Working Paper Series
Financial stability considerations in
the conduct of monetary policy
Paul Bochmann, Daniel Dieckelmann,
Stephan Fahr, Josef Ruzicka
Disclaimer: This paper should not be reported as representing the views of the European Central Bank
(ECB). The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the ECB.
No 2870
Abstract
We empirically analyze the interaction of monetary policy with financial stability and the
real economy in the euro area. For this, we apply a quantile vector autoregressive model
and two alternative estimation approaches: simulation and local projections. Our specifi-
cations include monetary policy surprises, real GDP, inflation, financial vulnerabilities and
systemic financial stress. We disentangle conventional and unconventional monetary policy
by separating interest rate surprises into two factors that move the yield curve either at the
short end or at the long end. Our results show that a build-up of financial vulnerabilities
tends to be accompanied initially by subdued financial stress which resurges, however, over
a medium-term horizon, harming economic growth. Tighter conventional monetary policy
reduces inflationary pressures but increases the risk of financial stress. We find unconven-
tional monetary policy to be similarly effective in reducing inflation, but with a lower adverse
effect on growth and financial stress. Tighter unconventional monetary policy is also found
to have a dampening effect on the build-up of financial vulnerabilities.
Keywords: monetary policy, financial stability, macroprudential policy, quantile regres-
sions, monetary policy identification.
JEL codes: E31, E52, G01, G10.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
Non-technical summary
The interplay of monetary policy, financial conditions and the real economy has been part of
a long-standing macro-financial debate. Monetary policy transmits to the real economy by
affecting financial conditions which themselves are taken into consideration in the conduct of
monetary policy to stabilize inflation and the real economy. In this transmission process, mon-
etary policy may enhance financial stability during slowdowns by supporting the debt servicing
capacity of economic and financial sectors, while tighter monetary policy during exuberant times
can attempt to mitigate financial imbalances by implicitly leaning against the wind of frothy
market conditions.
By expanding the empirical quantile regression framework of Chavleishvili and Kremer (2021)
to include monetary policy shocks, inflation and financial vulnerabilities we analyze the inter-
action of monetary policy with financial stability conditions and the real economy. We estimate
impulse response functions of a quantile vector autoregressive model via two estimation tech-
niques. First, using a simulation approach, following Ruzicka (2021b), and, second, using local
projections as in Ruzicka (2021a). These quantile methods capture potential asymmetries in the
interactions between economic activity, financial stability variables and monetary policy over
the full distribution of the variables. Our specifications contain a range of interest rate shocks
along the euro area yield curve as measure for monetary policy, euro area real GDP, euro area
HICP inflation, the Systemic Risk Indicator (SRI) of Lang et al. (2019) as a measure of financial
vulnerabilities and the Composite Indicator of Systemic Stress (CISS) of Hollo et al. (2012) as
a measure of financial stress. All models are estimated on monthly euro area data from 2002 to
2019.
Our results show that surging financial stress has a strong short-term impact on economic
growth, especially on the lower tail of the GDP distribution, in line with Adrian et al. (2018). A
build-up of financial vulnerabilities tends to initially be accompanied by subdued financial stress,
but financial stress surges over the medium term. Finally, tightening conventional monetary
policy reduces real GDP growth and inflationary pressures accompanied by increasing financial
stress. Unconventional monetary policy, such as quantitative easing, identified as surprises
in longer-term interest rates are found to be similarly effective in reducing inflation but have
a smaller ’sacrifice ratio’ for GDP growth and financial stress. We also find that financial
vulnerabilities tend to mildly recede following tighter unconventional monetary policy.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
The empirical results lend themselves to counterfactual analysis on the trade-offs that mon-
etary policy faces when pursuing price stability. The implemented exercises using 1-year ahead
forecasts reveal that monetary policy has faced a trade-off during the global financial crisis:
either tighten to stabilize inflation forecasts at 2% or loosen to curb stress and prevent tail risks
to economic growth to increase.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
1 Introduction
The interplay of monetary policy, financial conditions and the real economy has been part
of a long-standing macro-financial debate. Monetary policy transmits to the real economy to a
large extent by affecting financial conditions. Equally, monetary policy takes financial conditions
into account to stabilize inflation and the real economy (Mishkin, 2007; European Central Bank,
2021). During slowdowns monetary policy can enhance financial stability by supporting the debt
servicing capacity of the non-financial sector and by containing losses for the financial sector.
In the extreme event of a financial crisis, monetary policy especially through liquidity support
is crucial to contain financial stress and to avoid the materialisation of adverse equilibria
(Mishkin, 2009; Bekaert et al., 2013). At the same time, however, the theoretical literature
suggests that accommodative monetary policy could create financial vulnerabilities by raising
asset values, lowering risk premia, increasing leverage and increasing maturity and liquidity
mismatches (Ajello et al., 2022).
During financial exuberant times tighter monetary policy can help mitigate financial im-
balances by implicitly leaning against the wind of frothy market conditions. This would help
reduce the likelihood and severity of future financial crises. However, the empirical evidence on
the general effect of monetary policy on financial vulnerabilities and its effectiveness in leaning
against the wind is mixed and entails trade-offs (Svensson, 2017; Kockerols and Kok, 2019; Schu-
larick et al., 2021; Boyarchenko et al., 2022). One monetary policy trade-off involves interactions
between macro variables such as inflation and GDP growth, and financial stability, as measured
by financial stress and vulnerabilities. A second trade-off in the conduct of monetary policy
relates to the management of tail risks for the real economy relative to tail risks for financial
stability. Finally, an intertemporal trade-off relates the potential impact of monetary policy on
short-term financial stress relative to adjustments to economic and financial vulnerabilities in
the medium-term.
In this paper, we empirically analyze the interaction of monetary policy shocks, financial
stability conditions and the real economy in the euro area. We do so by estimating impulse re-
sponse functions of a quantile vector autoregressive model via two estimation techniques, namely
through simulation, following Ruzicka (2021b), and local projections as in Ruzicka (2021a). The
specifications include five variables: a range of interest rates from the euro area yield curve
as measure for monetary policy, euro area real GDP, euro area HICP inflation, the Composite
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
Indicator of Systemic Stress (CISS) of Hollo et al. (2012) as a measure of financial stress, and
the Systemic Risk Indicator (SRI) of Lang et al. (2019) as a measure of financial vulnerabilities.
Importantly, quantile methods capture potential asymmetries in the interactions between eco-
nomic activity (GDP and inflation), financial stability conditions (SRI and CISS) and monetary
policy shocks over the full distribution of the variables, including for impulse response analysis.
While macroeconomic conditions are typically summarized by real GDP and inflation, fi-
nancial stability conditions are less clearly defined. The SRI is our vulnerability metric and
characterizes the general state of the financial environment and serves as a ‘barometer’ for the
financial system (Duprey and Roberts, 2017). In exuberant times with elevated vulnerabilities,
the propagation of small shocks may result in amplifications for the economy, absent in normal
times (Lang et al., 2019). While vulnerability indicators contain forward-looking information,
they provide only limited information for the materialisation of stress at a specific point in time
in the future, given the uncertainty surrounding the future materialisation of shocks. For this,
our stress metric, the CISS, captures the materialization of financial instability and serves as
a ‘thermometer’ for the financial system (Chavleishvili and Kremer, 2021). The distinction of
financial vulnerability and stress is especially important to capture the intertemporal relation
between the initial build-up of vulnerabilities and subsequent downside tail risks to the financial
system and real economy.
Similarly to financial conditions, the monetary policy stance is only imperfectly summarized
by the short-term policy interest rate, given purchases of longer-term securities. Since the global
financial crisis, central banks have made active use of their balance sheets and forward guid-
ance. Monetary policy rates predominantly impact short-term market rates, forward guidance
affects interest rates further into the future, and purchases of medium- to long-term securities
affect interest rates over longer maturities. To capture monetary policies and their effects in an
empirical macro-financial estimation framework, we use monetary policy surprises in risk-free in-
terest rates between one month and ten years over a narrow time window (covering press release
and subsequent press conference) around the communication of ECB monetary policy decisions
contained in the “Euro Area Monetary Policy Event-Study Database” developed and regularly
updated by Altavilla et al. (2019). From these surprises we estimate a short- and long-term
factor of interest rate surprises and identify monetary policy shocks following G¨urkaynak et al.
(2005), Jaroci´nski and Karadi (2020) and Giuzio et al. (2021). The approach separates surprises
related to conventional monetary policy (short-term rates) from those related to unconventional
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
monetary policy (longer-term maturities).
Our results show that surging financial stress has a strong short-term impact on economic
growth, especially on the lower tail of the GDP distribution, in line with earlier findings such
as Adrian et al. (2018). We also find that while a build-up of financial vulnerabilities tends
to initially be accompanied by subdued financial stress i.e. below-average financial market
volatility, risk-pricing and excess returns stress surges over the medium term. This provides
for evidence that financial market tranquility during the initial phase of a financial expansion
hits back with a vengeance down the road. Finally, the estimation indicates that tightening
conventional monetary policy reduces inflationary pressures at the cost of slower real GDP
growth and surging financial stress. Tightening unconventional monetary policy, identified as
surprises in longer-term interest rates, is found to be similarly effective in reducing inflation
as shorter-term rates, but has a smaller impact on growth and financial stress, while financial
vulnerabilities mildly recede. This indicates that conventional and unconventional monetary
policies may at times be complementary for stabilizing the economy and financial system.
The empirical results allow for a quantitative assessment of monetary policy using coun-
terfactuals to shed light on monetary policy trade-offs in its pursuit of price stability. A first
counterfactual traces out the effects of monetary policy on Growth-at-Risk (GaR; the 10th per-
centile of the forecasted GDP growth distribution one year ahead) when setting price stability
at the objective of 2% annual inflation. Especially during the global financial crisis, monetary
policy faced a trade-off: either tightening to stabilizing inflation forecasts at 2% or loosening
to prevent Growth-at-Risk to deteriorate. This analysis indicates the potential beneficial use of
alternative policy measures to offer a complementary angle for stabilisation of the real economy.
Having established the relative efficiency of different policy tools, we illustrate how the esti-
mation results could inform a monetary and macroprudential policy mix to enhance stabilisation
over the sample period. We assume policy objectives of a 2% median inflation forecast one year
ahead and stabilization of GaR at its sample average of -1.08%. Given the relative efficiencies
the policymaker uses a mix of monetary policy (long-end interest rate factor) and macropruden-
tial policy (SRI). The GaR objective is non-symmetric, implying that the policymaker avoids
that GaR falls below the value of -1.08% while focussing solely on the objective of inflation
otherwise. The policymakers thus provides a hedge against crisis outcomes. We compute the
needed counterfactual policies based on the cumulated impulse response functions and find that
relatively large monetary policy shocks would have been needed to bring inflation forecasts back
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
to their target over the period 2005 until the first half of 2009. In contrast, over the earlier as
well as later parts of the sample period our results would have called for looser monetary policy.
