionment method with minimum
and maximum requirements was considered by Balinski and Young
30
. Moreover, the
linear allocation function was studied under the name of base + strict prop by Kellerman
31
.
We have observed that all these solutions are quite similar (with the notable exception of
min-max proportional), which is a consequence of the fact that our choice is limited by two
factors: the predetermined shape of the graph of an allocation function, and the fact that
the vast majority of seats are, in a sense, distributed in advance. However, one can
observe that the results for the parabolic, base + power, and homographic allocation
schemes lead to quite similar apportionments, whereas the choice of the base + prop
scheme is advantageous for large countries, and the piecewise linear and
linear + hyperbolic schemes seems to be beneficial for small countries
32
.
In 2011 the authors of this briefing joined the group of mathematicians and political
scientists endorsing the so-called ‘Cambridge Compromise’
33
. This allocation system, was
selected mainly because of its obvious simplicity
34
. However, this solution has been
criticised for being ‘not degressively proportional enough’ and departing too much from the
18
Grimmett et al. 2011, op. cit.
19
Słomczyński & Życzkowski 2012, op. cit.
20
Ramírez-González, V., Martínez Aroza, A., Márquez García, M., 2012, Spline methods for degressive proportionality
in the composition of the European Parliament. Mathematical Social Sciences 63, 114-120.
21
Ramírez González, V., 2004, Some guidelines for an electoral European system. In: Workshop on Institutions and
Voting Rules in the European Constitution, Seville, 1012 December; Ramírez-González, V., Palomares Bautista,
A., rquez García, M., 2006, Degressively proportional methods for the allotment of the European Parliament
seats amongst the EU member states. In: Simeone, B., Pukelsheim, F. (Eds.), Mathematics and Democracy.
Recent Advances in Voting Systems and Collective Choice. Springer, Berlin, p. 205220.
22
Ramírez-González et al. 2006, op. cit.
23
Grimmett, G., Oelbermann, K.-F., Pukelsheim, F., 2012, A power-weighted variant of the EU27 Cambridge
Compromise. Mathematical Social Sciences 63, 136140; see also Pukelsheim 2014, op. cit., p. 170., where the
method is called the downgraded-population variant of the Cambridge Compromise.
24
Theil, H., Schrage, L., 1977, The apportionment problem and the European Parliament. European Economic Review
9, 247263.
25
Cohen-Stuart, AJ., 1889, Bijdrage tot de Theorie der Progressieve Inkomstenbelasting. Martinus Nijhoff, Den Haag.
26
Słomczyński & Życzkowski 2012, op. cit.
27
Serafini, P., 2012, Allocation of the EU Parliament seats via integer linear programming and revised quotas.
Mathematical Social Sciences 63, 107113.
28
Słomczyński & Życzkowski 2010, op. cit.
29
Cassel, KG., 1901, The theory of progressive taxation. The Economic Journal 11, 481491.
30
Balinski, ML., Young, HP., 2001. Fair Representation. Meeting the Ideal of One Man, One Vote, second ed.
Brookings Institution Press, Washington, p. 133.
31
Kellermann, T., 2012, The minimum-based procedure: A principled way to allocate seats in the European
Parliament. Mathematical Social Sciences 63, 102-106.
32
Using the measure of degressive proportionality introduced in: Dniestrzański, P., 2014, Proposal for measure of
degressive proportionality. Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 110, 140147, one can check that it is
possible to order considered schemes from the least to the most degressively proportional: base + prop <
homographic parabolic < base + power < piecewise linear linear + hyperbolic. A similar hierarchy can be
reproduced by computing the relative entropy of the population distribution with respect to the seats distribution,
measuring in this way the deviation form proportionality, see Lauwers, L., Van Puyenbroeck, T., 2008, Minimally
Disproportional Representation: Generalized Entropy and Stolarsky Mean-Divisor Methods of Apportionment. HUB
research paper, Brussel.
33
Pukelsheim 2014, op. cit., p. 168-174.
34
Grimmett et al. 2011, op. cit.
Policy Department for Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
42
status quo by Moberg
35
. In 2012 a solution very similar to the base + power scheme was
considered by Grimmett et al. as a step along a continuous transition from the negotiated
status quo composition to the constitutionally principled Cambridge Compromise
36
. The
crucial point in these discussions seems to be the meaning of the term ‘degressive
proportionality’. Is it only a less perfect form of (pure) proportionality, as it was actually
suggested by some authors or is it a separate notion that requires distinct (and new)
mathematical and political solutions, as Moberg claims? Personally, we incline towards
the latter suggestion.
