http://www.shanlaxjournals.com
43
Shanlax
International Journal of Management
s ha n l a x
# S I N C E 1 9 9 0
OPEN ACCESS
Manuscript ID:
MGT-2021-08043816
Volume: 8
Issue: 4
Month: April
Year: 2021
P-ISSN: 2321-4643
E-ISSN: 2581-9402
Received: 29.01.2021
Accepted: 03.03.2021
Published: 01.04.2021
Citation:
Kumar, B. Pradeep.
“Changing Objectives
of Firms and Managerial
Preferences: A
Review of Models in
Microeconomics.” Shanlax
International Journal of
Management, vol. 8, no. 4,
2021, pp. 43-46.
DOI:
https://doi.org/10.34293/
management.v8i4.3816
This work is licensed
under a Creative Commons
Attribution-ShareAlike 4.0
International License.
Changing Objectives of Firms and
Managerial Preferences: A Review of
Models in Microeconomics
B. Pradeep Kumar
Assistant Professor of Economics, Government Arts & Science College, Ambalapuzha, Kerala &
Research Supervisor, University of Kerala, Thiruvananthapuram, India
https://orcid.org/0000-0003-4232-9640
Abstract
Theoretically, producer behavior models postulate that rms have had different objectives
ranging from prot maximization to setting aspirational levels. The assumption of the objective of
prot maximization was shaped based on the rationality principles, which has lost relevance with
the coming of the principle of behavioral economics in recent time. The present paper intends to
throw some light on changes that have been made in the objective of rms over years and attempts
to review some models emphasizing managerial utility as the core objective of rms.
Keywords: Prot maximization, Sales maximization, Managerial utility function,
Managerial discretionary powers, Slacks and salaries, Behavioral economics
Literature in microeconomics has a treasure of descriptions regarding the
dominant objectives that the rms have had to pursue. In the beginning, it
was thought that the rms had been pursuing and had been expected to pursue
only one objective, that is, the maximization of prot. This assumption of the
objective of prot maximization was shaped based on rationality principles.
Based on rationality, it was supposed that economic agents, being rational,
have had to pursue either the goal of utility satisfaction (for consumers) and
prot maximization (for producers). Following this, in early times, producer
behavioral theories and models in economics emphasized prot maximization
as the sole objective of rms. Since then, many shifts have been made in
the considerations of the objectives of rms, thanks mainly to the changes
in the organization of rms. The objectives of sales maximization, revenue
maximization, and managerial satisfaction (popularly known as the managerial
utility function) are some of such changes or shifts in the objective of the
rms. Among these, the most recent and the important one is the principle of
the managerial utility function, which postulates that rms attempt to increase
managerial satisfaction as a proxy for many of their other important functions,
including the objective prot maximization. The tendency of offering high
compensation packages for managers by the corporates stands testimony to
the increasing attention on the part of the rms to focus much on the managers
in an attempt to materialize the corporate objectives. The present paper
intends to throw some light on changes that have been made in the objective of
rms over years and attempts to review some models emphasizing managerial
utility as the core objective of rms.
http://www.shanlaxjournals.com
44
Shanlax
International Journal of Management
s ha n l a x
# S I N C E 1 9 9 0
Prot Maximization - the Early Sole Objective of
Firms
Prot maximization has been hypothesized as
the rational behavior of a rm. Every rm attempts
to maximize prot given the cost and market
conditions. The marginalist school in economics
gave sufcient theoretical underpinnings to the
objective of prot maximization. The economic
theory uses two methods to explain the conditionality
for the maximization of prot: One is the famous
and direct Total Cost-Total Revenue Concept. The
other is the Marginal Cost and Marginal Revenue
method. Thanks to the popularity that marginalism
has assumed in the eld of economics it quite natural
that the latter method has received wide currency in
the realm of economic literature. The elucidation of
the rms’ behavior in different market models like
perfect completion and monopoly centers around the
argument that the rms continue to produce when
the prot gets maximized, the so-called equilibrium
point. All rms, irrespective of market conditions,
are supposed to behave rationally, and therefore,
each one of them would be endeavoring to attain
maximum prot. Although this could be considered
as a starting point of the behavior of rms, this could
not be regarded as the single objective with which all
rms are expected to have been working.
The main lacuna of this argument is that it does
not consider the effect of time, specically the time
value of money. Some rms under the real market
conditions may act in such a way that they give up
prots to withstand in the market, hoping that in
the long run, they would be able to reap the prot.
The infamous strategy of selling products at a price
less than the average cost by rms in an attempt to
capture the market goes diametrically opposite to the
prot maximization strategy of the rms. In the short
turn, rms are seemed to be giving up their prot
for a high prot in the long run. This time element
in the prot expectation of rms does not nd any
place in the prot maximization principle based on
the rational economic behavior as postulated by the
so-called marginalist school in economics. Another
point of weakness of this argument lies in the absolute
negligence that it shows towards the uncertainty and
risks involved in planning the activities of rms.