Our results also indicate that looser macroprudential policy would have been needed starting
in September 2007 and throughout the global financial crises until September 2009 and again
on a few occasions during the euro area debt crisis to maintain GaR above its historical value.
Forecasts implied by these policy counterfactuals show that they would have been effective in
meeting combined inflation and growth targets, while limiting financial stress.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 reviews the core elements
of financial stability conditions and monetary policy in the recent literature. In section 3 we
describe our data set, including the indicators used to measure financial stability conditions
and the identification of monetary policy shocks. Next, in section 4 we describe the econometric
specifications. Section 5 presents impulse responses from our quantile vector autoregressions and
uncovers the dynamic interactions of financial vulnerabilities and stress with the real economy,
and the impact of monetary policy shocks. Section 6 covers counterfactual analysis and illus-
trates trade-offs between price stability and financial stability objectives for monetary policy.
It further assesses interactions between monetary policy and macroprudential policy. Finally,
section 7 concludes.
2 Monetary policy and financial stability interactions
Monetary policy frameworks around the globe focus on price stability as their main objective,
often accompanied with additional objectives such as full employment or financial stability.
Monetary policy’s role for financial stability is often subsumed in the effectiveness of monetary
policy transmission or delegated to other policy domains such as macroprudential policy. While
it is generally accepted that monetary policy takes financial stability into account at least in
some form, quantitative trade-offs are less prominent in the literature. Smets (2014) indicates
that the degree to which monetary policy should take financial stability considerations into
account depends crucially on its effectiveness in addressing risks to financial stability, but also
to what degree the financial stability considerations undermine the credibility of the central
bank’s price stability mandate.
Monetary policy faces several challenges when including financial stability considerations.
First, narrow indicators of financial conditions, stress and vulnerabilities (such as metrics of
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
risk-taking, liquidity and leverage) offer only partial measures of financial stability, especially
when considered in isolation, but are not fully comprehensive of prevailing financial stability
conditions. In turn, monetary policy instruments are multiple, and each one may interact differ-
ently with financial stability. Furthermore, at least theoretically, monetary policy may create an
inter-temporal trade-off for financial stability whereby accommodative monetary policy improves
current financial conditions in the short run at the cost of increasing future financial vulnerabil-
ities Adrian and Liang (2018). Empirically, it appears unclear to date whether monetary policy
itself can influence financial vulnerabilities, partly because financial cycles are typically much
longer than the business cycles monetary policy reacts to (Boyarchenko et al., 2022). Ultimately,
monetary policy’s efficacy as a tool for financial stability will depend on the cost-benefit trade-off
of tighter monetary policy for economic activity and inflation.
Our paper relates to different strands of the literature. First, we contribute to the literature
that investigates the empirical relationship between monetary policy and financial stability. The
primary focus of existing studies lies on financial vulnerabilities. However, a (surprise) monetary
tightening could also lead to acute episodes of surging financial stress and an abrupt tightening
of financial conditions. Recent literature (Adrian et al., 2019; Figueres and Jaroci´nski, 2020)
points to the importance of associated indicators for short-term (up to one year ahead) downside
risks to economic growth. Boyarchenko et al. (2022) provide a recent and detailed review of the
empirical literature studying the relationship between monetary policy and financial vulnerabil-
ities. Overall, the authors conclude that empirical evidence on the link between monetary policy
and financial vulnerabilities is limited.
However, the current literature does not rule out causal effects of monetary policy on finan-
cial vulnerabilities. Several research gaps emerge from this existing literature, some of which our
paper attempts to fill: Existing studies focus primarily on the United States while analyses for
the euro area are scarce. Furthermore, existing studies differ in their measurement of financial
vulnerabilities and focus mostly on narrow concepts such as asset valuations in selected mar-
kets, risk-taking by banks or other intermediaries, leverage and liquidity-maturity mismatches
or leverage of financial intermediaries, households and businesses. However, vulnerabilities that
have material impacts on the real economy appear to emerge from the interplay of asset prices
and credit (Jord`a et al., 2015) and we therefore employ a broad indicator of financial vulnera-
bilities in this paper.
Second, we estimate the dynamic interactions of macroeconomic, financial and monetary pol-
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
icy variables using multivariate quantile regression techniques. Quantile regressions of Koenker
and Bassett Jr (1978) have been extended to multivariate dynamic frameworks in various
ways. One approach involves multiple equations and iteration or simulation (White et al.,
2015; Chavleishvili and Manganelli, 2019; Montes-Rojas, 2022; Ruzicka, 2021b). The other ap-
proach focuses on a single-equation setup and direct estimation through local projections of
Jord`a (2005) in combination with quantile regression a prominent example is the work of
Adrian et al. (2019). Identification, smooth estimation, and inference for quantile regression
local projections is studied by Ruzicka (2021a). A unique feature of our paper is that we employ
both estimation approaches by using the methods from Ruzicka (2021b) as well as from Ruzicka
(2021a). Doing so, we obtain two valid estimates, which trade off bias and variance of impulse
response functions differently. In a least squares regression setting, Plagborg-Møller and Wolf
(2021) show that at shorter forecast horizons local projections are comparable with structural
vector autoregressions (Sims, 1980, SVAR), whereas at longer forecast horizons the local pro-
jections have lower bias but higher variance. We expect that the same phenomenon arises in a
quantile regression setting, as well.
Third, our assessment of the impact of monetary policy on financial stability focuses on an
assessment of the tails of the distribution of real economic and financial variables. The estimation
provides impacts for the lower and upper quantiles of these distributions and offers thereby risk
considerations beyond the impact on median or average effects. This relates to other work on the
stance of monetary and macroprudential policy using quantile reqressions, such as in Cecchetti
(2006), Kilian and Manganelli (2008), Duprey and Ueberfeldt (2018), Aikman et al. (2019)
and Carney (2020). The common feature of these approaches resides in the use of the tail of
forecasted variables to infer assessment of risks to the economy or a policy stance. And finally,
we relate to the empirical literature that identifies effects of monetary policy on asset prices
and the macroeconomy using high-frequency financial market surprises around central bank
monetary policy announcements going back to Kuttner (2001), as well as literature about the
identification of monetary policy from such event-study data (G¨urkaynak et al., 2005; Altavilla
et al., 2019; Jaroci´nski and Karadi, 2020; Giuzio et al., 2021).
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
3 Financial stability indicators and identification of monetary
policy shocks
Our data consists of a set of aggregate euro area macro-financial and monetary policy variables,
starting in the beginning of 2002 and running through the end of June 2019 at monthly frequency.
Our baseline model input consists of two macroeconomic variables, namely real GDP growth
and HICP inflation, the Composite Indicator of Systemic Stress (CISS) as a measure of financial
stress (Hollo et al., 2012; Chavleishvili and Kremer, 2021), and the Systemic Risk Indicator
(Lang et al., 2019, SRI) as a measure of financial vulnerabilities,monetary policy shocks built
from surprise rate changes over narrow time windows covering the communication of monetary
policy decisions through press release and the subsequent press conference on ECB Governing
Council monetary policy meeting dates using a data set developed and regularly updated by
Altavilla et al. (2019). The computation of these shocks is explained in detail further below in
Section 3.3.
Figure 1 plots the macro-financial variables used in our estimation which are further sum-
marized in Table 1. We deliberately represent financial stability aspects in our models with
two separate variables, distinguishing between short-term financial stress which can trigger in-
stability and medium-term vulnerabilities which make the financial system more susceptible to
destabilizing triggers. We approximate monthly GDP by interpolating a quarterly GDP series
with a monthly index of industrial production for the euro area.
3.1 Financial stress
The CISS serves as our measure of financial stress and captures the severity of financial crises,
serving as a ‘thermometer’ of financial instability. It is a timely, frequent and publicly available
indicator based on 15 individual indicators grouped into five sub-indices: financial intermediaries,
bond markets, equity markets, foreign exchange markets, and money markets. The contribution
from financial intermediaries is around 30%, that of equity markets around 25%, and each of
the three remaining sub-indexes around 15%.
1
Importantly, the CISS takes into account the
1
The equity market sub-index comprises stock price volatility of non-financial corporations (NFC), a measure
of maximum cumulated stock price losses and a measure of stock-bond correlation. The FX market sub-index
captures the volatility of EUR/USD, EUR/JPY and EUR/GBP exchange rates. The financial intermediaries
sub-index reflects bank stock return volatility, financial-nonfinancial bonds spread, and the cumulated loss of the
book-price ratio of banks. The bond market sub-index captures the volatility of German sovereign bonds (at
10-year maturity), the spread between A-rated NFC and sovereign bonds, and the 10Y interest rate swap spread.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
10
Figure 1: Macro-financial variables, monthly
2
1.5
1
0.5
0
0.5
1
1.5
2002M1
2003M1
2004M1
2005M1
2006M1
2007M1
2008M1
2009M1
2010M1
2011M1
2012M1
2013M1
2014M1
2015M1
2016M1
2017M1
2018M1
2019M1
RealGDPgrowth
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
2002M1
2003M1
2004M1
2005M1
2006M1
2007M1
2008M1
2009M1
2010M1
2011M1
2012M1
2013M1
2014M1
2015M1
2016M1
2017M1
2018M1
2019M1
HICPinflation
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
1
2002M1
2003M1
2004M1
2005M1
2006M1
2007M1
2008M1
2009M1
2010M1
2011M1
2012M1
2013M1
2014M1
2015M1
2016M1
2017M1
2018M1
2019M1
CISS
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
2002M1
2003M1
2004M1
2005M1
2006M1
2007M1
2008M1
2009M1
2010M1
2011M1
2012M1
2013M1
2014M1
2015M1
2016M1
2017M1
2018M1
2019M1
SRI
Notes: Monthly data 2002M1-2019M6. Variables are displayed as they enter
our models: real GDP and HICP in first differences of logs (in %), CISS and
SRI in levels.
correlation across sub-components, whereby higher correlation implies higher values of systemic
stress. The CISS leads GDP by up to one quarter (Chavleishvili and Kremer, 2021) and has
been shown to outperform narrower measures of financial conditions in the prediction of one-year
ahead tail risks to euro area output growth (Figueres and Jaroci´nski, 2020).
