EE_1439_Ferrarini_OL.indd 1 22/09/2014 08:06
Asia and Global
Production Networks
Implications for Trade, Incomes and
Economic Vulnerability
Edited by
Benno Ferrarini
Senior Economist, Economics and Research Department,
Asian Development Bank, Philippines
David Hummels
Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, Purdue
University and Research Associate, National Bureau of
Economic Research, USA
CO-PUBLICATION OF THE ASIAN DEVELOPMENT
BANK AND EDWARD ELGAR PUBLISHING
Edward Elgar
Cheltenham, UK • Northampton, MA, USA
© Asian Development Bank 2014
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a
retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical
or photocopying, recording, or otherwise without the prior permission of the
publisher.
Published by
Edward Elgar Publishing Limited Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc.
The Lypiatts William Pratt House
15 Lansdown Road 9 Dewey Court
Cheltenham Northampton
Glos GL50 2JA Massachusetts 01060
UK USA
The views expressed in this book are those of the authors and do not necessarily
reflect the views and policies of the Asian Development Bank (ADB), its Board of
Governors or the governments they represent.
ADB does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this publication and
accepts no responsibility for any consequences of their use.
By making any designation of or reference to a particular territory or geographic
area, or by using the term “country” in this document, ADB does not intend to
make any judgments as to the legal or other status of any territory or area.
ADB encourages printing or copying information exclusively for personal and
noncommercial use with proper acknowledgment of ADB. Users are restricted
from reselling, redistributing, or creating derivative works for commercial purposes
without the express, written consent of ADB.
Asian Development Bank
6 ADB Avenue, Mandaluyong City
1550 Metro Manila, Philippines
Tel +63 2 632 4444
Fax +63 2 636 2444
www.adb.org
A catalogue record for this book
is available from the British Library
Library of Congress Control Number: 2014938802
This book is available electronically in the ElgarOnline.com
Economics Subject Collection
ISBN 978 1 78347 208 6 (cased)
ISBN 978 1 78347 209 3 (eBook)
Typeset by Servis Filmsetting Ltd, Stockport, Cheshire
Printed and bound in Great Britain by T.J. International Ltd, Padstow
v
Contents
List of contributors vii
Foreword by Changyong Rhee ix
List of abbreviations and acronyms xi
1 Asia and global production networks: implications for trade,
incomes and economic vulnerability 1
Benno Ferrarini and David Hummels
2 Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output
framework for supply chain analysis 16
Terrie L. Walmsley, Thomas Hertel and David Hummels
3 The vulnerability of the Asian supply chain to localized
disasters 81
Thomas Hertel, David Hummels and Terrie L. Walmsley
4 Global supply chains and natural disasters: implications for
international trade 112
Laura Puzzello and Paul Raschky
5 Vertical specialization, tariff shirking and trade 148
Alyson C. Ma and Ari Van Assche
6 Changes in the production stage position of People’s Republic
of China trade 179
Deborah Swenson
7 External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange
rates in developing Asia 215
Andrei Levchenko and Jing Zhang
8 Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships
in Asia 249
Menzie Chinn
9 Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 287
Hubert Escaith
vi Asia and global production networks
10 The development and future of Factory Asia 338
Richard Baldwin and Rikard Forslid
Index 369
vii
Contributors
Richard Baldwin is Professor of International Economics at the Graduate
Institute, Geneva, Switzerland; a visiting Research Professor at the
University of Oxford, UK; Director of the Center for Economic Policy
Research (CEPR), UK; and Editor- in- Chief of Vox.
Menzie Chinn is Professor of Public Affairs and Economics at the
RobertM. La Follette School of Public Affairs, University of Wisconsin,
USA.
Hubert Escaith is the Chief Statistician of the World Trade Organization,
Switzerland and Research Associate at the Centre de Recherche en
Développement Économique et Finance Internationale, GREQAM/
DEFI Aix- Marseille University, France.
