WORKING PAPER NO. 109
THE DYNAMICS OF FOREIGN PORTFOLIO INFLOWS AND
EQUITY RETURNS IN INDIA
AMITA BATRA
September 2003
INDIAN COUNCIL FOR RESEARCH ON INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC RELATIONS
Core-6A, 4
th
Floor, India Habitat Centre, Lodi Road, New Delhi-110 003
Table of Contents
Foreword.................................................................................................................. 1
Abstract.................................................................................................................... 2
I. Introduction............................................................................................................. 3
II. Survey of Literature ............................................................................................... 4
III. Theoretical Foundations......................................................................................... 5
IV. Data ........................................................................................................................ 11
V. Empirical Analysis................................................................................................ 13
V.1 Positive Feedback Trading ............................................................................... 13
V.2 Herding............................................................................................................... 19
V.3 Destabilizing?..................................................................................................... 22
VI. Conclusions............................................................................................................ 23
Appendix.......................................................................................................................... 25
References........................................................................................................................ 27
2
Foreword
After a series of financial crises in the late 1990s, doubts have been expressed
about the wisdom of promoting free cross –border portfolio flows. Foreign Institutional
Investors (FIIs) constituting a major proportion of these cross –border capital flows are
considered to be driven by “animal spirits” rather than rational investment decisions. The
FIIs have often been blamed for large and concerted withdrawals of capital from
countries in times of crisis, despite evidence showing that domestic/resident investors are
often the first to exit at times of crisis, perhaps because of better information.
Foreign portfolio inflows through FIIs, in India, are important from the policy
perspective, especially when the country has emerged as one of the most attractive
investment destinations in Asia. In this paper an effort has been made to develop an
understanding of the investment decisions, trading strategies and behavior of the FIIs in
the Indian equity market.
This paper reveals aggregate evidence of FIIs chasing trends and adopting
positive feedback trading on a daily basis even though no such behavior is evident over
horizons of a month or so. This evidence seems to support the hypothesis that resident
investors have better information on a daily basis, thus making it essential for FIIs to use
price signals to discern underlying information that may have triggered them. Once the
information is in public domain basic analysis of the implications for stock returns
becomes more important. Thus, while FIIs do tend to herd together in the stock market,
their trading behavior does not appear to be destabilizing for the Indian equity market.
I do hope that this paper will serve as a useful source and provide valuable
reference material for researchers and policymakers associated with and interested in
foreign portfolio inflows in India.
Arvind Virmani
Director & Chief Executive
ICRIER
September 2003
1
Abstract
The Foreign Institutional Investors (FIIs) have emerged as important players in the Indian
equity market in the recent past. This paper makes an attempt to develop an
understanding of the dynamics of the trading behavior of FIIs and returns in the Indian
equity market by analyzing daily and monthly data. From our analysis we find that there
is strong evidence of FIIs chasing trends and adopting positive feedback trading strategies
at the aggregate level on a daily basis. However there is no evidence of positive feedback
trading on a monthly basis. The results of our analysis also indicate that foreign investors
have a tendency to herd together in their trading activity in India. The trading behavior
and biases of the FIIs do not appear to have a destabilizing impact on the equity market.
2
The Dynamics of Foreign Portfolio Inflows and Equity Returns in India
Amita Batra
7
I. Introduction
With the emerging market crises of the late 1990s, the role of Foreign Portfolio
Investment (FPI) and the major players therein i.e. the foreign institutional investors
(FIIs) has come under intense scrutiny by academics as well as policymakers. A general
perception about the FIIs is that they are speculators and their investment is motivated by
short- term gains. The FIIs in pursuit of short- term gains adopt short- term trading
strategies such as positive feedback trading and herding (i.e. buy or sell stocks together as
a group). Such behavioral biases of FIIs, it is believed, may lead to price overreaction and
contribute to the creation or exacerbation of a financial crisis.
In case of India, investment by FIIs has seen a steady growth since the opening of
the equity markets in September 1992. The share of FIIs in total FPI has increased from
47% in 1993-94 to around 74% in 2001-2002. FIIs have also acquired a significant
presence in the Indian stock market. The share of their trading in total turnover attained a
high of almost 30% in October 2001. In total market capitalization
1
FIIs account for
about 13% and they make about 50-60% of average daily deliveries on the stock market.
Notwithstanding the FIIs being important players in the Indian stock market and
that there are strongly held views on their trading behavior biases, little empirical analysis
on the subject in the Indian context has been undertaken. In this paper an effort has been
7
Sincere thanks are offered to Prof. Arvind Virmani for giving invaluable suggestions that helped me
finalize the paper. Thanks are due to an anonymous referee for making useful comments on the first draft.
Constructive suggestions by Dr. Wilima Wadhwa at the ICRIER seminar are thankfully acknowledged.
Research assistance provided by Mr. Puneet Sudan is appreciated.
1
Note that of total market capitalization only half is floating stock.
3
made to develop an understanding of the dynamics of the FII inflows and equity returns
in the Indian equity market.