3.2 Financial vulnerabilities
We capture medium-term financial vulnerabilities with the Systemic Risk Indicator (SRI): a
broad-based cyclical indicator that captures risks stemming from potential overvaluation of
property prices, credit conditions, external imbalances, private sector debt burden and the po-
tential mispricing of risk that serves as a ‘barometer’ of financial instability (Lang et al., 2019).
With the exception of the credit category, the authors use one variable for each of the aforemen-
The Money market sub-index comprises the 3M EURIBOR volatility, its spread to the 3M French T-bill spread,
and a measure of emergency lending of the Eurosystem.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
11
Table 1: Summary statistics
Statistic T Mean St. Dev. Min Max
Real GDP 210 0.100 0.359 1.416 0.910
HICP 210 0.138 0.171 0.413 0.644
CISS 210 0.177 0.201 0.002 0.913
SRI 210 0.068 0.296 0.436 0.542
Notes: Real GDP and HICP is in first differences of monthly logs
(in %). CISS and SRI are in monthly levels.
tioned categories, selecting from a larger pool of potential variables and transformations those
with the best predictive ability for systemic financial crises. In total, Lang et al. (2019) derive
six indicators which are normalized and aggregated as an optimally weighted average in terms
of overall predictive power of the composite indicator.
2
Measures of financial vulnerabilities are typically used to inform macroprudential policies.
For example, the credit-to-GDP gap is instrumental in the calibration of countercyclical capital
buffers. The SRI increases on average several years before the onset of systemic financial crises
with superior early-warning properties in comparison to the credit-to-GDP gap. In this capacity,
it also has significant predictive power for large declines in real GDP growth three to four years
into the future and its level at the onset of systemic financial crises is highly correlated with
measures of subsequent crisis severity. The SRI therefore provides useful information about
both the probability and the likely cost of systemic financial crises which makes it our preferred
measure of the financial cycle in comparison to other available indicators.
Financial vulnerabilities evolve more slowly and more gradually than the other variables in
our models, reflecting that financial cycles tend to last longer than economic cycles. Indeed,
the within-month interactions between the SRI and the other variables, measured by quantile
impulse responses, are negligible and insignificant except for financial stress (CISS) at the
90th percentile. On the other hand, financial vulnerabilities can be controlled by a range of
financial stability instruments, microprudential and macroprudential. Due to the negligible
contemporaneous interactions, we can interpret SRI changes as exogenous shocks, and treat the
SRI as the third policy tool, in addition to conventional and unconventional monetary policy.
2
The six sub-indicators used are the two-year change in the bank credit-to-GDP ratio, the two-year growth rate
of real total credit, the two-year change in the debt-service-ratio, the three-year change in the RRE price-to-income
ratio, the three-year growth rate of real equity prices, and the current account-to-GDP ratio.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
12
3.3 Monetary policy shocks
A large empirical literature, going back to Kuttner (2001), identifies effects of monetary policy
on asset prices and the macroeconomy using high-frequency, intra-day, financial market price
changes over short time windows covering central bank monetary policy announcements. Based
on such high-frequency event-study data, G¨urkaynak et al. (2005) find that two independent
factors constructed from federal funds futures the first related to short rates and an independent
second factor related to rates of longer maturities summarize the effects of U.S. monetary policy
on bond prices and stock returns.
We use their approach to extract two factors from intra-day overnight index swap (OIS) rate
changes over narrow time windows covering the press release as well as the subsequent press
conference about monetary policy decisions on ECB Governing Council monetary policy meeting
dates using the “Euro Area Monetary Policy Event-Study Database”, developed and regularly
updated by Altavilla et al. (2019). These two factors capture surprises along the yield curve as
they are constructed by fitting the time series of surprises in OIS rates of seven maturities (one,
three and six months as well as one, two, five and ten years). Surprises in OIS rates of maturities
longer than two years are only available from August 2011 onward and we proxy these series by
surprises in German government bond yields of the same maturity for the period from January
2002 to July 2011.
To provide a structural interpretation of the two factors, we rotate them as in G¨urkaynak
et al. (2005) such that the second factor is not impacted by surprises in the OIS rate of the
shortest maturity, i.e. its factor loading on the 1-month OIS surprises is set to zero, while im-
posing orthogonality between the two rotated factors. Finally, the rotated factors are rescaled
to match the standard deviations of 3-month OIS surprises for the first factor and 10-year OIS
surprise for the second factor. In this way, the first factor corresponds to shorter maturities
reflecting surprises related to conventional monetary policy and the second factor corresponds
to longer maturities, capturing surprises related to unconventional monetary policy. For conve-
nience we label these factors short- and long-end factors, in line with G¨urkaynak et al. (2005).
The corresponding factor loadings are shown in Figure 2.
The short- and long-end factors provide information about interest rate surprises along
the yield curve. Jaroci´nski and Karadi (2020) point out that such surprises reveal, addition-
ally to information about the monetary policy stance, also private central bank information
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
13
Figure 2: Monetary policy surprise factors - loadings
1m 3m 6m 1Y 2Y 5Y 10Y
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
1
F1 - short
F2 - long
Notes: The figure shows the estimated factor loadings after rotation.
about the state of the economy. To separate monetary policy from central bank information
shocks, Jaroci´nski and Karadi (2020) use an identification strategy with sign restrictions on high-
frequency stock price changes around monetary policy announcements. A positive co-movement
between intra-day interest rates and intra-day stock prices is interpreted as an information shock
as the central bank reveals new information about the state of the economy. In turn, a negative
co-movement reflects a monetary policy surprise whereby higher interest rates imply a decline
in stock prices, while a fall in interest rates implies higher stock prices. While intuitive, this
method yields implausible results for the euro area; in particular, the response of the monthly
stock index remains insignificant while a monthly BBB bond spread index used in their model
declines after a contractionary monetary policy shock. However, the analysis in our paper
builds on a consistent identification between high-frequency monetary policy shocks and asset
price responses to assess the financial stability implications of monetary policy.
As an alternative to stock prices, we therefore identify monetary policy and information
shocks based on daily changes of non-financial corporate (NFC) bond spreads instead of intra-
day stock price changes, as suggested by Giuzio et al. (2021). More specifically, we identify
monetary policy shocks from positive co-movement of our interest rate factors with daily changes
in BBB-rated euro-denominated NFC bond spreads (at 5-year maturity). Thus, a contractionary
monetary policy shock occurs when interest rates rise and bond spreads widen simultaneously
whereas an expansionary monetary policy shock is characterized by falling interest rates and
narrowing bond spreads. Consequently, central bank information shocks are identified from
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
14
negative co-movement between interest rate surprises and bond spreads. This identification
strategy improves not only the response of monthly bond spreads but also the response of
monthly stock prices to monetary policy shocks. We use bond spreads from Bank of America
obtained through Bloomberg until March 2007, while from April 2007 we use bond spreads from
iBoxx, which we found to be more liquid compared to those from Bank of America but not
continuously available before April 2007. Summary statistics of the interest rate series, bond
spreads, and identified surprises can be found in Table 2.
Table 2: Summary statistics for monthly interest rate factors and monetary policy surprises
(January 2002 - June 2019), T = 210, in bps.
Mean St. Dev. Min Max
Short-end factor 0.09 2.87 13.20 16.70
Short-end factor, MP shock 0.03 1.54 6.34 16.70
Short-end factor, CB info shock 0.11 2.39 13.20 10.27
Long-end factor 0.00 4.09 25.77 13.22
Long-end factor, MP shock 0.06 1.97 10.09 10.21
Long-end factor, CB info shock 0.12 3.52 25.77 13.22
BBB-rated NFC bond spread changes 0.13 3.40 -8.94 23.52
The cumulated factors of surprises in OIS rates are displayed in Figure 3 together with their
information and monetary policy components, based on the identification using BBB-rated NFC
bond spreads. Increasing values indicate tightening of interest rates relative to the prevailing
market expectations before monetary policy statements.
The short-end factor indicates a tightening of surprises in short rates during the early part
of our sample, followed by a period of loosening leading up to the Global Financial Crisis,
then a short period of tightening at the peak of Global Financial Crisis and finally an overall
loosening of rates over the remainder of our sample period. These dynamics were mainly driven
by surprises identified as central bank information shocks, while monetary policy shocks often
moved in opposite direction and indicate an overall tightening.
In turn, the cumulated long end factor falls strongly in July and August 2008, driven by
central bank information shocks, while gradually tightening for most of the remainder of the
sample period. This long tightening episode appears to be driven at least partially by monetary
policy shocks.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
15
Figure 3: Cumulated monetary policy factors 2002-2019
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
-50
-40
-30
-20
-10
0
10
20
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
long end factor
long end factor - CB info.
long end factor - MP
-40
-30
-20
-10
0
10
20
30
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
short end factor
short end factor - CB info.
short end factor - MP
Notes: The figure shows cumulated factors before and after identification with
BBB-rated NFC bond spreads in basis points.
The factors are extracted in a first step using maximum likelihood estimation to employ them
in a second step for estimating quantile treatment effects of policy interventions by minimizing
asymmetric l
1
loss functions. As a result, the two steps of the empirical strategy employ different
loss functions. While it may be possible to use the l
1
loss functions in factor extraction, such
an approach has not been used in the literature on monetary policy event study factors as far
as we know and is not considered in this work either.
4 Quantile modelling
4.1 Estimating quantile treatment effects of structural shocks
The main goal of our estimations is to quantify the impact of exogenous shocks on vulner-
abilities in the real economy and the financial sector. We do so by estimating the effect of
structural shocks on different parts of the distribution of the response variables, namely real
GDP growth, HICP inflation, financial vulnerabilities and financial stress. However, this task
is complex because we need to model the distributions of our endogenous variables, along with
their contemporaneous and dynamic interactions. Specifically, we estimate quantile treatment
effects (see Koenker, 2005, pp. 26–32) of structural shocks. A quantile treatment effect measures
how each quantile of a response variable is affected by a treatment. In our case, the treatment
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
16
is an exogenous impulse, also called a shock.
We estimate the quantile treatment effects by two different methods. The first is a simulation-
based, two-step approach in form of a quantile vector autoregressive model, while the second
one relies on direct estimation and regularization in form of a quantile local projection approach.
Both methods identify the shocks by recursive short-run restrictions and provide valid estimates
of the quantile treatment effect. However, the methods differ in their finite sample performance
and in robustness to misspecification, especially at longer forecast horizons. In the following, we
provide the general features of the two estimation methods together with basic technical notions
of their setup and refer the reader for additional details to the referenced papers.
The first method – simulation-based follows Ruzicka (2021b) and is based on the estimation
of the quantile regression process for a system of equations, with subsequent simulation using the
approach proposed by Koenker and Xiao (2006), described in detail in Koenker et al. (2018, pp.