2. RECOMMENDED SOLUTIONS FOR THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT
As ‘it is unclear whether the UK’s 73 seats will be lost or reallocated’
37
, we have analysed
six possible choices for the size of the EP:
751 - with the UK;
751 - without the UK;
678 = 751 73 - without the UK;
Optimal size - without the UK;
Minimum size - with the UK;
Minimum size - without the UK,
along with seven allocation schemes and three rounding methods, which overall results in
seventy seven different allocations. Analysing all these solutions, we primarily take into
account Article 4 of the Decision that requires establishing a system which in future will
make it possible, before each fresh election to the European Parliament, to allocate the
seats between Member States in an objective, fair, durable and transparent way,
translating the principle of degressive proportionality as laid down in Article 1, taking
account of any change in their number and demographic trends in their population, as duly
ascertained thus respecting the overall balance of the institutional system as laid
down in the Treaties
38
.
As all analysed schemes ‘translate the (mathematical) principle of degressive
proportionality’ into the political realm, and their mathematical form guarantees that the
resulted apportionment would be indeed objective, fair, durable and transparent, we have
looked for the solutions that change the status quo as little as possible
39
trying (in
order):
to minimize the number of seats transferred;
to minimize the number of Member States losing seats;
to maximize the number of Member States gaining seats.
Such solutions would lead to a relatively smooth transition from the current
apportionment into a new one. We call them balanced solutions. Note that some
35
Moberg, A., 2012, EP seats: the politics behind the math. Mathematical Social Sciences 63, 7884.
36
Grimmett et al. 2012, op. cit.
37
Patel, O., Reh, C., 2016, Brexit: The Consequences for the EU’s Political System. UCL Constitution Unit Briefing
Paper 2.
38
European Council Decision of 28 June 2013 establishing the composition of the European Parliament, op. cit.
39
Note that this fact seems to be crucial for practical implementation of a given apportionment scheme. For instance,
in opinion of the authors of Report on the composition of the European Parliament with a view to the 2014
elections. A7-0041/2013, the rapporteurs, Gualtieri and Trzaskowski, both base + prop and parabolic schemes
deviated too strongly from the status quo. As they wrote: The implementation [of the ‘Cambridge compromise’ as
the most ‘proportional’ mechanism respecting degressive proportionality] would trigger a traumatic reallocation of
seats, with heavy losses for medium-sized and small Member States and huge increases for larger ones.
Furthermore, failure to abolish the 96 upper limit would discriminate against Germany among the large Member
States, introducing a steep rise in the population/seats ratio between France and Germany. Among the various
possible mathematical formulae for implementing the principle of degressive proportionality the ‘parabolic’ method
is one of the most degressive. It could, in the longer term, be used as a benchmark in the absence of a treaty
change, but the redistribution which this model entails would be too drastic to be politically sustainable in a single
step. Cf. note 32.
The Composition of the European Parliament
43
transfer of seats is inevitable in this case, firstly, because of demographic changes
40
and, secondly, since the present apportionment in the EP is, in a sense, erratic and
irregular as a result of some historical bargaining
41
, rather than objective
considerations. To be more specific, one can say, with some degree of unavoidable
inaccuracy, that there are three groups of Member States for which the result of projected
changes will be, relatively or absolutely (depending on the future size of the EP)
positive: France, the United Kingdom (if applicable), Spain, Estonia;
neutral: Germany, Italy, Poland, the Netherlands, Denmark, Finland, Slovakia,
Ireland, Croatia, Slovenia, Latvia, Cyprus, Luxembourg, Malta;
negative: Romania, Belgium, Greece, the Czech Republic, Portugal, Sweden,
Hungary, Austria, Bulgaria, Lithuania.
The results of our considerations are outlined below, divided according to two main criteria -
the size of the EP and the presence of the British MEPs (see Tab. 1 and Tab. 2 for
details):
EP 751 (with the UK)
We are still convinced that the ‘Cambridge Compromise’ gives here the simplest acceptable
solution. However, a balanced solution in this case is given by the base + power
scheme with the rounding downwards.
EP 751 (without the UK)
Assume that the size of the EP remains unchanged after Brexit and all British seats are
distributed among other Member States. Then the ‘Cambridge Compromise’ produces
a solution with a substantial transfer of seats, especially to a few large states, while the
balanced solution is given by the base + power scheme rounding upwards.
EP 678 (without the UK)
Assume that the size of the EP is reduced by the number of British seats. Here again the
‘Cambridge Compromise’ produces a solution with a substantial transfer of seats, while the
balanced solution is given by the base + power scheme with rounding downwards.