Nevertheless, in the case of which ownership and
control rest on the same hand, prot maximization
may continue to be the sole objective. It is not
surprising that in small rms and businesses even
today, prot is the sole objective. Some economists
opine that the objective of prot maximization is just
an assumption (Mert, 2018)
Shareholders and Managers
The organizational changes in the structure of
companies made a clear-cut divide between the
managers and the shareholders or the exact owners
of the rms. The corporatization of business entities
fuelled this trend and triggered the difference
between the objectives of managers and the
shareholders. While in the earlier system of owners
acting themselves as the managers, the objective of
prot maximization had an important place. But in
later times, with the coming up market capitalization
of business entities, the objective of the ultimate
owners or the shareholders of the company became
different from that of the managers. Although the
shareholders wanted to have reasonably maximum
prot from the business, the managers paid much
attention to enhancing their salaries, perks, and other
career opportunities. Shareholders did not have
much information about the business. Therefore,
they could not exercise unlimited inuence on the
managers to pursue them to fall in line with the
objective of maximizing prots.
Sales Maximization, not Prot Maximization
Managers appear to be more concerned with
increasing the company’s sales to keep the company
as a market leader. The prestige of the manager
does not depend on maximizing the prot but on
the size of the market and the volume of business
that they command. Taking this into account Prof.
Baumol, opined that rms’ main objective is not to
raise the level of prot but to raise the sales of the
company after having attained a certain desirable
limit of prot. In the view of Baumol, after an
acceptable level of prot is reached, the emphasis
of the rm will be shifted from prot maximization
to sales maximization. Baumol argues that given
the separation of ownership from management and
changing the organizational structure of rms, the
http://www.shanlaxjournals.com
45
Shanlax
International Journal of Management
s ha n l a x
# S I N C E 1 9 9 0
shift to the objective of sales maximization has been
quite evident. Since managers’ salaries and slacks
(slacks are what managers receive over and above
what is required to maintain them in the company.
It is similar to ‘economic rent’ in traditional theory
(Koutsoyiannis, 1979)) is more aligned with the
volume of sales, not with the prot of the rms,
it quite natural that managers would be focusing
more on sales maximization rather than the prot
maximization (Baumol, 1959).
Satiscing Behavior of Firms
In rms with dichotomization of the ownership
and control of the entity, prot satiscing has been
considered to be an important objective. Here,
managers of the rms are expected to prot from the
business, making shareholders or the owners of rms
happy. After making that satiscing prot, another
objective that meets the aspirations of the managers
would be followed. The difference between the
production behavior aiming for prot maximization
and prot satiscing can be understood from the
following gure. The X-axis measures the quantity
of output and Y-axis prots. Two prot levels are
shown viz.’ π
max
,’ maximum prot level and ‘π,’
satisfying prot. A prot-maximizing rm would
choose to produce ‘q
p
quantity of output while a prot
satiscing might produce any quantity between ‘q
o
and ‘q
s
’ (https://www.economicsdiscussion.net/rm,
2021). The principle-agent problem would occur in
these cases. Managers being the agents, possess all
information about the rms. Therefore, they attempt
to capitalize on the information asymmetry and try
to pursue their own goals instead of focusing on
enhancing the level of prot after a certain limit.
Figure 1: Alternative Objectives of Firms: Prot
Satiscing Behavior of Firms
Source: https://www.economicsdiscussion.net/rm
Marris’s Managerial Utility Function
In Marris’s model of Managerial Enterprise,
Marris stresses the importance of managerial utility
function in accomplishing the goal of a rm, the
maximization of the balanced rate growth of the rm
(Marris R., 1963). In pursuing this goal, the rm has
two main constraints: the availability of managerial
team and skill and a nancial constraint (Marris R.,
1964). The utility function of the managers may be
written as:
U
M
= f (salaries, power, status, job security)
In the utility function of the managers, as outlined
above, salaries occupy an important place along with
other elements like power, status, and job security.
Putting it differently, the managerial utility function
is nothing but a function of the compensation to
managers plus some other quality variables like job
security and status. In pursuance of this, rms have
been offering high salaries and job security to top-
level managers to prompt promising managers to
continue in the job and concentrate on furthering the
designed objectives of rms, including maximization
of revenue, sales, and prots.
Williamson’s Model of Managerial Discretion
It is well known that in the emerging business
environment and the changing organizational
structure of enterprises, managers enjoy certain
discretionary powers in running the business not
only in the interest of owners or shareholders
but also, more importantly, in the interest of the
managers themselves. These discretionary powers
have been modeled rst by O. Williamson in 1963
(Williamson, 1963). It is argued that managers have
full discretion in pursuing their own goals and not the
owners’ objective of maximizing the prot. Making
or maximizing prot is regarded as something which
acts as a hindrance to the behavior of the managers.