The paper is organized as follows. In addition to Introduction in section one a
brief survey of the literature is presented in section two. In the following section the
theoretical foundations of positive feedback trading and herding are discussed. The data,
data sources and summary statistics of net equity purchases and equity returns are
presented in section four. Empirical estimation comprising three parts on positive
feedback trading, herding and impact of FII trading on stock market stability is given in
section five. Section six concludes.
II. Survey of Literature
Dornbusch and Park (1995) argue that foreign investors pursue positive feedback
trading strategies that make stocks overreact to changes in fundamentals. Bohn and Tesar
(1996) and Clark and Berko (1996) show a positive contemporaneous relation between
equity flows and stock returns using monthly data for Mexico. Choe, Kho and Stulz
(1998) have examined the impact of foreign investors on stock returns in Korea before
and after the 1997 Asian crisis using daily trade data. They find evidence of positive
feedback trading before the crisis. During the crisis period their study reveals a
weakening of the herding effect and disappearance of positive feedback trading by
foreign investors. In addition they find no evidence of a destabilizing effect of the trades
by foreign investors on Korea’s stock market. Using the measure for herding as
developed by Lakonishok, Shleifer and Vishny [LSV (1992)], Kim and Wei (2002) also
show strong tendencies for herding by foreign investors and offshore investment funds in
Korea in a similar time period. Bonser-Neal et al (2002) analyze the foreign trading
behavior on the Jakarta stock exchange (Indonesia) between 1995 and 2000.They detect
herding and positive feedback trading by foreign investors, but find no evidence to
indicate that such trading behavior by foreign investors destabilized the market prices
during the Asian crisis. Griffin et al (2002) use a theoretical model and empirical analysis
to show that global stock return performance is an important factor in understanding
4
equity flows. Richards (2002) using data for daily net purchases by foreigners in six
Asian emerging equity markets over 1999-2001 gives strong evidence of positive –
feedback trading with respect to domestic, US and regional equity returns.
As against the existing empirical literature that concentrates largely on stock /
firm level analysis, our study has broader coverage. It attempts to analyze aggregate
trading by FIIs in India rather than stock level trades of individual investors. Further,
keeping in view the greater possibility of homogeneity of trading behavior in one group,
our analysis includes all the FIIs rather than one subset of FIIs as has been the case in
earlier studies relating to feedback trading and herding.
III. Theoretical Foundations
Positive feedback trading pattern can result from extrapolative expectations about
prices, from stop – loss orders i.e. automatic selling when the price falls below a certain
point, from forced liquidations when an investor is unable to meet her margin calls or
from portfolio insurance investment strategy which calls for selling stocks when the price
falls and buying it when the price rises.
Our analysis on positive feedback trading tests the hypothesis that net equity
demand by FIIs is driven by recent returns in the equity market of the host country. This
can be viewed as a general exploration of the Brennan and Cao (1997) model that
suggests that net inflows should be a linear function of returns across equity markets.
This model explains why flows would depend on returns in contrast with the more often
discussed and tested, mean –variance model that produces no flows because of changes in
asset prices. A brief outline of the Brennan and Cao (1997) model on international
portfolio investment followed by the model specification for the present analysis is given
below
.
5
The Brennan and Cao Model
The optimal trading strategy of the individual investor i is given by
,
~
)(
~
)
~~
()
~~
(
~~~
1
0
1
+=
=
t
j
tj
i
j
t
ttt
i
t
i
t
i
t
i
t
i
t
PSS
r
X
PUSPZSrDDD
……. (1)
1
~~~
tPPPwhere
tt
Equation (1) shows that the trading strategy of investor
i
in period depends on:
t
the difference between his vector of private signals in period (Zt) and the vector of
prices, , weighted by his private signal precision matrix, ,
t
i
t
t
P
~
S
the difference between the vector of the average private signal,
U
, and the vector of
prices, , weighted by the average private signal precision matrix, ,
~
t
P
~
t
S
the vector of supply shocks due to new liquidity traders in session ,
t
X
~
the vector of price changes, , weighted by the difference between the investor's
private signal precision matrix and the market average precision matrix,
,
accumulated for all sessions up to session
t
.
t
P
~
j
i
j
SS
1
Since the econometrician observes neither the supply shock nor the private
signals, it is convenient to consider the expected trade of investor
conditional on the
vector of price changes at time ,
.
i
t
t
P
~
The conditional expected trade vector might be written as:
6
]
~
]
~
|/
~
[
~
[]
~
|
~
[
t
i
tttt
i
tt
i
t
PPrtXEPrPDE
+Γ=
ω
where
,
t
i
t
i
t
SS
=
ω
the marginal informational (dis)advantage of investor arising from
private signals received at time
i
t
,
t
i
t
t
oj
i
j
i
t
KK
==
=
ω
the cumulative informational (dis)advantage of the investor
arising from all the private signals received up to time t.