EP Optimal size (without the UK)
Assume that the size of the EP is reduced by a smaller number than the number of British
seats. We have been looking for the smallest size of the Parliament with no Member State
losing seats. Several options are possible here with the balanced solution given in this
case by the base + power scheme with rounding to the nearest integer and the size
of the EP equal to 721.
EP Minimum size (with or without the UK)
Assume that the simplest allocation function is chosen, i.e., linear with the rounding to
the nearest integer. The resulting size of the EP would be either 718 (with the UK) or 640
(without the UK). Although probably politically hard to implement, this solution shows
(approximately) how many seats can be in fact freely allocated in both situations: only
751 718 = 33 or 678 640 = 38, respectively.
An additional argument for the base + power scheme
The base + power scheme has an additional property called super-proportionality
42
. To
illustrate this property consider two pairs of Member States: Romania/France and
Belgium/Poland, with the similar population quotient (approx. 29.7%), and another such
configuration: Sweden/Romania and Finland/Greece (approx. 50.6%). Note that in all these
40
E.g., the population of Sweden is currently larger than that of Hungary, yet Hungary has one more seat in the
European Parliament.
41
Balinski & Young 1982, op. cit.
42
See Słomczyński & Życzkowski 2012, op. cit. for a precise definition of this notion.
Policy Department for Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
44
cases the seat quotient must be larger than the population quotient because of
degressive proportionality. However, in both cases (assuming the balanced solution and the
current size of the EP: 28 states and 751 seats) the seat quotient is greater for the
‘smaller’ pair than for the larger’ one, as we get 31.25% for Romania/France whereas
40% for Belgium/Poland, as well as 60% for Sweden/Romania whereas 68.42% for
Finland/Greece. In other words, a super-proportional method leads to the following property
of an allocation system (before rounding): The smaller a pair of states is, the larger the
gain in seats of the smaller member in the pair over the larger one. Hence, if an
allocation function is super-proportional, then the degressive proportionality acts more
strongly for smaller states, and so such functions are, in a sense, more degressively
proportional than others. Thus, this is in fact a kind of degressivedegressive
proportionality.
Final recommendation for the European Parliament apportionment
We recommend the adoption of the Modified Cambridge Compromise (MCC), i.e.,
base + power system as the solution that minimizes the transfer of seats and, at the
same time, fulfils all constitutional requirements and expresses the principle of
degressive proportionality more accurately than other solutions considered. The
specific form of rounding in the system should depend on the projective size of the EP
and concrete population data, and should be chosen to further minimize the transfer of
seats. Having at our disposal two extreme solutions: maintaining the current size of the
Parliament (751) or reducing the size by all British seats (to 678), we advocate, however,
for an intermediate solution. Assuming that no Member State should lose any seat during
the transition procedure, and simultaneously trying to minimize the size of the Parliament,
we arrive at the ‘optimal’ number of 721 representatives
The Composition of the European Parliament
45
Table 1: Alternative proposals for the EP apportionment depending on the EP size (with
the UK). Here (CC) stands for the Cambridge Compromise, (MCC) for the base + power
scheme, (L) for the linear allocation, (d) and (n) for the rounding, resp., downwards and to
the nearest integer. Total transfer of seats is the sum of losses and gains in the number of
seats. The exponents are computed for the base + power schemes.
Member State
Population
Status quo
EP+UK
751
(CC)
EP+UK
751
(MCC)
(d)
EP+UK
Minimum
(L)
(n)
Germany
82 064 489
96
96
96
96
France
66 661 621
74
84
80
79
United
Kingdom
65 341 183
73
83
79
78
Italy
61 302 519
73
78
74
73
Spain
46 438 422
54
60
59
57
Poland
37 967 209
51
50
50
47
Romania
19 759 968
32
29
30
27
The
Netherlands
17 235 349
26
26
27
25
Belgium
11 289 853
21
19
20
18
Greece
10 793 526
21
18
19
17
Czech Republic
10 445 783
21
18
19
17
Portugal
10 341 330
21
18
19
17
Sweden
9 998 000
20
17
18
17
Hungary
9 830 485
21
17
18
16
Austria
8 711 500
18
16
17
15
Bulgaria
7 153 784
17
14
15
13
Denmark
5 700 917
13
12
13
12
Finland
5 465 408
13
12
13
12
Slovakia
5 407 910
13
12
12
11
Ireland
4 664 156
11
11
12
11
Croatia
4 190 669
11
10
11
10
Lithuania
2 888 558
11
9
9
9
Slovenia
2 064 188
8
8
8
8
Latvia
1 968 957
8
8
8
8
Estonia
1 315 944
6
7
7
7
Cyprus
848 319
6
7
6
6
Luxembourg
576 249
6
6
6
6
Malta
434 403
6
6
6
6
UE-27
510 860 699
751
751
751
718
Total transfer of seats
0
66
42
56
Exponent
-
-
0.903
1
Population data based on the Council Decision 2016/2353 of 8 December 2016 amending the Council's Rules of
Procedure. (See endnote 16 for the formula used to compute the MCC and the linear apportionments.)