328–329), and also used by Montes-Rojas (2022). It is similar to Chavleishvili and Manganelli
(2019) and Montes-Rojas (2022). However, unlike Chavleishvili and Manganelli (2019), we do
not set any sample paths to their median values and instead consider the full set of possible
sample paths. This increases the computational complexity, but gives a more complete and
agnostic picture of the effects we estimate. Unlike Montes-Rojas (2022) and Chavleishvili and
Manganelli (2019), we do not discretize the model on an ex-ante chosen grid of quantile indices,
but instead estimate the entire quantile regression process, that is, we estimate each quantile
regression for all quantile indices in (0,1). The practical consequence is that our estimates
don’t suffer from unnecessary approximation errors due to discretization. In addition, unlike
Chavleishvili and Manganelli (2019) and Montes-Rojas (2022), we construct confidence intervals
for the quantile treatment effects as in Ruzicka (2021b).
The second method estimates the quantile treatment effects directly by employing the lo-
cal projections of Jord`a (2005) in a quantile regression setting. Local projections estimated by
quantile regressions have become a popular way to capture heterogeneous effects of macroeco-
nomic shocks. However, applied research based on plain quantile regression local projections is
challenging: The estimated impulse response functions tend to wiggle a lot, it is unclear what
the underlying identification conditions are, and it is unclear how to construct closed-form confi-
dence intervals. Ruzicka (2021a) overcomes these challenges by introducing roughness penalties
to smooth the impulse response functions, by establishing the identification conditions, and by
providing closed-from as well as weighted bootstrap confidence intervals.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
17
These features are essential for our results for the following reasons. First, if it were not
for the smoothing, the estimated impulse response functions would change abruptly from one
forecast horizon to the next, making them difficult to interpret and less accurate. Second, the
theoretical result of Ruzicka (2021a) reveals which control variables must be included (and which
must not) in order to identify the quantile treatment effect of interest. This is essential for causal
interpretation and to prevent simultaneity bias. Third, the weighted bootstrap doesn’t entail any
tuning parameters, unlike the stationary bootstrap proposed Han et al. (2022) which depends
on a parameter (average block length), whose appropriate choice is nontrivial in practice.
Next, we present the basic technical notions underlying both estimation methodologies: the
data generating process and the impulse response function that measures the quantile treat-
ment effect of interest. For random variables X and Y we denote Q
τ
(Y |X) the τ th conditional
quantile of Y given X. For a stochastic process {Y
t
}, let {F
t
} be its filtration (the informa-
tion known up to time t). We assume the data follow an I-dimensional stochastic process
3
{Y
t
} = {[y
1,t
, y
2,t
, . . . , y
I,t
]} given by
Q
τ
1
(y
1,t
|F
t1
) =
I
X
i=1
P
X
p=1
a
p1i
(τ
1
)y
i,tp
+ ε
1
(τ
1
)
Q
τ
2
(y
2,t
|y
1,t
, F
t1
) = a
021
(τ
2
)y
1,t
+
I
X
i=1
P
X
p=1
a
p2i
(τ
2
)y
i,tp
+ ε
2
(τ
2
)
.
.
.
Q
τ
I
(y
I,t
|y
1,t
, y
2,t
, . . . , y
I1,t
, F
t1
) =
I1
X
i=1
a
0Ii
(τ
I
)y
i,t
+
I
X
i=1
P
X
p=1
a
pIi
(τ
I
)y
i,tp
+ ε
I
(τ
I
)
(1)
3
This type of a stochastic process was studied by Chavleishvili and Manganelli (2019), Ruzicka (2021a,b) and
Montes-Rojas (2022). It is a special case of the VAR for VaR of White et al. (2015), who additionally allow
conditional quantiles to depend on the lags of conditional quantiles.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
18
This stochastic process can be expressed in a random coefficient representation as
y
1,t
=
I
X
i=1
P
X
p=1
a
p1i
(u
1t
)y
i,tp
+ ε
1
(u
1t
)
y
2,t
= a
021
(u
2t
)y
1,t
+
I
X
i=1
P
X
p=1
a
p2i
(u
2t
)y
i,tp
+ ε
2
(u
2t
)
.
.
.
y
I,t
=
I1
X
i=1
a
0Ii
(u
It
)y
i,t
+
I
X
i=1
P
X
p=1
a
pIi
(u
It
)y
i,tp
+ ε
I
(u
It
)
(2)
where u
i,t
U[0, 1], y
i,t
is non-decreasing in u
it
a.s. for all i and t, and {u
it
} are independent.
The disturbances {u
it
} in (2) change from one period to the next and represent the realized
values of τ
i
in each time period.
4
The model is identified by recursive short-run restrictions. For example, the second variable
is not allowed to contemporaneously affect the distribution of the first variable, but it may
affect the distribution of the third variable. This recursive ordering is analogous to the one of
Sims (1980). However, note that the identification restrictions are not equivalent to a Cholesky
decomposition of a covariance matrix in fact, the quantile model above is well-defined even if
the variance of Y
t
doesn’t exist.
In the first, simulation-based approach, we estimate the quantile regression process of all
equations above over all quantile indices in (0,1) and subsequently recover the quantile treatment
effects of shocks by simulation, as outlined earlier. In the second, direct estimation approach,
we rely on the result of Ruzicka (2021a) who shows that for all forecast horizons h N
0
and all
i, j {1, 2, . . . , I} in the representation
Q
τ
(y
j,t+h
|F
t1
, y
1,t
, . . . , y
i,t
) = β
0,j,0,h
(τ) +
i
X
k=1
β
k,j,0,h
(τ)y
k,t
+
I
X
k=1
P 1
X
p=1
β
k,j,p,h
(τ)y
k,tp
(3)
the slope coefficient β
i,j,0,h
(τ) is the quantile treatment effect of the ith shock on variable j after
h periods at quantile τ . The last equation could be estimated directly by quantile regression,
separately for each forecast horizon. However, such estimates are usually rather inaccurate
and difficult to interpret as they differ dramatically between neighboring forecast horizons. For
4
Koenker et al. (2018)[pp. 313-317, 328-329] discuss the conditional quantile and random coefficient forms of
quantile autoregressive processes, their relations and role in forecasting.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
19
that reason we use the smooth quantile local projections estimator of Ruzicka (2021a), which
solves the problem by regularization, shrinking the impulse response functions towards cubic
polynomials via roughness penalties. In addition, we impose a long-run equilibrium constraint
which ensures the impulse response functions converge to a constant function at the final forecast
horizon.
5
We set the optimal value of the roughness penalty by the Bayesian information
criterion (Schwarz, 1978), as adapted for this setup by Ruzicka (2021a). Following Ruzicka
(2021a), we construct the confidence intervals by the weighted bootstrap with undersmoothing
(using standard exponential weights; the roughness penalty for confidence intervals is one quarter
of its value for point estimates.)
We collect the quantile treatment effects at different horizons into a quantile impulse re-
sponse function, using the definition of Ruzicka (2021b). The quantile impulse response function
QIR(j, i, h, τ, s) is the response of the jth variable at quantile τ to the ith shock of size s after
h periods, formally
QIR(j, i, h, τ, s) = Q
τ
h
y
j,t+h
ε
i
(u
it
) := ε
i
(u
it
) + s
i
Q
τ
h
y
j,t+h
i
(4)
=
Q
τ
[y
j,t+h
|u
it
]
ε
i
(u
it
)
s (5)
where the notation ε
i
(u
it
) := ε
i
(u
it
) + s represents a modified version of the process, with ε
i
(u
it
)
substituted by ε
i
(u
it
)+s for all u
it
[0, 1]. For some variables we are interested in the cumulative
effect of a shock through cumulative quantile impulse response functions, given by
QIRC(j, i, h, τ, s) = Q
τ
"
h
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
ε
i
(u
it
) := ε
i
(u
it
) + s
#
Q
τ
"
h
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
#
(6)
=
Q
τ
"
h
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
u
it
#
ε
i
(u
it
)
s (7)
4.2 Counterfactual scenarios linking forecasts and impulse responses
The quantile impulse response function as defined above involves an intervention at a single
point in time. However, it is also possible to allow interventions in various consecutive time
periods. This is more complicated, but it is useful in order to isolate the effects of sustained
policy interventions. To be specific, we work with monthly data, the interventions are introduced
5
For our two models, the forecast horizon is up to 72 months and 12 months, respectively.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
20
in 12 consecutive months, and the response variable is a monthly growth rate. Formally, the
intervention at time t + m is of size s
m
, where m {0, 1, . . . , 11}. We want to see the effect of
the interventions on the τ th quantile of
P
11
k=0
y
j,t+k
, which represents the year-over-year growth
rate of the response variable. Using the same notation as in (4), the effect of the sequence of
interventions is
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
m {0, 1, . . . , 11}: ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) := ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) + s
m
#
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
#
(8)
It can be shown
6
that (8) equals
11
X
l=0
QIRC(j, i, l, τ, s
11l
) (9)
The sequence of external impulses can be combined with quantile forecasts into a counter-
factual scenario. Such a scenario shows how quantile forecasts would have responded to policy
interventions in the past. Recall that F
t1
represents the information known at time t 1. The
forecast of the year-over-year growth rate of the ith variable is represented by
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
F
t1
#
(10)
Next, we introduce policy interventions over 12 consecutive months. The forecast changes to
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
F
t1
, m {0, 1, . . . , 11}: ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) := ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) + s
m
#
(11)
and represents our counterfactual scenario. It turns out that
7
(11) equals (12)
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
F
t1
#
+
11
X
l=0
QIRC(j, i, l, τ, s
11l
) (12)
which comprises the quantile forecast (the first term) and the effect of the sequence of interven-
tions (the second term).
This form of a counterfactual scenario does not set any specific sample path and so it is differ-
ent from the one in Chavleishvili et al. (2021). Fixing a sample path ex ante as in Chavleishvili
6
Proof A.2 in the appendix.
7
Proof A.3 in the appendix.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
21
et al. (2021) obviates the need to run a large number of simulations. However, since our coun-
terfactual scenario is based on a sequence of exogenous interventions, we can calculate (9) just
by summing up the cumulative quantile impulse response functions. These must be estimated
beforehand, either by simulation or by direct estimation through local projections.
Finally, the counterfactual scenario gives us a way to quantify the contribution of interven-
tions (observed or estimated) on the in-sample quantile forecasts over a specific time horizon.
In our case, the interventions are monetary policy surprises. Formally, consider interventions to
variable i at time t + l of size s
t+l
, where 0 l 11. Then the term
11
X
l=0
QIRC(j, i, l, τ, s
t+11l
) (13)
measures how the year-over-year growth rate of the jth variable would change if the interventions
s
t
, s
t+1
, . . . , s
t+11
were replaced by zero. We interpret (13) as the contribution of the interven-
tions to the year-over-year growth rate of variable j over the time horizon t, t + 1, . . . , t + 11.