]
~
[]
~
,
~~
[
1
1
tttt
PVarPPUCov
=Γ
The following simple results can be obtained in a single security setting:
0
>Γ
t
so that the trades of an investor with no cumulative information advantage ( =
0), but with positive marginal information advantage (
> 0), will be positively
correlated with the current price change; the trades of an investor with a positive
cumulative information advantage , but with no marginal information
advantage
, will be negatively correlated with the price change in the current
period.
i
t
i
t
ω
)0(
>
i
t
)0(
=
i
t
ω
Thus the relation between the trades of well and poorly informed investors and
price changes is critically related to the extent to which the information (dis)advantage
arises from a marginal private information advantage in the current period, or from an
accumulation of superior private information signals in the past. To derive testable
implications from the model it will be necessary to make an assumption about the relative
magnitudes of the cumulative and marginal information advantages of domestic
investors.
7
To develop the implications of the model for international portfolio investment,
consider a setting in which there are M countries indexed m. The market portfolio of each
country is treated as a single risky asset, currency risk is ignored and assume that
investors in all countries have access to the same riskless asset whose return is zero.
Let
denote the measure of domestic investors in country m. Then, from equation (2),
the vector of conditional expected trades by investors in country m is given by:
m
µ
]
~
]
~
|/
~
[
~
[]
~
|
~
[
t
i
tttt
i
tt
i
t
PPrtXEPrPDE
+Γ=
ω
……(3)
Assuming that the contribution of noise traders in country m to the aggregate
supply shock, , is . Then, adding the trades on noise traders to those of the
(rational) investors, and dropping the time subscript, the expectation of the vector of
aggregate security purchases by all individuals in country m (including noise traders),
, conditional on the vector of prices changes, , is
t
X
~
t
m
X
~
µ
m
Π
~
P
~
E
[
]
PP
mm
~~
|
~
Θ=Π
(4)
where
[
]
mmm
r
ΓΘ
ω
, ,
di
i
mi
m
ωω
ε
di
i
mi
m
ε
Equation (4) implies that portfolio flows can be written as a linear function of
price changes in the M market portfolios plus an orthogonal error term. If there are no
differences in information precisions across countries, then
and portfolio
flows will be independent of market returns. If there are differences in information
endowments, the conditional expectations of portfolio flows will be linearly dependent on
the vector of price changes
0
==
mm
ω
2
.
2
Allowing for lagged decision making by foreign investors, the flows may be expressed as a linear
function of recent returns.
8
It may be noted that Brennan and Cao predict a positive relationship between
flows and recent returns on the assumption that the information of the locals is the result
of a gradual process of superior information acquisition rather than of periodic large
information leakages to locals. A negative relation is possible if neither investor has a
cumulative information advantage, but locals have a marginal informational advantage
(i.e. better access to news).
Based on equation (4) above we specify the model for the present analysis. The
portfolio inflows i.e. net purchases of stocks by FIIs (NFIIP) is modeled as a function of
recent returns on the market portfolio of only one country i.e. the host country. Our
model specification is thus as follows:
Model Specification
NFIIP
t
=
γ
R
t-1
Where
NFIIP
t
denotes net equity purchases by FIIs at time t.
R
t-1
denotes returns in the previous period. As our analysis is restricted to one
country, i.e. India, the FII equity demand is modeled as a function of the returns on the
market portfolio (index) of India as represented by R
t-1.
γ
>0 refers to the case of positive feedback traders.
γ
<0 indicates a case of
negative feedback trading. The negative feedback trader exhibits a “buy low, sell high
strategy” Negative feedback trading can result from profit taking as markets rise or from
investment strategies that target a constant share of wealth in different assets.
If indeed the trading by foreign investors is related with returns, there are several
views as to whether this reflects the informational advantage or disadvantage of foreign
investors. Further there are differing views on the possible creation of price pressure,
9
herding bias and destabilizing effects of trading by FIIs. Some theoretical rationales that
have been developed to explain the herding bias in investor trading are as follows:
Reputational Herding
3
, investors may disregard their private information and
trade with the crowd due to the reputational risk of acting differently from other
managers (Scharfstein and Stein (1990)).
Investigative Herding, managers may trade together simply because they receive
correlated private information, perhaps from analyzing the same indicators (Froot,
Scharfstein and Stein (1992)) and (Hershleifer, Subrahmanyam and Titman (1994)).
Informational cascades- managers may infer private information from prior trades
of better-informed managers and trade in the same direction (Bikchandani, Hershleifer
and Welch (1992)),
Institutional investors may share an aversion to stocks with certain characteristics,
such as stocks with lower liquidity or stocks that are less risky (Falkenstein 1996).
While there exist several alternative rationales to explain herding, there is not, to
our knowledge, any theoretical model that takes into account these alternative rationales
to derive explicit predictions regarding herding by different groups of investors.
Pioneering empirical work to quantify herding has been undertaken by Lakonishok,
Shleifer and Vishny (LSV 1992) and Wermers (1999). We follow both LSV and
Wermers to measure the extent of herding by FIIs in India.
3
In The General Theory, John Maynard Keynes (1936 pp. 157-58) expresses skepticism about the ability
and inclination of “long term investors” to buck market trends and ensure efficient investment. In his view,
investors may be reluctant to act according to their own information and beliefs, fearing that their
contrarion behavior will damage their reputation as sensible decision makers
10
IV. Data
Basic Data
The analysis is undertaken using daily data. Daily data give more precise results
and are better able to capture the lead – lag dynamics between net equity purchases by
FIIs and equity returns. However as a longer series on both the equity returns and the FII
equity purchase and sales with a monthly frequency is available some results based on
monthly data are also presented to gain further insight into the trading behavior of FIIs
based on long horizon returns
4
. The average of the daily closing values of the price index
is used to arrive at the monthly data.