Policy Department for Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
46
Table 2: Alternative proposals for the EP apportionment depending on the EP size (without
the UK). Here (MCC) stands for the base + power scheme, (L) for the linear allocation, and
(d), (n), and (u) for the rounding, resp., downwards, to the nearest integer, and upwards.
Total transfer of seats is the sum of losses and gains in the number of seats. The exponents
are computed for the base + power schemes.
Member State
Population
Status
quo
EP-UK
751
(MCC)
(u)
EP-UK
Optimal
(MCC)
(n)
EP-UK
678
(MCC)
(d)
EP-UK
Minimum
(L)
(n)
Germany
82 064 489
96
96
96
96
96
France
66 661 621
74
83
82
80
79
United Kingdom
-
73
-
-
-
-
Italy
61 302 519
73
78
76
75
73
Spain
46 438 422
54
63
62
60
57
Poland
37 967 209
51
55
53
51
47
Romania
19 759 968
32
35
33
30
27
The
Netherlands
17 235 349
26
31
30
27
25
Belgium
11 289 853
21
24
22
20
18
Greece
10 793 526
21
23
22
20
17
Czech Republic
10 445 783
21
23
21
19
17
Portugal
10 341 330
21
23
21
19
17
Sweden
9 998 000
20
22
21
19
17
Hungary
9 830 485
21
22
21
18
16
Austria
8 711 500
18
20
19
17
15
Bulgaria
7 153 784
17
18
17
15
13
Denmark
5 700 917
13
16
15
13
12
Finland
5 465 408
13
16
14
13
12
Slovakia
5 407 910
13
16
14
13
11
Ireland
4 664 156
11
14
13
12
11
Croatia
4 190 669
11
14
13
11
10
Lithuania
2 888 558
11
11
11
9
9
Slovenia
2 064 188
8
10
9
8
8
Latvia
1 968 957
8
10
9
8
8
Estonia
1 315 944
6
8
8
7
7
Cyprus
848 319
6
7
7
6
6
Luxembourg
576 249
6
7
6
6
6
Malta
434 403
6
6
6
6
6
UE-27
445 519 516
751
751
721
678
640
Total transfer of seats
0
73
43
34
56
Exponent
-
0.796
0.829
0.886
1
Population data based on the Council Decision 2016/2353 of 8 December 2016 amending the Council's Rules of
Procedure. (See endnote 16 for the formula used to compute the MCC and the linear apportionments.)
The Composition of the European Parliament
47
THE SYSTEM OF VOTING IN THE COUNCIL OF THE EU
Adopting one of the mathematically motivated, fair and objective systems of allocation of
seats in the EP recommended above, will lead to a certain transfer of power in the European
Union. In particular, the largest Member States (with the exception of Germany) will
increase their number of representatives in the Parliament. Therefore, to preserve the
overall balance of power in the Union, it is well justified to consider a simultaneous
suitable modification of the existing voting system in the Council.
The current solution, adopted in December 2007 in Lisbon, is based on the principle of
‘double majority’: a decision of the Council is taken if it is supported by a coalition, which:
a. is formed by at least 55% of the Member States,
b. represents at least 65% of the population of the Union.
Additionally, a decision is adopted if the supporting coalition consists of all but three (or
fewer) countries even if it represents less than 65% of the population of the Union
43
.
The case of Brexit creates an urgent need to discuss and reconsider these rules
44
.
A detailed analysis by Moberg shows that the current system of the ‘double majority’ is not
really double, as the population criterion (b) plays a dominant role
45
. As noted by several
authors
46
, the existing system is biased in favour of the most and the least populated
countries. In particular, the voting power of a typical citizen in these states, measured by
the Banzhaf-Penrose index, is larger than the power of a medium-sized state citizen. These
disadvantages of any ‘double majority’ voting system were noted by Lionel Penrose
47
as
long ago as in 1952. Working on the problem of voting power, Penrose formulated his
square root law and proposed an objective voting system, in which the voting weights
are proportional to the square root of the population for each state. A voting system
based on the Penrose law was first proposed for the Council of Ministers by Laruelle and
Widgrén
48
in 1996 and, independently, by Felsenthal and Machover
49
in 1997.