Benno Ferrarini is Senior Economist in the Economics and Research
Department of the Asian Development Bank, Philippines.
Rikard Forslid is Professor, Department of Economics, Stockholm
University, Sweden.
Thomas Hertel is Distinguished Professor of Agricultural Economics
at Purdue University, USA and founder and Executive Director of the
Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP).
David Hummels is Professor of Economics, Department of Economics,
Purdue University and a Research Associate of National Bureau of
Economic Research, USA.
Andrei Levchenko is Associate Professor, Department of Economics,
University of Michigan, USA; Faculty Research Fellow, National Bureau
of Economic Research, USA; and Research Fellow, Centre for Economic
Policy Research, UK.
Alyson C. Ma is Associate Professor of Economics, University of San
Diego, USA.
Laura Puzzello is Senior Lecturer in the Department of Economics at
Monash University, Australia.
viii Asia and global production networks
Deborah Swenson is Professor of Economics, University of California
Davis, USA and a Research Associate of National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Paul Raschky is Senior Lecturer in the Department of Economics at
Monash University, Australia.
Ari Van Assche is Associate Professor of International Business at HEC
Montréal and Research Fellow at CIRANO, Canada.
Terrie L. Walmsley is an Honorary Associate Professor in the Department
of Economics at the University of Melbourne, Australia and Chief
Economist at ImpactECON LLC, USA.
Jing Zhang is Senior Economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
USA.
ix
Foreword
The past few years have witnessed the emergence of a large and growing
body of research on global value chains (GVCs), that is the creation of
final goods and services through interlinked stages of production scattered
across international borders. Although GVCs are hardly a new phenom-
enon, the attention devoted to the topic largely is. After years of neglect,
policy makers, practitioners and scholars in the field of international
economics have come to agree that global value chains should figure more
prominently in policies, advice and research.
To be fair, there has been earlier work in the business and economics
literature, focused primarily on measurement of the extent, geographic
orientation, and growth in GVCs. But such work was sporadic, and only
during the past three years or so has GVCs as a topic been receiving the
full attention of the international policy community. Efforts have been
directed mainly to gathering necessary statistics and correctly measur-
ing the value- added trade associated with production fragmentation, as
opposed to gross trade statistics, which mask the true origin of the value
added embodied in goods and services traded internationally. Notably,
the World Trade Organization (WTO) Secretariat launched its ‘Made
in the World’ initiative in 2010, and has collaborated since with the
Organisation for Co- operation and Economic Development (OECD) and
other agencies to establish a statistical platform (OECD- WTO TIVA) that
quantifies GVCs and to increase the measurement capacity of the national
and international statistics agencies. Other notable efforts include the
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development UNCTAD- Eora
GVC database, as well as the World Input–Output Database (WIOD),
which was established by a consortium of universities, think tanks and
international bodies with funding by the European Commission and
launched in 2012.
Proper measurement is an important first step in understanding the
extent of GVCs, and a wealth of path breaking statistics and insights
have accrued from recent efforts in that direction. But what remains is
a far harder task: to understand how GVCs change the nature of global
economic interdependence, and how that in turn changes our under-
standing of policies appropriate in this new environment. This volume
x Asia and global production networks
attempts to take on some of this task, with particular focus on two broad
themes.
The first explores the impact of greater integration and interdependence
on economies’ exposure to adverse shocks elsewhere in the world, such as
natural disasters, political disputes, or recessions. Various chapters inves-
tigate to what extent do global value chains serve to transmit and even
magnify shocks across national borders and, when a national economy
absorbs the blow from an international shock, how firms respond. The
second theme looks at the evolution of global value chains at the firm level
and how this will affect competitiveness in Asia. Various chapters explore
theory and data at the firm level to understand the evolution of GVCs
within and across countries.