The returns are calculated for the sensex. Sensex was a natural choice for
inclusion in the study, as it is the most popular market index and widely used by market
participants for benchmarking.
Returns are proxied by the log difference change in the price index.
R
t
= log P
t
– log P
t-1
R
t
= return at time t
P
t,
P
t-1
= closing value of the stock price index at time t, t-1.
Days when there is no trading are omitted and the price change is calculated from
the last day the market was open. Local currency returns are used
5
.
Data on FII equity purchases and sales on daily and monthly basis for our
reference period are used. This is as available from the Securities and Exchange Board of
India (SEBI).
4
Weekly data was also analyzed. The results are not reported as they were not significantly different from
those for monthly data.
5
Typically, local market securities settle in local currency.
11
Sample Period
In the daily analysis we are constrained by the availability of data. Daily data on
FII equity purchase and sales are available from January 2000 to December 2002.
January 2000 to December 2002 is therefore our reference period for the daily analysis.
On a monthly basis, however data for both the sensex and the FII equity purchase and
sales is available from January 1994 to December 2002 and so the analysis on the
monthly basis is undertaken for this reference period. A further sub sample analysis is
undertaken for the monthly data. The sub samples are drawn as per an endogenous break
date analysis for the total turnover series to examine if the FIIs alter their trading
strategies when the total turnover series reveals a structural break. For herding, the sub
samples are identified to examine if the FIIs reveal excess herding in times of pressure (a
financial crisis in the region i.e. the East Asian crisis) in the stock market.
Descriptive statistics
A brief summary of the descriptive statistics for net equity purchases by FIIs and
the equity returns in the Indian stock market over 2000 – 2002 are presented in the
Appendix. Data on the autocorrelation structure of daily net equity purchases by FIIs and
trading imbalance (normalized excess purchases) and daily returns upto five lag periods
are also presented. The extent of predictability in daily net equity purchases by FIIs is
positive but small. The positive autocorrelation could be on account of investors
responding to new information in the same direction but with different speeds or simply
because some investors establish positions slowly. The first order autocorrelation is .16
for the trading imbalance and .26 for excess equity purchases and this falls over
subsequent periods. The median autocorrelation in net daily equity purchases by FIIs is
.05. The first order autocorrelation in returns is even lower and turns negative at lag two.
Median autocorrelation in daily net returns is very small (-.0190) and negative.
12
V. Empirical Analysis
Our empirical analysis comprises three parts. In part one we examine if trading by
FIIs reveals any trends of positive feedback trading. In part two we examine if there is
evidence of herding by the FIIs. In the last part we analyze the destabilizing impact, if
any, of the FII trading strategies on stock prices in India.
V.1 Positive Feedback Trading
Positive feedback trading describes the strategy of rushing in when the markets are
booming and rushing out when the markets are on the decline. Hence it predicts a relation
between the past performance of the market (as indicated by the value of the market
index) and the current FII investment. Based on the model specified in section III we
estimate the following regression
6
:
TRIM
t =
γ
R
t-1
+
ε
t
…………………………………………………………………..(V.1)
where
TRIM, the dependent variable is defined as normalized trading imbalance of FIIs
i.e. excess purchases normalized by total trade undertaken by FIIs at time t
TRIM is conditioned on the sign of the market return of the previous day (R
t-1
), the same
day (R
t
) and the day after (R
t+1
).
γ
> 0 indicates positive feedback trading
γ
< 0 indicates a case of negative feedback trading
The model as in equation (V.1) is estimated and then analyzed in three stages as
follows:
6
Our regressions provide no test for informational advantage or otherwise that the FIIs may have.
13
i) Static Analysis
As a first step to estimating the bivariate model in equation (V.1) we do a Granger
–causality test. Granger causality test is used to eliminate the possibility of a simultaneity
bias in the model. Our results for the test show that market returns Granger-cause future
foreign investment flows in India. Thus ensuring one way causality in the model we
proceed with checking for the presence of a unit root in the two variables. Both the
Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) and Philips - Perron (PP) tests confirm that variables,
TRIM and Ret., are stationary. The model is then estimated under OLS assumptions.
ii) A Dynamic analysis using a VAR model
()
t
t
t
t
t
TRIM
R
L
TRIM
R
+
+=
1
1
βα
Where L indicates the lag structure
7
.
The above specified VAR
8
system is used to analyze the impact of innovations in
returns on trading imbalance. For this we specify the channels of causality using the
standard “identification by ordering” methodology. The channel of causality is as
established from the results of the Granger – causality test. The Impulse Response
Functions (IRFs) so generated allow us to trace the time path of the impact of shocks on
the variables contained in the VAR.
iii) As the flows are somewhat predictable, it might only be the unexpected or
surprise component of flows that is related to lagged returns. To test for this a
series of unexpected trading imbalance (UTRIM) on day t is constructed.