However, to construct any weighted voting system one has to choose not only the
voting weights, but also to fix the quota (threshold) of the qualified majority, which
plays a crucial role in the system
50
. In the past, the quotas in the voting systems for the
Council had been established subjectively in a bargaining procedure, without an objective
justification. A new solution to the problem relates the value of the quota to an
optimization procedure: the optimal quota is set in such a way that the voting power of
every citizen in each Member State is approximately equal
51
. Such a solution is known in
the literature as the Jagiellonian Compromise
52
and its advantages have been
43
Consolidated version of the Treaty on European Union, OJ C 326, 26.10.2012, Article 16(4).
44
Macháček, V., Hrtúsová, T., 2016, Brexit and the functioning of European institutions. Special analysis, EU
Office/Knowledge Centre - Česká spořitelna; Kalcik, R., Wolff, GB., 2017, Is Brexit an opportunity to reform the
European Parliament? Bruegel Policy Contribution 2.
45
Moberg, A., 2010, Is the double majority really double? The voting rules in the Lisbon Treaty. In: [CŻ10], p. 19-34.
46
See [CŻ10]: Kirsch, W., The distribution of power in the Council of Ministers of the European Union, p. 93-107;
Pukelsheim, F., Putting citizens first: Representation and power in the European Union, p. 235-253; Słomczyński &
Życzkowski 2010, op. cit.
47
Penrose, LS., 1952, On the Objective Study of Crowd Behaviour. H.K. Lewis & Co, London.
48
Laruelle, A., Widgrén, M., 1996, Is the Allocation of Voting Power Among the EU States Fair? CEPR Discussion
Paper No. 1402.
49
Felsenthal, DS., Machover, M., 1997, The weighted voting rule in the EU’s Council of Ministers, 195895:
Intentions and outcomes. Electoral Studies 16, 3347.
50
Machover, M., 2010, Penrose’s square root rule and the EU Council of the Ministers: Significance of the quota. In:
[CŻ10], p. 35-42.
51
Słomczyński, W., Życzkowski, K., 2004, Voting in the European Union: The Square Root System of Penrose and a
Critical Point. Preprint cond-mat.0405396; Życzkowski, K., Słomczyński, W., Zastawniak, T., 2006, Physics for
fairer voting. Physics World 19, 35-37; Słomczyński, W., Życzkowski, K., 2007, From a toy model to the double
square root voting system. Homo Oeconomicus 24, 381-399.
52
Słomczyński, W., Życzkowski, K., 2010, Jagiellonian Compromise - an alternative voting system for the Council of
the European Union. In: [CŻ10], p. 43-57; Słomczyński, W., Życzkowski, K., 2014, Square root voting system,
optimal threshold and π. In: Fara, R., Leech, D., Salles, M. (Eds.), Voting Power and Procedures. Springer, Berlin,
p. 127146.
Policy Department for Citizens' Rights and Constitutional Affairs
48
acknowledged by several experts
53
. Its name is related to the fact that it can be considered
as an objective and fair compromise between the older Nice voting system, in which
the largest Member States suffer a relatively small voting power, and the current ‘double
majority’ voting system, where they seem to have too much power.
The Jagiellonian Compromise is a voting system for the Council of Ministers consisting
of a single criterion only determined by the following two rules:
1. Each Member State is attributed the voting weight proportional to the square
root of its population;
2. The decision of the Council is taken if the sum of the weights of members of
a coalition supporting it exceeds the quota equal to the arithmetical mean of the
sum of the weights and the square root of the total population of the Union.
The quota for the qualified majority is considerably larger than 50% for any size of the
voting body of a practical interest. Thus, the voting system is moderately conservative,
as it should be. Furthermore, it is transparent: the voting power of each Member State,
measured by the Banzhaf-Penrose index, is, up to a high accuracy, proportional to its voting
weight. As a crucial advantage of the system one can emphasize its extendibility: if the
number of Member States or their populations change, all one needs to do is to set the
voting weights according to the rule (1), and adjust the quota according to the rule (2).
Currently, the value of the optimal quota equals (approximately) 61.4%; while after
Brexit it would change to 61.6%. Implementing a new voting system in the Council based
on the Jagiellonian Compromise would contribute to an increase in the a priori voting power
of the medium-sized members of the EU. In a sense, this step would compensate for the
losses incurred by these states due to the allocation of seats according to the (Modified)
Cambridge Compromise and will contribute to preservation of the current overall
balance of power in the European Union.
Final recommendation for the voting system in the Council
We recommend the adoption of the Jagiellonian Compromise as the degressively
proportional solution for the voting system in the Council of Ministers, counterbalancing the
effects of the new apportionment of seats in the European Parliament.
53
Pukelsheim 2014, op. cit., p. 174-176.