In this volume, authors bring to bear a wide variety of methodologi-
cal tools and data, and perspectives ranging from the firm-level micro
economy to the global macro economy to help understand how GVCs are
reshaping interdependence in Asia. With its emphasis on analysis, rather
than policy, this volume aims at providing scholars and stakeholders with
an analytical toolbox useful to conceptualizing and assessing the relevant
phenomena. Future work will have to complement these analytical aspects
with in- depth discussions about the policy and regulatory implications
stemming from the latest progress in this line of research, which largely
represents a joint effort and work in progress by a large community of
international and national policy makers, academia, and think- tanks.
I would like to thank Benno Ferrarini and David Hummels for their
outstanding leadership, coordination and management of the research
underlying this volume, and Cindy Castillejos- Petalcorin for invaluable
administrative support and editorial assistance. The volume benefitted
from excellent inputs from Richard Niebuhr as copy editor, and from
helpful advice by Anna Sherwood of the ADB Department for External
Relations on contractual matters concerning its publication. Joseph
Zveglich Jr provided strategic support and guidance throughout the study.
My special acknowledgement goes to the many scholars who contributed
their invaluable expertise to this study.
Changyong Rhee
Chief Economist, Asian Development Bank
xi
Abbreviations and acronyms
ADB Asian Development Bank
AIO Asian input–output
APL average propagation length
ASEAN Association of Southeast Asian Nations
B2B business- to- business
BACI Base pour l’analyse du commerce internationale
BEC Broad Economic Classification
CAD computer- aided design
CDE constant difference of elasticity
CEPII Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et d’Informations
Internationales
CES constant elasticity of substitution
CGE computable general equilibrium
CIF cost, insurance and freight
CNY Chinese yuan
CO
2
carbon dioxide
COMTRADE Commodity Trade Statistics Database
CPC Central Product Classification
CPI consumer price index
CRED Centre for Research on Epidemiology of Disasters
CT coordination technologies
DC developing countries
DGP data- generating process
EA East Asia
EBOPS Extended Balance of Payments Services Classification
ECLAC Economic Committee for Latin America and the
Caribbean
ELE electrical equipment
EM- DAT Emergency Events Database
Eora Eora multi- region input–output database
EU European Union
EUROSTAT European Commission statistics
EXIOBASE global, detailed multi- regional environmentally extended
supply and use/input–output database
xii Asia and global production networks
FAO Food and Agriculture Organization
FDI foreign direct investment
FOB free on board
G5 Group of five (France, Germany, Japan, the United
Kingdom, the United States)
G7 Group of Seven (Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan,
the United Kingdom, the United States)
G- 20 Group of Twenty (Argentina, Australia, Brazil, Canada,
the People’s Republic of China, France, Germany, India,
Indonesia, Italy, Japan, the Republic of Korea, Mexico,
the Russian Federation, Saudi Arabia, South Africa,
Turkey, the United Kingdom, the United States, and the
European Union)
GAD Global Antidumping Database
GATT General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
GDP gross domestic product
GTAP Global Trade Analysis Project
GTAP- ICIO Global Trade Analysis Project- Inter- Country
Input–Output
GVCs global value chains
HHI Herfindahl–Hirschman Index
HP Hodrick–Prescott
HQ headquarters
HS Harmonized System
ICIO inter- country input–output
ICT information and communication technology
IDE- JETRO Institute of Developing Economies- Japan External Trade
Organization
IIO international input–output
IIT intra- industry trade
ILO International Labour Organization
IMF International Monetary Fund
IO input–output
IOT input–output table
IRF impulse response functions
ISIC International Standard Industrial Classification of All
Economic Activities
MNEs multinational enterprises
MRIO multi- region, input–output
NBER National Bureau of Economic Research
NICs newly industrialized countries
NSO national statistical office
Abbreviations and acronyms xiii
OECD Organisation for Economic Co- operation and
Development
OLS ordinary least squares
PPP purchasing power parity
PRC People’s Republic of China
RCA relative comparative advantage
RER real exchange rate
SC supply chain
SCT supply chain trade
SCV supply chain vulnerability
SDR Special Drawing Rights
SITC Standard International Trade Classification
SNA system of national accounts
SOE state owned enterprise
SUT supply and use table
TEC trade by enterprise characteristics
TFP total factor productivity
TiVA OECD- WTO trade in value added database
TOSP tasks, occupations, stages, products
ToT terms of trade
UK United Kingdom
UN United Nations
UNCTAD UN Conference on Trade and Development
UNIDO United Nations Industrial Development Organization
US United States
VA value added
VAR vector autoregressions
WDI World Development Indicators
WIOD World Input–Output Database
WTO World Trade Organization
WTW World Trade Web
ADB recognizes China by the name People’s Republic of China.