Unexpected TRIM was derived as actual imbalance less expected flows. Both the
14
7
We estimate the model with two lags as determined by the AIC and SBC criteria.
8
As both the variables are stationary the VAR model is estimated in levels.
static and dynamic specifications are re-estimated with the unpredictable
component of trading imbalance as the dependent variable. Specifically we ask
the question: do returns predict flows over and above the predictions of lagged
flows?
Results:
Static Model
The results of the Static estimation of equation (V.1) using both TRIM and
UTRIM as dependent variable are shown below in Table V.1:
Table V.1
Independent variables
Dependent Variable
Normalized Trade Imbalance
R
R (-1)
R(+1)
TRIM
.5309
(1.0052)
3.49
(6.8159)*
.936
(1.7735)
UTRIM
.6568
(1.2779)
3.62
(7.2785)
7
1.06
(2.0686)
Figures in parentheses are t ratios
* Significant at .5%
A significant and positive relation between lagged daily returns and trade
imbalance is observed. There is strong evidence that FIIs have been positive feedback
traders at the aggregate level tending to buy following good news in the equity market in
India. With UTRIM as dependent variable the results remain unchanged. A highly
significant indication of the unexpected component of the variable TRIM following
lagged returns is observed.
15
The similarity of results for both the regressions using TRIM and UTRIM as
dependent variables could be on account of a very small predictable component in both
the series. As indicated in section IV the extent of autocorrelation at lag one is only 16
per cent for TRIM and 26 per cent for net purchases.
The static regression analysis has also been undertaken for the monthly data
9
and
the results are as shown in Table V.2 below:
TABLE V.2
Independent variables
Dependent variable:
Normalized Trade Imbalance
TRIM
R R (-1) R(+1)
1994:02 2002:07
1994:02 1998:02
10
1998:03 2002:06
.514
(1.0284)
1.146
(1.1356)
-.047
(-.1794)
.177
(.3513)
.67
(.6429)
-.237
(-.903)
.633
(1.2354)
1.0327
(1.0027)
.276
(1.0486)
Figures in parentheses are t ratios
There is no indication of positive feedback trading in monthly data. For monthly
data on the unpredictable component of trading imbalance (UTRIM) there is no
indication of positive feedback trading at all
11
. On a monthly basis the series of TRIM are
9
Exogeneity of variables for monthly data is established using Granger causality and Hausman test. The
results of the latter are presented in the Appendix.
10
For monthly data the analysis is carried out for the full sample and two sub periods. The sub periods are
classified by an endogenous break date analysis. We carry out this structural break test for total turnover
series. The test yields 1998:02 as indicative of a break in the total turnover series. We then proceed to
examine if the structural break in the FII turnover is accompanied by a change in their trading strategies
also.
11
Results not presented here but available with the author.
16
highly autocorrelated. It is possible that the FII investment is not led by returns, that is the
FIIs are not indulging in return chasing but is led by their own trade on a monthly basis.
From the static regression estimation results we can conclude that FIIs buy following
high previous day stock returns but respond very little with respect to previous month
stock returns
Dynamic Analysis (VAR)
The graphs for the Impulse Response Functions (IRFs) as generated by the
bivariate VAR model are shown in Figures 1 and 2 for lagged daily returns and lagged
monthly returns respectively. The response of TRIM to one S.E error shock to returns on
the previous day is sharp, significant but short lived. For the unexpected flows the lagged
returns are highly significant and the impact as seen through the Impulse Response
graphs trace a very sharp response of the UTRIM to lagged returns. The impact however
dies very soon. For monthly returns no significant feedback trading is observed
Figure 1: Response to a Shock to Lagged Daily Returns
-0.05
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of TRIM to RET(-1)
Response to One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.
-0.05
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of UTRIM to RET(-1)
Response to One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.
17
Figure 2: Response to a Shock to Lagged Monthly Returns
-10
0
10
20
30
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Res pons e of TRIM to RET(-1)
Response to One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.
-10
0
10
20
30
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of UTRIM to RET(-1)
Response to One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.
The analysis using the VAR model reinforces our conclusion from the static
estimation i.e. FIIs undertake significant positive feedback trading in relation to lagged
daily returns.
As the data reveals a strong tendency for the FIIs to indulge in positive feedback
trading over short horizons, we examine further if the FIIs show a herding bias in their
trading behavior. Before doing so, we briefly recapitulate our conclusions of the analysis
on positive feedback trading by FIIs in the Indian equity market.
Positive Feedback Trading: Conclusions
There is strong evidence that FIIs have been positive feedback investors at the
aggregate level on daily basis.
- FIIs in India are “return chasers” and/or “momentum traders”
A shock to current returns increases flows significantly but the impact is short-lived
The trend chasing - momentum trading characteristic of the FIIs meets the more
stringent test as well
18
- Lagged daily returns help in predicting daily flows over and above the
predictability of past flows
FIIs do not follow their own daily trade. This is evident from the low predictable
component FII net equity purchases by FIIs.