4.3 The setup: real economy, financial variables and monetary policy
Based on the general framework described in the previous section, we outline the specific model
setup for an economy with financial interactions. In brief, we estimate three models. The first
one encompasses economic activity, price level, financial vulnerabilities, and financial stress. We
obtain the second model by incorporating short-term rates. Finally, we replace the short-term
rates by long-term rates to arrive at our third model. These models are estimated separately
to ensure tractability, results from one combined model with both monetary policy series are
qualitatively similar but subject to wider confidence bands.
We estimate each of the three models using the two alternative methods described earlier,
that is, with a simulation-based approach as well as with a local projection approach. Both
approaches rely on the same identification assumptions. Theoretically, the estimates from both
methods converge to the same limit in large samples, provided our model is correctly specified.
All specifications include three lags of all the included variables.
The first model combines real GDP growth and HICP inflation with variables of financial
vulnerabilities and systemic stress into a four-variable model of their entire distribution. Fi-
nancial vulnerabilities are captured by the SRI and financial stress is measured by the CISS.
Identification is achieved through recursive short-run restrictions: Hereby real GDP growth is
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
22
placed first, HICP inflation second, the SRI third and CISS fourth. The identification strategy
thus implies that the financial stress variable (placed fourth) can react contemporaneously to
macroeconomic and SRI shocks, while the SRI (placed third) can only react contemporaneously
to shocks to output growth and HICP inflation. In turn, real output growth only reacts with
a lag to shocks of inflation, the SRI, and stress. This follows standard assumptions in the
empirical literature such as Kilian (2009) and Gilchrist and Zakrajˇsek (2012). The estimates
and the identification strategy allow us to quantify amplifications of risks for future economic
activity caused by elevated levels of financial imbalances as well as financial stress. This is rel-
evant for modelling the variables over time and for the counterfactual policy scenarios. In this
four-variable model we consider impulse responses up to 72 months ahead.
The second and third model append the previous four-variable model by adding either the
short-end or the long-end monetary policy surprise factors (while results based on central bank
information shocks are shown in the appendix). The monetary policy series are ordered first so
as to contemporaneously affect all the other variables in the system. Given that we investigate
the monetary policy effects on different parts of the distribution of the response variables while
having a modest sample size, we focus on impulse responses over the short-run, up to 12 months
ahead. Even though we cannot comment on medium term monetary policy effects, Doh and
Foerster (2022) show that monetary policy transmission lags have shortened after 2009, at least
in the United States.
5 Results
With model specifications and the monetary policy shock identification fully established, this
section focuses on the estimation results and their interpretation. We discuss the quantile im-
pulse response functions in two blocks starting with those based on the model without monetary
policy surprises which we show up to 72 months ahead, followed by those from the two models
that include monetary policy surprises, for which we focus on short-term dynamics of up to 12
months ahead.
5.1 Impulse responses of macro-financial variables
The impulse responses of macroeconomic variables in our quantile setting follow those known
from structural linear VARs in the literature. As Figure 4 shows, an impulse to real GDP leads to
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
23
a persistent increase of GDP, accompanied by an increase in inflation – with a mild overshooting
over two quarters. In turn, an impulse to inflation does not imply persistent effects for future
inflation and does not affect real GDP growth in a statistically significant manner. The impulse
responses of the two variables do not indicate heterogeneous dynamics across quantiles.
Figure 4: Impulse Responses of GDP, inflation, financial vulnerability, and stress
(estimated by simulation)
monthly GDP response (cumulative)
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
1 SD monthly GDP shock
HICP inf. response (cumulative)
0.05
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
SRI response
0.050
0.025
0.000
0.025
0.050
CISS response
0.02
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.1
0.0
0.1
1 SD HICP inf. shock
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.050
0.025
0.000
0.025
0.050
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1 SD SRI shock
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.03
0.00
0.03
0.06
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
0 12 24 36 48 60 72
month
1 SD CISS shock
0.2
0.1
0.0
0.1
0 12 24 36 48 60 72
month
0.050
0.025
0.000
0.025
0.050
0 12 24 36 48 60 72
month
0.00
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
0 12 24 36 48 60 72
month
quantile
0.1 0.5 0.9
Notes: Four-variable specification without monetary policy shock. Confidence bands are at 90% and are excluded
for the median response.
In turn, the financial variables provide additional information on the macroeconomic dy-
namics. An innovation of the SRI, reflecting an increase in financial vulnerabilities, implies a
temporary upward deviation of output with a peak after 24 months, whereby the 10th percentile
of the distribution reverts more quickly while the 90th percentile has a larger persistence. The
effects on inflation, on the other hand, appear more persistent, especially for the upper tail of
the distribution. These findings indicate that macroprudential policy targeting the SRI can be
effective in boosting or slowing growth and inflation. As regards the materialisation of stress
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
24
as captured by the CISS, it exerts a strong downward adjustment for the 10th percentile of the
GDP distribution, in line with the findings in the literature (Adrian et al., 2019; Chavleishvili
and Manganelli, 2019; Chavleishvili and Kremer, 2021). In turn, the inflation rate adjusts in
the short term but rebounds quickly, without statistically significant longer-term effects on the
price level.
As regards the impulse responses of financial vulnerabilities and stress, we find that shocks to
GDP and HICP inflation have only insignificant impacts on financial variables, while the corre-
sponding impulse responses indicate that a positive SRI impulse initiates a persistent medium-
term episode of increasing vulnerabilities, whereby higher quantiles increase relatively more
strongly and cumulate after 24 months compared to the lower quantiles. Together with in-
creasing financial vulnerabilities, financial stress is being dampened in the short-term, especially
for higher quantiles of the CISS. However, as the vulnerabilities indicator recedes, the stress
indicator reverts with financial market stress and losses. This interplay between financial vul-
nerabilities and financial stress reflects a key intertemporal trade-off for policymakers between
short-term gains from exuberant financial conditions and higher risks of financial stress in the
medium term. Shocks to the CISS have only a statistically insignificant impact on the SRI, and
appear to die out after about 24 months.
The impulse responses from the two estimation approaches are qualitatively comparable with
only few exceptions, such as the impact of CISS shocks on the upper part of the SRI distribution
or the effect of the SRI shock on the upper part of the GDP growth distribution.
5.2 Impact of monetary policy shocks
Beyond the macro-financial interactions discussed thus far, we next assess the impact of mone-
tary policy shocks on financial stability conditions and the real economy. For this, we employ
the two monetary policy factors defined in Section 3.3, the short-end factor capturing surprises
in short-term rates and linked to conventional monetary policy, and the long-end factor cap-
turing surprises in longer rates, unrelated to surprises in short-term rates, and thus linked to
unconventional monetary policy. The results for monetary policy shocks feature in this section,
while the impulse responses of the central bank information shocks are shown in the appendix.
As Figures 6 and 7 show, an identified conventional monetary policy tightening shock has
the expected contractionary effect on real GDP growth and HICP inflation, in line with the
monetary policy literature (Bernanke and Mishkin, 1997; Clarida et al., 1999). Beyond the
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
25
Figure 5: Impulse Responses of GDP, inflation, financial vulnerability, and stress
(estimated by local projections)
monthly GDP response (cumulative)
0.4
0.0
0.4
0.8
1 SD monthly GDP shock
HICP inf. response (cumulative)
0.2
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
SRI response
0.09
0.06
0.03
0.00
0.03
CISS response
0.050
0.025
0.000
0.025
0.050
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
0.2
1 SD HICP inf. shock
0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.05
0.00
0.05
0.06
0.03
0.00
0.03
0.06
0.0
0.5
1 SD SRI shock
0.2
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.05
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.05
0.00
0.05
1.00
0.75
0.50
0.25
0.00
0 12 24 36 48 60 72
month
1 SD CISS shock
0.75
0.50
0.25
0.00
0.25
0 12 24 36 48 60 72
month
0.100
0.075
0.050
0.025
0.000
0 12 24 36 48 60 72
month
0.05
0.00
0.05
0 12 24 36 48 60 72
month
quantile
0.1 0.5 0.9
Notes: Four-variable specification without monetary policy shock. Confidence bands are at 90% and are excluded
for the median response.
macroeconomic effects, a tightening shock also impacts financial stability conditions. In the
short term, the shock raises financial stress measured by the CISS across all quantiles, but
especially so for the upper part of the distribution. This implies that following a tightening
shock, the CISS does not only increase on average, but the distribution also becomes more
asymmetric with a larger right tail, permitting stronger surges in financial stress.
In turn, the impact on systemic risk and medium-term financial vulnerabilities is less clear
cut. It appears that over time, the impact on the SRI is negative, indicating ’taming-the-cycle’
dynamics, but the effects are statistically insignificant.
Impulse responses to an unconventional monetary policy tightening shock differ meaningfully
from those following a shock to the short-end factor. Figures 8 and 9 show that the impact of
a comparable one standard deviation shock on GDP growth is smaller, and statistically not
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
26
Figure 6: Impulse Responses of monetary policy tightening shock on short-term rates
(estimated by simulation)
monthly GDP response (cumulative)
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
0.1
1 SD FShort MP shock
HICP inf. response (cumulative)
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
SRI response
0.01
0.00
0.01
CISS response
0.00
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
1 SD monthly GDP shock
0.025
0.000
0.025
0.050
0.010
0.005
0.000
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.10
0.05
0.00
0.05
1 SD HICP inf. shock
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
0.010
0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.010
0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
1 SD SRI shock
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.000
0.025
0.050
0.075
0.05
0.04
0.03
0.02
0.01
0.00
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
0 3 6 9 12
month
1 SD CISS shock
0.05
0.00
0.05
0 3 6 9 12
month
0.010
0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0 3 6 9 12
month
0.00
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
0 3 6 9 12
month
quantile
0.1 0.5 0.9
Notes: Five-variable specification with response of monetary policy shock variable excluded. Confidence bands
are at 90% and are excluded for the median response.
significant, while the impact on HICP inflation is comparable and statistically significant. As
for short-end shocks we find a dampening impact on financial vulnerabilities, this time marginally
significant at least for the 10th percentile. The impact of long-end shocks on financial stress
is found to be insignificant, unlike short-end shocks. Finally, impulse responses to monetary
policy shocks generated from the two estimation approaches are generally comparable for both
monetary policy factors.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
27
Figure 7: Impulse Responses of monetary policy tightening shock on short-term rates
(estimated by local projections)
monthly GDP response (cumulative)
0.4
0.2
0.0
1 SD FShort MP shock
HICP inf. response (cumulative)
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
SRI response
0.02
0.01
0.00
0.01
CISS response
0.050
0.025
0.000
0.025
0.050
0.075
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
1 SD monthly GDP shock
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.02
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.025
0.000
0.025
0.050
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
1 SD HICP inf. shock
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.02
0.00
0.02
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
1 SD SRI shock
0.05
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.00
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.06
0.04
0.02
0.00
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
0 3 6 9 12
month
1 SD CISS shock
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
0.1
0 3 6 9 12
month
0.00
0.01
0.02
0 3 6 9 12
month
0.00
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
0 3 6 9 12
month
quantile
0.1 0.5 0.9
Notes: Five-variable specification with response of monetary policy shock variable excluded. Confidence bands
are at 90% and are excluded for the median response.