But, they need to take care of the prot in the absence
of which their job security would be endangered. As
in Marris’s model here also the managerial utility
function encompasses variables like salary, security,
power, status, prestige, professional excellence, and
the like. It is obvious that of these variables, only
the rst one can be made amenable to measurement.
The others variable are together labeled as expense
preference, ‘which is dened as the satisfaction which
managers derive from certain types of expenditures’
(Koutsoyiannis, 1979).
http://www.shanlaxjournals.com
46
Shanlax
International Journal of Management
s ha n l a x
# S I N C E 1 9 9 0
Concluding Observations
Thus, it is quite evident that the tendency of
offering high compensation packages for managers
by the corporates stands testimony to the increasing
attention on the part of the rms to focus much on the
managers in an attempt to materialize the corporate
objectives. This paper has thrown some light on
changes that have been made in the objective of
rms over years and attempts to review some models
emphasizing managerial utility as the core objective
of rms. As evident from the review of models,
one can comprehend the importance attached to the
maximization of the managerial utility function these
days as the prominent objective of rms.
References
Barney, Jay. “Firm Resources and Sustained
Competitive Advantage.” Journal of
Management, vol. 17, no. 1, 1991, pp. 99-120.
Baumol, William. Business Behaviour, Value and
Growth. Macmillan, 1959.
Becker, Gary S. The Economics of Discrimination.
University of Chicago Press, 1957.
Chamberlin, Edward. The Theory of Monopolistic
Competition. Harvard University Press, 1962.
Dixit, Avinash. “Incentives and Organizations in the
Public Sector: An Interpretative Review.” The
Journal of Human Resources, vol. 37, no. 4,
2002, pp. 696-727.
Edwards, Franklin R. “Managerial Objectives in
Regulated Industries: Expense-Preference
Behaviour in Banking.” Journal of Political
Economy, vol. 85, no. 1, 1977, pp. 147-162.
Fama, Eugene F. “Agency Problem and the Theory
of the Firm.” Journal of Political Economy,
vol. 88, no. 2, 1980, pp. 288-307.
Fellner, William. Competition among the Few;
Oligopoly and Similar Market Structures.
A.M. Kelley, 1949.
Galbraith, John. American Capitalism: The Theory
of Countervailing Power. Houghton, 1952.
Koutsoyiannis, A. Modern Microeconomics. The
Macmillan, 1979.
Kyer, Ben L. “A Test of the Baumol Model of
Unbalanced Growth.” Atlantic Economic
Journal, vol. 17, 1989.
Marris, Robin. Theory of ‘Managerial’ Capitalism.
Macmillan, 1964.
Marris, Robin. “A Model of the Managerial
Enterprise.” Quarterly Journal of Economics,
vol. 77, no. 2, 1963, pp. 185-209.
Mert, Merter. “What does a Firm Maximize?
A Simple Explanation with Regard to
Economic Growth.” International Journal of
Engineering Business Management, 2018.
Radner, Roy. “Hierarchy: The Economics of
Managing.” Journal of Economic Literature,
vol. 30, 1992, pp. 1382-1415.
Rajagopalan, Nandini. “Strategic Orientations,
Incentive Plan Adoptions, and Firm
Performance: Evidence from Electric Utility
Firms.” Strategic Management Journal,
vol. 18, no. 10, 1997, pp. 761-785.
Saaty, Thomas L. The Analytic Hierarchy Process:
Planning, Priority Setting, Resource
Allocation. McGraw-Hill International Book
Company, 1980.
Simon, Herbert. Administrative Behavior: A Study of
Decision-Making Processes in Administrative
Organization. MacMillan, 1957.
Veblen, Thorstein. The Engineers and the Price
System. Transaction Publishers, 1994.
Ward, Edwards, et al. Advances in Decision
Analysis: From Foundations to Applications.
Cambridge University Press, 2007.
Weiss, Robert. Learning From Strangers: The Art
and Method of Qualitative Interview Studies.
Free Press, 1995.
Williamson, Oliver E. “Managerial Discretion and
Business Behaviour.” American Economic
Review, vol. 53, no. 5, 1963, pp. 1032-1057.
Yarrow, G.K. “Managerial Utility Maximization
under Uncertainty.” Economica, vol. 40,
1973, pp. 155-173.
Yin, Robert K. Case Study Research: Design and
Methods. Sage Publications, 2009.
Author Details
Dr. B. Pradeep Kumar,
Assistant Professor of Economics, Government Arts & Science College, Ambalapuzha,
Kerala & Research Supervisor, University of Kerala, Thiruvananthapuram, India, Email ID: [email protected]