Popular financial press hypothesis of flows impacting returns does not hold true for
India
The trading Horizon of FIIs is possibly a day and not a month
V.2 Herding
In this section we evaluate the extent to which the FIIs herd. Herding or
correlated trading refers to a tendency for a particular investor group’s trade to
accumulate on one side of the market or the other without regard to direction.
Measurement of Herding
We assume that the market comprises of two groups of traders, foreign investors
and domestic investors. We calculate herding from the foreign investor’s perspective
. We
follow the measure proposed by Lakonishok, Shleifer and Vishny [LSV (1992)] and
Wermers (1998) to investigate the extent of herding by FIIs in India. The LSV measure is
as follows:
HM = | p(t) – E[p(t)]| - E| p(t) – E[p(t)]| ……………………………….. (V.2)
where
p (t) is the proportion of “buy” trade by FIIs on day t.
E| p (t)-E[p (t)] | is the adjustment factor to allow for random variation around the
expected proportion of “buys” under the null hypothesis of independent trading decisions
by FIIs. The adjustment factor assumes that p(t) follows a binomial distribution with the
probability E[p(t)] of success. For E[p (t)] a proxy that is the average “buy” trade during
the entire period of reference is used.
19
Implicitly equation (V.2) defines and measures herding as the tendency of a
subgroup of investors to trade a given stock (in our case stock index) together and in the
same direction, more often than would be expected by investors trading randomly and
independently
12
. The average of HM over the entire sample period gives the extent to
which FIIs herd in India. A positive and significant HM
13
is evidence of herding by FIIs.
Modified Herding Measure
We also use a modified herding measure (Wermers-1999) to examine if in a
particular period the FIIs were buying (or selling) in a proportion greater than the average
trade during that period. For monthly data this conditional measure is further examined
for a time period of excessive pressure (financial crisis in the region – East Asian crisis)
to see if the trading pattern by the FIIs in this period is any different from the other “more
normal” time period. The relation between the conditional and unconditional measure is
as follows:
Buy Herding Measure: BHM (t) = HM (t)|p (t)>E[p (t)]
Sell Herding Measure: SHM (t) = HM (t)|p (t)<E[p (t)]
Average of BHM and SHM will reveal if the FIIs herd into or out of the Indian
stock market at any time point. In computing these measures we are assuming that each
trade is originating from different institutional investors. It is possible otherwise that
herding may be on account of the same investor executing multiple trades. We however
do not have data to this level of detail and hence the assumption.
12
The LSV measure uses only the number of investors on the two sides of the market, without regard to the
extent of trade that they indulge in, to assess the extent of herding. In situations where, if the buyers and
sellers on either side are same in number but one side exceeds the other in terms of its trade (i.e. buy or sell
imbalance) the LSV measure may not be able to capture herding even though it may exist in the market.
We hope to correct for this deficiency in the LSV measure as we use the trade (buy) imbalance rather than
the number of FIIs on either side of the market.
13
The herding measure may be thought of as a measure of dispersion.
20
We compute the herding measure using daily and monthly horizon. The results for the
herding measures are presented in Table V.3 below.
Results:
Table V.3: Herding Measures (%)
LSV Herding
Measure (%)
Conditional HM (%)
BHM SHM
Daily (full sample)
Monthly (full sample)
Sub period (EA crisis)
Pre sub period
9.41
14.72
13.31
24.02
9.04
14.31
6.79
22.6
9.82
15.16
20.97
26.5
Daily data extends from January 4, 2000 to December 30, 2002.
Monthly data extends from January 1994 to December 2002
EA crisis sub period is defined as July 1997 to December 1998.
Both daily and monthly data indicate herding. Herding by foreign investors on a
daily basis averages 9.41 per cent
14
. This implies that the extent to which trade by FIIs
accumulates on one side of the market is 9.41 per cent higher than the expected had the
FIIs trade been independent and random. For monthly data the HM measure is higher at
14.72. The higher HM for the monthly time period may imply that not all FIIs that move
together do so on the same day.
While daily and monthly HM do not reveal any significant difference in the buy
and sell side herding, even though there is a sell side bias in herding it is not very
significant. This however becomes very significant in times of pressure in the region as
revealed by our monthly data results for the sub - period coinciding with the East Asian
crisis. The sub - period shows a distinct pattern of heavy sell side herdingin comparison
14
Note that this HM value is more than that reported by Kim and Wei (2002) and Bonser – Neal et al(2002)
for pre crisis Korea and Indonesia respectively.
21
with the buy side herding during a crisis in comparison with HM prior to the pressure
period. There is a spectacular fall in the HM from pre crisis to crisis period on the buy
side and the fall though not as spectacular as for the buy side is also observed on the sell
side. This could be due to a differential reaction of the investors or because of lack of
liquidity of markets as crisis evolved. It is easier for investors to trade on the same side if
the liquidity is high than when the markets dry up.
The results indicate that foreign investors have a tendency to herd in the Indian
equity market even though they all may not do it on the same day. In times of pressure in
the stock market, on account of a financial crisis in the region there is excessive sell side
herding even though the extent of herding on the average and on either side of the market
during a crisis may be lower than that in the immediately preceding period
V.3 Destabilizing?