6 Counterfactuals
6.1 Impact of monetary policy shocks on inflation and Growth-at-Risk
The empirical quantile models allow us to identify the role of monetary policy in the forecasts of
macro-financial variables and to consider counterfactual analysis. Figure 10 shows the forecasts
for GaR and one year ahead median annual HICP inflation together with the contribution of
monetary policy shocks over time. The monetary policy contributions are constructed as the
12-month cumulative impact of the individual monetary policy surprises in each of these months
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
28
Figure 8: Impulse Responses of monetary policy tightening shock on long-term rates
(estimated by simulation)
monthly GDP response (cumulative)
0.2
0.1
0.0
1 SD FLong MP shock
HICP inf. response (cumulative)
0.10
0.05
0.00
SRI response
0.015
0.010
0.005
0.000
0.005
CISS response
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
1 SD monthly GDP shock
0.04
0.00
0.04
0.08
0.010
0.005
0.000
0.005
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.10
0.05
0.00
0.05
0.10
1 SD HICP inf. shock
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
0.010
0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
1 SD SRI shock
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.000
0.025
0.050
0.075
0.05
0.04
0.03
0.02
0.01
0.00
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
0 3 6 9 12
month
1 SD CISS shock
0.10
0.05
0.00
0.05
0 3 6 9 12
month
0.01
0.00
0 3 6 9 12
month
0.00
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
0 3 6 9 12
month
quantile
0.1 0.5 0.9
Notes: Five-variable specification with response of monetary policy shock variable excluded. Confidence bands
are at 90%.
multiplied with the estimated impulse response function of the relevant horizon. They are thus
conditional on the macro-financial information up to a point t, but conditional on the monetary
policy surprises from t to t + 12.
The largest contributions of conventional monetary policy for GaR and the annual median
inflation forecast (left panels), can be observed over the period 2007–2008 when it exerted
large negative, i.e. tightening, contributions. When excluding these shocks, the Growth-at-Risk
measure would have been positive, instead of falling into negative territory. Our counterfactual
analysis indicates that the cumulative impact of conventional monetary policy shocks helped to
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
29
Figure 9: Impulse Responses of monetary policy tightening shock on long-term rates
(estimated by local projections)
monthly GDP response (cumulative)
0.2
0.1
0.0
0.1
0.2
1 SD FLong MP shock
HICP inf. response (cumulative)
0.2
0.1
0.0
0.1
SRI response
0.02
0.01
0.00
0.01
CISS response
0.04
0.02
0.00
0.02
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
1 SD monthly GDP shock
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.01
0.00
0.03
0.00
0.03
0.06
0.2
0.1
0.0
1 SD HICP inf. shock
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.03
0.02
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.02
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
1 SD SRI shock
0.0
0.1
0.00
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
0.06
0.04
0.02
0.00
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
0 3 6 9 12
month
1 SD CISS shock
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
0.1
0 3 6 9 12
month
0.00
0.01
0 3 6 9 12
month
0.000
0.025
0.050
0.075
0 3 6 9 12
month
quantile
0.1 0.5 0.9
Notes: Five-variable specification with response of monetary policy shock variable excluded. Confidence bands
are at 90% and are excluded for the median response.
stabilize inflation over that period it would otherwise have increased above 4% and then
bring down inflation forecasts in 2008.
The relatively large impact of monetary policy over this episode can be explained by tight-
ening shocks in the second half of 2008 (see also Figure 3), while markets may have expected
larger reductions earlier in the crisis. Beyond the Global Financial Crisis, sizable monetary pol-
icy impacts of the short-term interest rate factor appear during the aftermath of the euro area
debt crisis (2013–2014) when loosening policy helped to boost growth and to uphold inflation.
While the 12-month cumulated surprises in the short-rate factor played an important role
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
30
Figure 10: Monetary policy contributions to 1-year ahead GaR and inflation for short- and
long-end factor
8
6
4
2
0
2
4
2001M12 2005M12 2009M12 2013M12 2017M12
CumulatedshortMPcontribution
GrowthatRisk(1yearahead)
GaRnetofmonetarypolicycontribution
2
1
0
1
2
3
4
5
2001M12 2005M12 2009M12 2013M12 2017M12
CumulatedshortMPcontribution
Medianannualinflationforecast(1yearahead)
InflationforecastnetofMPcontribution
2
1
0
1
2
3
4
5
2001M12 2005M12 2009M12 2013M12 2017M12
CumulatedlongMPcontribution
Medianannualinflationforecast(1yearahead)
InflationforecastnetofMPcontribution
8
6
4
2
0
2
4
2001M12 2005M12 2009M12 2013M12 2017M12
CumulatedlongMPcontribution
GrowthatRisk(1yearahead)
GaRnetofmonetarypolicycontribution
Notes: This figure shows the forecasts for one year ahead GaR and median annual HICP inflation
together with the contribution of monetary policy shocks over time. The monetary policy contributions
are constructed as the 12-month cumulative impact of the individual monetary policy surprises in each
of these months multiplied with the estimated impulse response function of the relevant horizon. They
are thus conditional on the macro-financial information up to a point t, but conditional on the monetary
policy surprises from t to t + 12.
during the Global Financial Crisis, the long-rate factor had more limited effects on GaR and
median inflation forecasts, as can be seen from the right panels in Figure 10. The contributions
are not only smaller in comparison to those from the short-end factor, but alternate sign more
frequently. Up until 2014, effects were in the range of up to one percentage point for GaR and
0.5 percentage points for median inflation, but became more muted since then.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
31
6.2 Monetary policy and stabilization trade-offs
The contributions of monetary policy surprises to GDP Growth-at-Risk and HICP inflation serve
as a basis for assessing monetary policy trade-offs while pursuing a price stability objective. We
illustrate how monetary policy could stabilize median inflation at the price stability objective
of 2% and how such a stabilization compares to a policy that would stabilize GaR at its long-
run mean. The sign and size of the required stabilizing policy will depend on the state of the
economy in deviations from the respective inflation and GaR objective and the effectiveness
with which the policy instruments can achieve these objectives. A larger policy innovation is
needed if current forecasts strongly deviate from the objective or if the policy instrument is less
effective in bringing the economy back to the objective.
Figure 11: Short-end monetary policy shocks needed to stabilise GaR and 1-year ahead
median inflation forecasts
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
-15 -10 -5 0 5 10
Monetary policy shock to stabilize HICP
inflation
Monetary policy shock to stabilize GaR(10)
2002-2004 2005-2007 2008-2009 2010-2019
Notes: The monetary policy changes required to stabilize median HICP inflation and the 10th per-
centile of GDP growth are in standard deviations of the monetary policy innovations. Positive values
imply a required tightening and negative values a required loosening of short-term rates.
Figure 11 illustrates the necessary size of the short-term interest rate factor to stabilize 1-
year ahead forecasts of median inflation at 2% (vertical axis) and of GaR at its sample average
of -1.08% (horizontal axis). Observations in the upper right quadrant indicate that a tightening
of short-term rate would have helped to jointly stabilize price inflation and GaR objective. This
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
32
concerns primarily the period leading up to the Global Financial Crisis (2005–2007). In turn,
observations in the lower left quadrant would have implied a loosening to bring the variables
towards their objectives, but there have been only few of such instances over the sample period.
For the observations in the upper left quadrant, instead, policy prescriptions would have implied
a monetary policy tightening to stabilize inflation, but a loosening to raise GaR towards its tar-
get, relevant during the height of the Global Financial Crisis (2008–2009). For the observations
in the bottom right quadrant, a loosening of monetary policy would have been needed to raise
inflation towards its 2% objective, but a tighter policy would have helped to stabilize GaR.
The numerous observations in this bottom right quadrant indicate that monetary policy faced
an inflation-GaR trade-off for most of the post-crisis period. In such a trade-off situation, an
additional policy instrument could complement and support monetary policy to stabilize the
macroeconomy. Such policies may be fiscal or structural policies for the economic dimension, or
macroprudential policy for the financial dimension.
6.3 Relative efficiency of monetary and macroprudential policy
Our estimation framework can capture an important role for macroprudential policy in comple-
menting monetary policy in its efforts to stabilize the macroeconomy. The use of macroprudential
policy would be most effective if it was complementary to monetary policy in stabilizing median
inflation and GaR. To assess the relative efficiency of the two policies, we consider the policy
interventions that are necessary to bring one-year ahead median inflation to 2% or to stabilize
GaR at its historical average of -1.08%. In the empirical specifications, monetary policy is cap-
tured by the short- or the long-factor of risk-free interest rates, and macroprudential policy is
captured by the SRI.
8
In order to make the size of the two policies comparable, we divide both
measures by their historical standard deviation. The results on the relative efficiency hinge on
the standard deviation of historical surprises in the short- and long-factor and in the SRI.
The cumulated impulse responses of the policy variables reveal that, to stabilize 1-year
ahead GaR, a one-standard deviation of monetary policy achieves the same stabilization as
1.39 standard deviations of the SRI. When considering the long-term factor of interest rates, the
relative efficiency to stabilize GaR is 0.42 which implies that macroprudential policy is more than
twice as effective relative to the long-rate factor. Taken together, the short-term interest rate
factor is more efficient relative to macroprudential policy and macroprudential policy is more
8
This implicitly assumes that macroprudential policy makers can freely adjust the level of vulnerabilities.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
33
effective than the long term factor in stabilising GaR. When assessing the relative effectiveness
in stabilizing median inflation based on the cumulative impulse responses, we find that the short
factor is 1.3 times more effective than the SRI and the long-rate factor is as effective as the SRI
(factor of 1.0).