1
1. Asia and global production
networks: implications for trade,
incomes and economic vulnerability
Benno Ferrarini and David Hummels
1. INTRODUCTION
Global value chains (GVCs) involve the production of goods and services
through interlinked stages of production scattered across international
borders. The international exchange of intermediate inputs, as opposed to
final consumer goods, is a phenomenon as old as trade itself. What is new
in the global economy is rapid growth in the extent and the complexity of
global value chains. Nowhere in the world is production fragmented quite
as much, or GVCs quite as complex or as fast growing, as in Asia.
As a consequence, there has been a widespread recognition by policy
makers, practitioners and scholars in the field of international economics
that global value chains should figure more prominently in their policies,
advice and research. Early academic work focused primarily on measure-
ment of the extent, geographic orientation, and growth in GVCs (Arndt
and Kierzkowski 2001; Hummels, Ishii and Yi 2001; Grossman and Rossi-
Hansberg 2008; Kimura 2006; Johnson and Noguera 2012). Among inter-
national bodies, the World Trade Organization (WTO) Secretariat launched
its “Made in the World” initiative in 2010, and has collaborated since with
the Organisation for Co- operation and Economic Development (OECD)
to establish a statistical platform (OECD- WTO TiVA) to quantify GVCs
and to increase measurement capacity. Reports have thus proliferated by
international bodies, including the World Bank (Cattaneo et al. 2010),
IDE/JETRO and WTO (2011), OECD (2013), and UNCTAD (2013), and
various think tanks and other bodies, such as the World Economic Forum
(2012) and the Fung Global Institute (Park et al. 2013; Elms and Low 2013).
New measures have opened up insights into the extent and complexity
of global production networks. For example, Figure 1.1 shows a network
graph based on the OECD- WTO TIVA indicator of value added embodied
in 2009 gross exports by source country.
1
Three hubs the United States
2
AUS
KOR
HKG
CHL
PHI
INO
VIE
SAU
NET
RUS
USA
GER
FRA
UKG
LTU
TUR
BEL
JPN
SWI
POR
POL
CZE
LUX
AUT
NOR
SVK
ITA
SPA
HUN
>40%
>60%
>80%
DEN
ISR
SWE
IRE
MEX
CAN
SIN
MAL
BRA
PRC
TAP
IND
FIN
THA
Relative size of countries’ total gross exports
Relative intensity and direction of value added transferred
Domestic value added as share of gross exports
Note: Based on OECD- WTO TiVA database, accessed 5 October 2013.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure 1.1 Global value chains in 2009
Implications for trade, incomes and economic vulnerability 3
(US), Germany and the People’s Republic of China (PRC)are seen at the
center of a tightly knit web of value added transfers mainly among regional
economies engaged in split production processes. The US is positioned at
the center of the global supply chains both as the largest gross exporter of
goods and services and as the main exporter of US value added embodied
in other countriesexports. Germany and the PRC follow in the ranks in
terms of gross (direct) and value added (indirect) exports. Compared to the
US, these economies are positioned further downstream the value chains,
involving a substantial share of value added inflows and outflows.