In the previous sections, we find evidence that foreign investors engage in herding
and positive feedback trading strategies in the Indian stock market. There has been
considerable debate on whether such trading strategies have adverse impacts on the
financial markets of emerging market economies. Neither positive feedback trading nor
herding may necessarily be destabilizing. The concern about positive feedback trading
however is that it makes stock prices overshoot to new information. Consequently, if
trades by FIIs destabilize markets, we would expect large sales (buys) by FIIs that
decrease (increases) prices to be followed by further price declines (increases).
On examining the data we observe that the days of “buy” imbalance follow
positive index returns, so that FIIs buy following price increases. The price increase
usually does not continue after the purchase by FIIs. In fact same sign (to the trade
imbalance) contemporaneous returns are also not observed. The reverse holds true for
“sell” imbalances. In case of events where price increase persists the returns are
insignificantly different from zero. This implies that even though trading by FIIs reveals
22
trend -chasing behavior there is no consequent persistent impact on prices or returns in
the market.
To investigate further if FIIs have a destabilizing effect on the equity market in
India, we use the event study methodology. We select days of largest buy order and sell
order imbalance. For each of the selected events we examine abnormal returns (based on
constant mean return model) from the preceding five (-5) to the following five (+5) days.
In Table VI.1 below we present the returns and abnormal returns for one such event.
Table Vl.1
Days Relative to the FII Trade Imbalance (Day 0)
-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5
"Sell"
Raw Returns -0.03 0.004 -0.007 -0.003 0.011 0.009 0.019 0.001 -0.012 0.019 0.024
AR -0.015 0.029 0.018 0.022 0.014 0.034 0.026 0.013 0.006 0.006 0.044
"Buy"
Raw Returns -0.005 -0.001 0.034 0.002 0.016 0.006 -0.005 0.006 -0.001 0.007 0.001
AR -0.014 -0.01 0.025 0.007 -0.007 -0.003 -0.04 -0.003 -0.01 -0.002 -0.002
In general, on a day of positive net buy order imbalance the abnormal returns
show a negative sign while the reverse is true of the days of net sell order imbalance. The
FIIs therefore do not appear to have a destabilizing influence on stock prices.
VI. Conclusions
In this paper daily and monthly data has been analyzed to explore the trading
behavior of FIIs and the impact of their trading biases upon stock market stability. It is
found that there is strong evidence that FIIs have been positive feedback investors and
trend chasers at the aggregate level on a daily basis. However, there is no evidence of
positive feedback trading on a monthly basis. There are almost no joint dynamics
between long horizon returns and net equity purchases. The results of our analysis also
indicate that foreign investors have a tendency to herd on the Indian equity market even
though they all may not do it on the same day. In times of pressure in the stock market on
23
account of a financial crisis in the region there is excessive sell side herding even though
the extent of herding on the average and on either side of the market during a crisis may
be lower than that in the immediately preceding period. On investigating the impact of
trading imbalance across days we do not find any significant evidence that would make it
possible to attribute equity market instability to FIIs.
24
Appendix
I. Summary Statistics: 2000-2002
Variable
Mean
Median
S.D.
1
ρ
2
ρ
3
ρ
4
ρ
5
ρ
TRIM 0.056838 0.070316 0.24226 0.169 0.149 0.132 0.105 0.07
RET -0.000652 0.000473 0.017237 0.071 -0.015 -0.034 0.035 -0.011
NFIIP 30.85261 21.10 132.508 0.261 0.203 0.181 0.133 0.035
II. Stationarity
Unit Root Tests
TRIM
Test t statistic Critical value Inference(1%)
ADF -9.821 3.4417 No unit root
PP -21.8323 3.4417 No unit root
Ret
Test t statistic Critical value Inference(1%)
ADF -12.1304 3.4417 No unit root
PP -25.3946 3.4417 No unit root
25
III.A. Exogeneity
Granger Causality tests
Null Hypothesis F statistic Critical Value Inference
TRIM does not Granger cause Ret 4.27 6.68 Not reject
TRIM does not Granger cause Ret 31.24 6.68 Reject
The inference is drawn at 1 per cent level of significance but is valid at 5% also.
III.B. Hausman Test
Variable Coefficient t-statistic
C 3.80 .6799
Ret 421.85 .2954
Resid. Ret -362.17 -.2543
26
References
Bekaert, Geert and Campbell R. Harvey, 2003. ‘Emerging Markets Finance’, Journal of
Empirical Finance 10, 3-55.
Bikhchandani, Sushil, David Hirshleifer, and Ivo Welch, 1992, ‘A Theory of Fads,
Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades’, Journal of
Political Economy 100, 992-1026.
Bohn, H., and L. Tesar, 1996, ‘U. S. Equity Investment in Foreign Markets: Portfolio
Rebalancing or Return Chasing?’, American Economic Review 86 (2), 77-81.
Bonser-Neal, C, Steven L. Jones, David Linman and Robert Neal, 2002, Herding,
Feedback Trading and Foreign Investors. Indiana University.
Brennan, M., and H. Cao, 1997, ‘International Portfolio Investment Flows’, Journal Of
Finance 52, 1851-1880.