The estimation indicates that the short factor is the most efficient instrument not only to
stabilize GaR but also inflation. However the differences in effectiveness are larger for GaR
than for inflation. When considering a potential assignment of policy instruments to policy
objectives, the relative effectiveness in stabilizing one or the other variable becomes key (Fahr
and Fell, 2017). Using the effectiveness of the SRI as a reference point, the short-term rate
is 1.07 (=1.39/1.30) times more effective in stabilising GaR relative to inflation. In turn, the
long-rate factor is only 0.42 (=0.42/1.00) times as effective to stabilize GaR relative to inflation,
which implies that in relative terms the long-rate stabilizes inflation with least impact on GaR.
The relative efficiency itself does not yet provide us with the indications on the specific timing
for using either of the two policies. The complementarity comes to the fore when monetary policy
is constrained by a trade-off between stabilizing inflation and GaR, as captured in the top-left
and bottom-right corner of Figure 11. In those situations, the adjustment of macroprudential
policy can help to reduce the trade-off for monetary policy.
6.4 Monetary and macroprudential policy for stabilizing inflation and Growth-
at-Risk
Having established the relative efficiency of different policy tools, we illustrate how the estima-
tion results could inform monetary and macroprudential policy to enhance stabilization over the
sample period. We assume policy objectives of 2% median inflation one year ahead and stabi-
lization of GaR at its sample average of -1.08%. Given the relative efficiencies ,the policymaker
uses monetary policy (long-end interest rate factor) and macroprudential policy (SRI). The GaR
objective is non-symmetric, implying that the policymaker avoids GaR falling below the value
of -1.08% while focusing solely on the objective of inflation otherwise. The policymakers thus
provides a hedge against crisis outcomes.
Figure 12 displays results from this exercise. We find that relatively large monetary policy
shocks would have been needed to bring inflation forecasts back to their target over the period
from 2005 until the first half of 2009. In contrast, over the earlier as well as later parts of the
sample period our results would have called for looser monetary policy as inflation forecasts
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
34
Figure 12: Monetary- and macroprudential policy mix for joint inflation and Growth-at-Risk
targets.
Left: policy shocks. Right: forecasts conditional on policy shocks
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
04/2002
04/2003
04/2004
04/2005
04/2006
04/2007
04/2008
04/2009
04/2010
04/2011
04/2012
04/2013
04/2014
04/2015
04/2016
04/2017
04/2018
04/2019
long-end shock
dSRI shock
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
-1.5
-1.0
-0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
04/2002
04/2003
04/2004
04/2005
04/2006
04/2007
04/2008
04/2009
04/2010
04/2011
04/2012
04/2013
04/2014
04/2015
04/2016
04/2017
04/2018
04/2019
GaR(10)
HICP 0.5
dSRI 0.5
CISS 0.9 (rhs)
Notes: Left: This panel shows long-end and SRI shocks (in standard deviations) required to simul-
taneously achieve a 2% one-year ahead HICP inflation forecast while ensuring GaR above its sample
average of -1.08%. Positive shocks indicate tightening for monetary policy but loosening for macro-
prudential policy. Right: This panel shows one-year ahead forecasts conditional on the policy shocks
from the left panel. We show median forecasts for inflation and SRI, GaR and the 90th percentile
forecast for the CISS.
from our models were consistently below their 2% target. Looser macroprudential policy (SRI)
would have been needed starting in September 2007 and throughout the Global Financial Crisis
until September 2009 and again on a few occasions during the euro area debt crisis. Forecasts
implied by these policy counterfactuals show that they would have been effective in meeting
their targets, while effectively limiting financial stress.
7 Conclusions
Our empirical analysis focused on the interaction of monetary policy shocks, financial stability
conditions and the real economy in the euro area. The quantile vector autoregressive model,
using two estimation techniques and five variables, estimates the entire distribution of real and
financial variables. The setup allows for quantitatively assessing monetary policy trade-offs.
One such trade-off involves two different policy goals and is captured by interactions between
macro variables, such as inflation and GDP growth, and financial stability as measured by
financial stress and vulnerabilities. A second trade-off is of intertemporal nature and differenti-
ates between the potential impact of monetary policy on short-term financial stress relative to
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
35
adjustments to financial vulnerabilities in the medium term.
Our specifications consider not only the short-term interest rates as a policy tool, but also
changes in the longer term rates, so as to capture effects from forward guidance and asset
purchases of medium- to long-term securities. To identify monetary policy shocks, our empirical
strategy considers surprises in risk-free interest rates in a narrow time window around the
communication of ECB monetary policy decisions and further separates between information
and monetary policy shocks.
We find that surging financial stress has a strong short-term impact on the lower tail of the
GDP distribution. In turn, a build-up of financial vulnerabilities tends to be followed by sub-
dued financial stress initially, but vulnerabilities rise again over the medium term. Furthermore,
tightening conventional monetary policy reduces inflationary pressures (and real GDP growth)
at the cost of increasing financial stress. Changes in the long-term interest rates induced by
unconventional monetary policy, on the other hand, are equally effective in bringing down infla-
tion but have a relatively smaller adverse impact on growth and financial stress while financial
vulnerabilities mildly recede.
Our quantitative assessment of monetary policy using counterfactuals sheds light on mon-
etary policy trade-offs. During the global financial crisis, monetary policy would have had to
either tighten to stabilize inflation forecasts at 2% or loosen to prevent Growth-at-Risk to de-
teriorate. Our analysis thus indicates the potentially beneficial use of an alternative policy and
we show how macroprudential tools - through their impact on financial vulnerabilities - can
be deployed effectively in a complementary way to stabilize the financial system and macro
economy.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
36
References
Adrian, T., N. Boyarchenko, and D. Giannone (2019). Vulnerable growth. American Economic
Review 109, 1263–1289.
Adrian, T., F. Grinberg, N. Liang, and S. Malik (2018). The term structure of growth-at-risk.
IMF Working paper 18/180 . International Monetary Fund.
Adrian, T. and N. Liang (2018). Monetary policy, financial conditions, and financial stability.
International Journal of Central Banking 14(1), 73–131.
Aikman, D., J. Bridges, S. H. Hoke, C. O’Neill, and A. Raja (2019). Credit, capital and crises:
a gdp-at-risk approach. Bank of England Staff Working Paper No. 824.
Ajello, A., N. Boyarchenko, F. Gourio, and A. Tambalotti (2022). Financial stability considera-
tions for monetary policy: Theoretical mechanisms. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff
Reports No. 1002.
Altavilla, C., L. Brugnolini, R. S. G¨urkaynak, R. Motto, and G. Ragusa (2019). Measuring euro
area monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 108, 162–179.
Bekaert, G., M. Hoerova, and M. L. Duca (2013). Risk, uncertainty and monetary policy. Journal
of Monetary Economics 60 (7), 771–788.
Bernanke, B. S. and F. S. Mishkin (1997). Inflation targeting: a new framework for monetary
policy? Journal of Economic perspectives 11 (2), 97–116.
Boyarchenko, N., G. Favara, and M. Schularick (2022). Financial stability considerations for
monetary policy: Empirical evidence and challenges. Federal Reserve Finance and Economics
Discussion Series No. 2022-006.
Carney, M. (2020). The grand unifying theory (and practice) of macroprudential policy. Speech
at University College London.
Cecchetti, S. G. (2006). The brave new world of central banking: Policy challenges posed by
asset price booms and busts. National Institute Economic Review 196, 107–119.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
37
Chavleishvili, S., R. F. Engle, S. Fahr, M. Kremer, S. Manganelli, and B. Schwaab (2021). The
risk management approach to macro-prudential policy. Working Paper Series 2565, European
Central Bank.
Chavleishvili, S. and M. Kremer (2021). Measuring Systemic Financial Stress and its Impact on
the Macroeconomy. SSRN Working Paper.
Chavleishvili, S. and S. Manganelli (2019). Forecasting and stress testing with quantile vector
autoregression. ECB Working paper No. 2223. European Central Bank.
Clarida, R., J. Gali, and M. Gertler (1999). The science of monetary policy: a new keynesian
perspective. Journal of economic literature 37 (4), 1661–1707.
Doh, T. and A. Foerster (2022, December). Have Lags in Monetary Policy Transmission Short-
ened? Economic Bulletin (December), 1–3.
Duprey, T. and T. Roberts (2017). A barometer of canadian financial system vulnerabilities.
BoC Staff Analytical Note No. 2017-24. Bank of Canada.
Duprey, T. and A. Ueberfeldt (2018). How to manage macroeconomic and financial stability
risks: A new framework. Staff Analytical Note No. 2018-11.
European Central Bank (2021). The role of financial stability considerations in monetary policy
and the interaction with macroprudential policy in the euro area. ECB Occasional Paper No.
272.
Fahr, S. A. and J. P. Fell (2017). Macroprudential policy closing the financial stability gap.
Journal of Financial Regulation and Compliance 25, 334–359.
Figueres, J. M. and M. Jaroci´nski (2020). Vulnerable growth in the euro area: Measuring the
financial conditions. Economics Letters 191, 109–126.
Gilchrist, S. and E. Zakrajˇsek (2012). Credit spreads and business cycle fluctuations. American
Economic Review 102 (4), 1692–1720.
Giuzio, M., C. Kaufmann, E. Ryan, and L. Cappiello (2021). Investment funds, risk-taking, and
monetary policy in the euro area. ECB Working Paper No. 2605. European Central Bank.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
38
G¨urkaynak, R. S., B. Sack, and E. T. Swanson (2005). Do actions speak louder than words? the
response of asset prices to monetary policy actions and statements. International Journal of
Central Banking 1, 55–93.
Han, H., W. Jung, and J. H. Lee (2022). Estimation and Inference of Quantile Impulse Response
Functions by Local Projections: With Applications to VaR Dynamics. Journal of Financial
Econometrics 2022, 1–29.
Hollo, D., M. Kremer, and M. Lo Duca (2012). CISS a composite indicator of systemic stress
in the financial system. ECB Working paper No. 1426. European Central Bank.
Jaroci´nski, M. and P. Karadi (2020). Deconstructing Monetary Policy Surprises—The Role of
Information Shocks. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 12, 1–43.
Jord`a,
`
O. (2005). Estimation and inference of impulse responses by local projections. American
economic review 95 (1), 161–182.
Jord`a,
`
O., M. Schularick, and A. Taylor (2015). Leveraged bubbles. Journal of Monetary
Economics 76 (S), S1–S20.
Kilian, L. (2009). Not all oil price shocks are alike: Disentangling demand and supply shocks in
the crude oil market. American Economic Review 99 (3), 1053–1069.
Kilian, L. and S. Manganelli (2008). The central banker as a risk manager: Estimating the
federal reserve’s preferences under greenspan. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 40 (6),
1103–1129.
Kockerols, T. and C. Kok (2019). Leaning against the wind: Macroprudential policy and the
financial cycle. ECB Working paper No. 2223. European Central Bank.