2
In the
European regional network, horizontal integration prevails, with value
added flowing in both directions among country pairs. Asian production
networks are more hierarchical. At the top, countries such as Japan – and
the US from outside the region – inject value added through the provision
of key components and services to the PRC, the hub downstream, as well
as through Malaysia, Thailand and to a lesser extent the other Association
of Southeast Asian Nations economies as well as India. Other key players,
right at the center of the regional networks, are the Republic of Korea,
Taipei,China, as well as Singapore, each economy exporting high shares of
foreign value added in reflection of their strong GVC involvement.
Baldwin and Forslid (Chapter 10) in this volume provide a deeper
insight into the genesis and development of the Asian production net-
works, drawing on the latest data and insights that have become available
during the past two years, while Escaith (Chapter 9) delves into methodo-
logical issues concerning measuring and mapping of trade associated with
GVCs’ activities.
Proper measurement is an appropriate first step in understanding the
extent of GVCs, but it is only a beginning. What remains is a far harder
task: to understand how GVCs change the nature of global economic
interdependence, and how that in turn changes our understanding of poli-
cies appropriate in this new environment. The chapters in this volume are
focused on this harder task. The authors bring to bear a wide variety of
methodological tools and data, and perspectives ranging from the firm-
level micro economy to the global macro economy to help understand how
GVCs are reshaping interdependence in Asia.
2. ANALYTICAL TOOLS TO ASSESS THE
IMPLICATIONS OF GVCS FOR TRADE,
INCOMES AND ECONOMIC VULNERABILITY
We have two broad themes. We start with a topic of great concern to
scholars and policy makers. Greater integration and interdependence
4 Asia and global production networks
can lead to efficiency gains, but it can also expose national economies to
adverse shocks (natural disasters, political disputes, recessions) elsewhere
in the world. This suggests several important but underexplored questions.
One, to what extent do global value chains serve to transmit and even
magnify shocks across national borders? Two, when a national economy
absorbs the blow from an international shock, what are the most impor-
tant response margins? That is, do firms respond to the failure of a key
supplier or a drop off in foreign demand by shifting to new partners? If
not, do these trade shocks result in large changes in output and employ-
ment, or are they absorbed through changes in factor and product prices?
Of course, shocks need not be abrupt to have important effects at the mac-
roeconomic level. Rebalancing current account surpluses may take years
or decades, and the ways in which rebalancing is absorbed will depend
critically on how nations are linked through GVCs in both consumption
and production.
Our second theme is focused on the evolution of global value chains at
the firm level and how this will affect competitiveness in Asia. Global value
chains allow firms to specialize in stages of production in which they excel,
leaving remaining stages to other firms or other nations. Conceptually this
is a straightforward proposition applying the principle of comparative
advantage to exchanging stages of production rather than final goods.
What remains unclear are the sources of advantage at the firm level.
Perhaps firm advantages are based on technological sophistication, the
realization of scale economies, arbitrage of policy differentials, or simply,
factor input costs. Also unclear is how firm advantages trade off against
the greater coordination costs of realizing these advantages in a far- flung
“global factory”. Various chapters explore theory and data at the firm
level to understand the evolution of GVCs within and across countries.
2.1 Disaster Impact Assessments with the GTAP Supply Chain Model
Walmsley, Hertel and Hummels (Chapter 2 in this volume) and Hertel,
Hummels and Walmsley (Chapter 3 in this volume) provide a set of tools
for analyzing global value chains in a full general equilibrium context.
Their approach can be thought of as a bridge between two important
literatures related to GVCs: multi- region input–output (MRIO) analysis
and computable general equilibrium (CGE) analysis. In a MRIO analysis
researchers link national input–output tables with trade data to construct
an international, multi- region IO table. Rather than examine total input
usage for each industry, as is the case in national tables, a MRIO provides
information on the source of these inputs. With this disaggregation a
researcher can calculate the share of foreign versus domestic value added
Implications for trade, incomes and economic vulnerability 5
in output and exports for a particular industry, or further break foreign
value added into specific source countries. That is, a MRIO distinguishes
the value of Korean and Chinese steel used in the Japanese automobile
industry, enabling researchers to examine how the Republic of Korea
and the PRC are differentially affected by a shock to Japan. Such tables
provide the basis of most trade in value added statistics and macro level
assessments of global value chains. Additional details on the strengths
and weaknesses of this approach can be found both in Walmsley et al.