Chakrabarti, Rajesh, FII Flows to India: Nature and Causes, Georgia Institute of
Technology.
Choe, Y., B. C. Kho, and R. M. Stulz, 1998, ‘Do Foreign Investors Destabilize Stock
Markets? The Korean Experience in 1997’, NBER Working Paper 6661, NBER
Cambridge M A.
Choe, Y., B. C. Kho, and R. M. Stulz, 1998, ‘Do Domestic Investors Have More
Valuable Information about Individual Stocks than Foreign Investors?’, NBER
Working Paper 8073
Claessens, Stijn, Susmita Dasgupta and Jack Glen. 1995, ‘Return Behavior in Emerging
Stock Markets’, World Bank Eonomic Review (January) 131-151.
27
Clark, J., and E. Berko,1997, ‘Foreign Investment Fluctuations and Emerging Market
Stock Returns: The Case of Mexico’, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Staff
Reports 24.
Dornbusch, R. and Y.C.Park, 1995, ‘Financial Integration in a Second Best World: Are
We Sure About Our Classical Prejudices’, in R. Dornbusch and Y.C. Park, eds.,
Financial Opening: Policy Lessons for Korea, Korea Institute of Finance, Seoul,
Korea.
Froot, K., O’ Connell, P., and M. Seasholes, 2001, ‘The Portfolio Flows of International
Investors’, Journal of Financial Economics 59, 151-193
Froot, Kenneth A., David S. Scharfstein, and Jeremy C. Stein, 1992, ‘Herd on The Street:
Informational Inefficiencies in a Market with Short-Term Speculation’, Journal of
Finance 47, 1461-1484.
Gooptu, Sudarshan. 1993, ‘Portfolio Flows to Emerging Markets, in Portfolio Investment
in Developing Countries’, World Bank Discussion Paper ed. by Stijn Claessens
and Sudarshan Gooptu (Washington: World Bank).
Grinblatt, M., S. Titman and R. Wermers, 1995, ‘Momentum Investment Strategies,
Portfolio Performance, and Herding’, American Economic Review 85, 1088-1105.
Griffin John M., F. Nardari and Rene M. Stulz, 2002, ‘Daily Cross Border Equity Flows:
Pushed of Pulled?’ NBER Working Paper 9000.
Hamao, Y., and J. Mei. 2001, ‘Living with the “Enemy”: An Analysis of Investment in
the Japanese Equity Market’, Journal of International Money and Finance 20:
715-730
28
Hirshleifer, David, Avanidhar Subrahmanayam, and Sheridan Titman, 1994, ‘Security
Analysis and Trading Patterns when Some Investors Receive Information Before
Others’, Journal of Finance 49, 1665-1698.
Hirshleifer, David and Siew Hong Teoh, 2001, ‘Herd Behavior and Cascading in Capital
Markets: A Review and Synthesis’, Working Paper, Ohio State University.
Howell, Michael J. 1993, ‘Institutional Investors and Emerging Stock Markets, in
Portfolio Investment in Developing Countries’, World Bank Discussion Paper ed.
By Stijn Claessens and Sudarshan Gooptu (Washington: World Bank).
Kim, W., and S.Wei, 2002, ‘Foreign Portfolio Investors Before and During A Crisis’,
Journal of International Economics 51, 77-96.
Lakonishok, Josef, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny, 1992, ‘The Impact of
Institutional Trading on Stock Prices’, Journal of Financial Economics 32, 23-44.
Nofsinger, John R. and Richard W. Sias, 1999, ‘Herding and Feedback Trading by
Institutional and Individual Investors’, Journal of Finance, 54, 6, December 2263-
2295.
Richards, Anthony, 2002, ‘Big Fish in Small Ponds: The Momentum Investing and Price
Impact of Foreign Investors in Asian Emerging Equity Markets’, Reserve Bank of
Australia and IMF.
Samal, Kishore C., 1997. Emerging Equity Market in India: Role of Foreign Institutional
Investors, Economic and Political Weekly, October 18, 2729-2732.
Scharfstein, David S. and Jeremy C. Stein, 1990, ‘Herd Behavior and Investment’,
American Economic Review 80, 465-479.
29
Seasholes, M., 2001, ‘Smart Foreign Traders in Emerging Markets’, Unpublished
working paper, University of California, Berkeley.
Sias, Richard W., and John R. Nofsiger, 1998, ‘Herding and Feedback Trading by
Institutional and Individual Investors’, Unpublished working paper, Washington
State University.
Sias, Richard W., and Laura T. Starks, 1997, ‘Return Auto-correlation and Institutional
Investors’, Journal of Financial Economics 46, 103-131.
Sias, Richard W., 2001, ‘The Behavior of Institutional Investors: Tests for Herding,
Stealth Trading, and Momentum Trading’.
Warther, V., 1995, ‘Aggregate Mutual Fund Flows and Security Returns’, Journal of
Financial Economics.
Wermers, Russ, 1999, ‘Mutual Fund Herding and The Impact on Stock Prices’, Journal
of Finance 2, 581-622.
30