Koenker, R. (2005). Quantile Regression. Cambridge University Press.
Koenker, R. and G. Bassett Jr (1978). Regression quantiles. Econometrica: Journal of the
Econometric Society, 33–50.
Koenker, R., V. Chernozhukov, X. He, and L. Peng (2018). Handbook of Quantile Regression.
Chapman & Hall/CRC Handbooks of Modern Statistical Methods. CRC Press.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
39
Koenker, R. and Z. Xiao (2006). Quantile autoregression. Journal of the American statistical
association 101 (475), 980–990.
Kuttner, K. N. (2001). Monetary policy surprises and interest rates: Evidence from the fed
funds futures market. Journal of Monetary Economics 47 (3), 523–544.
Lang, J. H., C. Izzo, S. Fahr, and J. Ruzicka (2019). Anticipating the bust: a new cyclical
systemic risk indicator to assess the likelihood and severity of financial crises. ECB Occasional
Paper No. 219. European Central Bank.
Mishkin, F. S. (2007). Financial instability and monetary policy. Speech at the Risk USA 2007
Conference, New York City, NY.
Mishkin, F. S. (2009). Is monetary policy effective during financial crises? American Economic
Review 99 (2), 573–577.
Montes-Rojas, G. (2022). Estimating Impulse-Response Functions for Macroeconomic Models
using Directional Quantiles. Journal of Time Series Econometrics 14 (2), 199–225.
Plagborg-Møller, M. and C. K. Wolf (2021). Local Projections and VARs Estimate the Same
Impulse Responses. Econometrica 89 (2), 955–980.
Ruzicka, J. (2021a). Quantile local projections: Identification, smooth estimation, and inference.
mimeo, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid.
Ruzicka, J. (2021b). Quantile structural vector autoregression. mimeo, Universidad Carlos III
de Madrid.
Schularick, M., L. Ter Steege, and F. Ward (2021). Leaning against the wind and crisis risk.
American Economic Review: Insights 3 (2), 199–214.
Schwarz, G. (1978). Estimating the Dimension of a Model. The Annals of Statistics 6 (2),
461–464.
Sims, C. A. (1980). Macroeconomics and reality. Econometrica 48 (1), 1–48.
Smets, F. (2014). Financial stability and monetary policy: How closely interlinked? Interna-
tional Journal of Central Banking 10 (2), 263–300.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
40
Svensson, L. E. O. (2017). Cost-benefit analysis of leaning against the wind. Journal of Monetary
Economics 90, 193–213.
White, H., T.-H. Kim, and S. Manganelli (2015). VAR for VaR: Measuring tail dependence
using multivariate regression quantiles. Journal of Econometrics 187 (1), 169–188.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
41
A Appendix
A.1 Additional results
Figure A.1: Impulse Responses of information shock on short-term rates
(estimated by simulation)
monthly GDP response (cumulative)
0.0
0.1
0.2
1 SD FShort INFO shock
HICP inf. response (cumulative)
0.05
0.00
0.05
0.10
SRI response
0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
CISS response
0.02
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.02
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
1 SD monthly GDP shock
0.00
0.04
0.08
0.12
0.005
0.000
0.005
0.02
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.10
0.05
0.00
0.05
0.10
1 SD HICP inf. shock
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
0.015
0.010
0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.02
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
1 SD SRI shock
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.000
0.025
0.050
0.075
0.05
0.04
0.03
0.02
0.01
0.00
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
0 3 6 9 12
month
1 SD CISS shock
0.10
0.05
0.00
0.05
0 3 6 9 12
month
0.015
0.010
0.005
0.000
0.005
0 3 6 9 12
month
0.00
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
0 3 6 9 12
month
quantile
0.1 0.5 0.9
Notes: Five-variable specification with response of information shock variable excluded. Confidence bands are at
90% and are excluded for the median response.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
42
Figure A.2: Impulse Responses of information shock on short-term rates
(estimated by local projections)
monthly GDP response (cumulative)
0.2
0.0
0.2
1 SD FShort INFO shock
HICP inf. response (cumulative)
0.2
0.1
0.0
0.1
0.2
SRI response
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
0.025
CISS response
0.04
0.02
0.00
0.02
0.04
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
1 SD monthly GDP shock
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.01
0.00
0.04
0.02
0.00
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
0.1
1 SD HICP inf. shock
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.02
0.00
0.02
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
1 SD SRI shock
0.0
0.1
0.00
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.06
0.04
0.02
0.00
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
0 3 6 9 12
month
1 SD CISS shock
0.2
0.1
0.0
0.1
0 3 6 9 12
month
0.00
0.01
0.02
0 3 6 9 12
month
0.00
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
0 3 6 9 12
month
quantile
0.1 0.5 0.9
Notes: Five-variable specification with response of information shock variable excluded. Confidence bands are at
90% and are excluded for the median response.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
43
Figure A.3: Impulse Responses of information shock on long-term rates
(estimated by simulation)
monthly GDP response (cumulative)
0.0
0.1
0.2
1 SD FLong INFO shock
HICP inf. response (cumulative)
0.00
0.05
0.10
SRI response
0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
CISS response
0.04
0.03
0.02
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
1 SD monthly GDP shock
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.010
0.005
0.000
0.005
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.10
0.05
0.00
0.05
0.10
1 SD HICP inf. shock
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.010
0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
1 SD SRI shock
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.000
0.025
0.050
0.075
0.05
0.04
0.03
0.02
0.01
0.00
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
0 3 6 9 12
month
1 SD CISS shock
0.10
0.05
0.00
0.05
0 3 6 9 12
month
0.010
0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0 3 6 9 12
month
0.00
0.02
0.04
0.06
0 3 6 9 12
month
quantile
0.1 0.5 0.9
Notes: Five-variable specification with response of information shock variable excluded. Confidence
bands are at 90% and are excluded for the median response.
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
44
Figure A.4: Impulse Responses of information shock on long-term rates
(estimated by local projections)
monthly GDP response (cumulative)
0.2
0.0
0.2
0.4
1 SD FLong INFO shock
HICP inf. response (cumulative)
0.2
0.1
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
SRI response
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.02
CISS response
0.075
0.050
0.025
0.000
0.025
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
1 SD monthly GDP shock
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.015
0.010
0.005
0.000
0.005
0.06
0.03
0.00
0.03
0.06
0.4
0.2
0.0
1 SD HICP inf. shock
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.015
0.010
0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.02
0.00
0.02
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
1 SD SRI shock
0.05
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.00
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.06
0.04
0.02
0.00
0.4
0.2
0.0
0 3 6 9 12
month
1 SD CISS shock
0.2
0.1
0.0
0.1
0 3 6 9 12
month
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0 3 6 9 12
month
0.00
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
0 3 6 9 12
month
quantile
0.1 0.5 0.9
Notes: Five-variable specification with response of information shock variable excluded. Confidence
bands are at 90% and are exluded for the median response.
A.2 Representing a sequence of external interventions proof
We need to show
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
m {0, 1, . . . , 11}: ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) := ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) + s
m
#
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
#
=
11
X
l=0
QIRC(j, i, l, τ, s
11l
)
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
45
First, we rewrite the expression as a telescoping sum. Second, we use the history independence
property of quantile impulse response functions (4). Third, using the linearity of quantile impulse
response functions (4), we express the difference between the two quantiles as the derivative of
a conditional quantile. Finally, u
i,t+l
is independent of y
j,t+k
for k < l, so we can eliminate the
first l 1 terms from the sum.
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
m {0, 1, . . . , 11}: ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) := ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) + s
m
#
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
#
(14)
=
11
X
l=0
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
m {0, 1, . . . , l}: ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) := ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) + s
m
#
(15)
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
m {0, 1, . . . , l 1}: ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) := ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) + s
m
#!
(16)
=
11
X
l=0
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
u
i,t+l
[0, 1]: ε
i
(u
i,t+l
) := ε
i
(u
i,t+l
) + s
l
#
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
#!
(17)
=
11
X
l=0
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
u
i,t+l
#
ε
i
(u
i,t+l
)
s
l
=
11
X
l=0
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=l
y
j,t+k
u
i,t+l
#
ε
i
(u
i,t+l
)
s
l
(18)
=
11
X
l=0
QIRC(j, i, 11 l, τ, s
l
) =
11
X
l=0
QIRC(j, i, l, τ, s
11l
) (19)
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
46
A.3 Representing a counterfactual scenario proof
We need to show
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
F
t1
, m {0, 1, . . . , 11}: ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) := ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) + s
m
#
=
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
F
t1
#
+
11
X
l=0
QIRC(j, i, l, τ, s
11l
)
(20)
First, we subtract and add the quantile forecast. The second equality follows by the same
arguments as in the proof (A.2). The third equality is due to the history independence property
of quantile impulse response functions (4).
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
F
t1
, m {0, 1, . . . , 11}: ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) := ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) + s
m
#
= (21)
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
F
t1
, m {0, 1, . . . , 11}: ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) := ε
i
(u
i,t+m
) + s
m
#
(22)
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
F
t1
#
+Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
F
t1
#
= (23)
11
X
l=0
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=l
y
j,t+k
F
t1
, u
i,t+l
#
ε
i
(u
i,t+l
)
s
l
+ Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
F
t1
#
= (24)
11
X
l=0
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=l
y
j,t+k
u
i,t+l
#
ε
i
(u
i,t+l
)
s
l
+ Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
F
t1
#
= (25)
Q
τ
"
11
X
k=0
y
j,t+k
F
t1
#
+
11
X
l=0
QIRC(j, i, l, τ, s
11l
) (26)
ECB Working Paper Series No 2870
47
Acknowledgements
The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the European Central Bank.
Paul Bochmann
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: paul.bochmann@ecb.europa.eu
Daniel Dieckelmann
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: daniel.[email protected]ropa.eu
Stephan Fahr
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; email: stephan.fahr@ecb.europa.eu
Josef Ruzicka
Nazarbayev University, Astana, Kazakhstan; email: josef.ruzicka@nu.edu.kz
© European Central Bank, 2023
Postal address 60640 Frankfurt am Main, Germany
Telephone +49 69 1344 0
Website www.ecb.europa.eu
All rights reserved. Any reproduction, publication and reprint in the form of a different publication, whether printed or produced
electronically, in whole or in part, is permitted only with the explicit written authorisation of the ECB or the authors.
This paper can be downloaded without charge from www.ecb.europa.eu, from the Social Science Research Network electronic library or
from RePEc: Research Papers in Economics. Information on all of the papers published in the ECB Working Paper Series can be found
on the ECB’s website.
PDF ISBN 978-92-899-6247-6 ISSN 1725-2806 doi:10.2866/271025 QB-AR-23-107-EN-N