(Chapter 2) and in Escaith (Chapter 9).
The challenge for a MRIO comes when a researcher wants to go beyond
a static look at the data and consider changes to the world economy.
That is, a MRIO describes a particular pattern of input–output use that
prevailed at a point in time, but is not well suited to analyzing what will
happen to that pattern should there be a significant shock to an economy.
To answer such questions requires a full computable general equilibrium
model that can track behavioral responses in production, consumption,
and trade.
Walmsley et al. (Chapter 2) provide a detailed discussion of how to
embed MRIO- like data on global value chains into GTAP, a widely used
CGE tool for world trade analysis. The resulting model is called GTAP-
SC (“Supply Chain”). This methodological piece includes a discussion of
the challenges and choices involved in reconciling disparate data sources
on GVCs. The chapter then provides a series of exercises meant to illus-
trate how MRIO and CGE approaches differ when analyzing changes
to global value chains. The authors show that standard MRIO analysis
is actually an extremely restrictive version of a CGE analysis in which
one assumes that output can instantaneously and costlessly adjust to any
shock to the system. The GTAP- SC model allows for much more general
responses, including evaluating how shocks lead to price changes, which
in turn induce substitution in production and consumption, both within
and across countries. The results here are illuminating in themselves,
but readers may find them even more useful as a kind of guidebook to
pursuing their own analysis of GVCs.
Hertel et al. (Chapter 3) employ the GTAP- SC model to evaluate two
major disasters that reduce output and productivity: the first in the elec-
tronics sector in Taipei,China and the second at the Port of Singapore.
The model traces through effects on goods and factor markets, focus-
ing on the distribution of effects as a function of GVC linkages to these
sectors. A clear distinction arises between sectors and countries that are
vertically linked to the disrupted area versus sectors and countries that are
substitutes. Vertically linked sectors suffer while substitutes enjoy tremen-
dous growth as they at least temporarily replace the disrupted production.
6 Asia and global production networks
A novel part of the analysis is the ability to evaluate changes that occur at
different time horizons. For example, at very short time horizons, output
quantities may be slow to respond to shocks, so all adjustment must
occur through prices. At medium horizons, some factors of production
(unskilled labor) may be mobile across firms, while others (capital to build
factories) are not, which allows for adjustment to occur through a mix of
price and quantity changes. Similarly, by varying substitution parameters
in the model, the authors can experiment with inputs as vitally necessary
(very difficult to replace), or commodities (easy to replace) to gauge the
resulting impact.
2.2 Natural Disasters Impact Assessment through Regression Analysis
We can think of Hertel et al. (Chapter 3) as a stylized simulation of
what might happen in some future disastrous event, tracing through the
effects on output, trade, employment, wages, and prices. Puzzello and
Raschky (Chapter 4) also examine natural disasters, but they focus on
disasters that have actually occurred and econometrically examine the
linkage between these disasters and trade flows. They draw on a com-
prehensive database of natural disasters (drought, earthquakes, floods,
wind storms) that provides data on the number of persons affected,
numbers killed, and estimated dollar damage for all countries worldwide
during the period 1995–2010. Using this data, they construct measures
of the vulnerability of global value chains to natural disasters. For each
country and industry, these measures capture the proportion of inputs
provided by suppliers struck by at least one large natural disaster in a
given year.
Next, they estimate a regression model that explains a country’s exports
at the industry level as a function of, among other factors, the vulner-
ability to natural disasters of that country- industry’s supply chain. The
causal channel here is straightforward. If an industry relies heavily on
inputs whose supply is disrupted by a disaster, it should raise costs or
lower production for that industry, and this will show up in reduced inter-
national competitiveness and exports. This is not inevitable, of course. It
may be that, while firms purchase inputs from abroad they are not truly
dependent on them. Rather, they may find it relatively easy to switch
away from a disaster- struck supplier to an alternative vendor, with costs,
competitiveness and exports unimpeded.
These authors reveal a set of interesting facts. They find that manu-
facturing products are highly exposed to large natural disasters abroad,
which is consistent with the high incidence of input trade in the manufac-
turing sector. Asia and North America are the regions most vulnerable to
Implications for trade, incomes and economic vulnerability 7
large natural disasters both at home and abroad, both because they are
more disaster prone and because production there is more globalized. The
regression estimates show that higher supply chain vulnerability to large
natural disasters significantly reduces exports, and that the effects are
larger when large disasters happen at home. More complex industries are
little affected by disasters at home, but are affected by disasters abroad.
This is consistent with the idea that firms find it relatively easy to substi-
tute away from affected inputs when they are domestically sourced inputs,
but find it difficult to do the same for imported inputs.
2.3 Impact Assessment of Current Account Rebalancing in Asia
While natural disasters are an excellent laboratory for examining abrupt
changes to GVCs and the world economy, not all shocks are abrupt or
unanticipated. Even slow moving changes can have profound effects if
they fundamentally reorder patterns of production and consumption.
Levchenko and Zhang (Chapter 7) examine one such shock, current
account rebalancing in Asia. A country running a trade surplus is spend-
ing less than the value of its output. Rebalancing an elimination of the
trade surplus then by construction increases the country’s total spend-
ing. Classical theory predicts that an elimination of a trade surplus in a
country: (i) increases both relative and real incomes; (ii) appreciates the
real exchange rate; (iii) increases the employment share in the non- traded
sector; and (iv) reduces exports. All of these effects are reversed in the
trade deficit countries as the trade imbalance is eliminated.
While useful starting points, classic theory on rebalancing is based on
stylized small- country or two- country models that are too simplistic to
reliably gauge the magnitudes involved. The real world features many het-
erogeneous countries with highly asymmetric trade relationships between
them. While this distinction is non- existent in two- country models, in the
real world the elimination of the PRC’s trade surplus will likely have a
very different global impact than the elimination of Japan’s trade surplus,
as those two countries occupy different positions in the world trading
system. Since there are differences in the nature and orientation of global
value chains feeding inputs into traded and nontraded sectors, rebalancing
will have differential effects on these suppliers.
Levchenko and Zhang base their analysis on a quantitative Ricardian-
Heckscher–Ohlin framework that features 75 countries (including 14
from developing Asia), 19 tradeable and 1 non- tradeable sector, multiple
factors of production, as well as the full set of cross- sectoral input–output
linkages forming a global supply chain. They begin with a baseline equilib-
rium that matches the observed levels of trade imbalances in each country
8 Asia and global production networks
in 2011, and then compare outcomes to a counterfactual scenario in which
each country is constrained to have balanced trade.
In their sample of 14 developing Asia countries, seven have trade sur-
pluses and seven trade deficits in 2011. Rebalancing leads to the following
effects. The surplus countries experience a large increase in wages relative
to the US, 17.5 percent on average. There is a modest (at the median, 4
percent) increase in the share of labor employed in the non- traded sector
as these countries stop transferring income abroad and instead use it to
purchase domestically produced goods and services. The trade- weighted
real exchange rate (RER) for the surplus countries in developing Asia
appreciates slightly, 1.47 percent on average. While one might expect
larger adjustments given the magnitude of the rebalancing involved, it is
important to keep in mind patterns of trade. Much of these countries’ trade
is with each other, and thus even as they are all appreciating relative to the
US, their trade- weighted appreciation is much smaller. The Republic of
Korea and Taipei,China even experience modest RER depreciations.
The impact of external rebalancing on welfare is much smaller than on
either relative wages or RERs. At the median, these countries experience a
rise in welfare of 0.4 percent, two orders of magnitude less than the average
increase in the relative wage. This is sensible: as these countries’ relative
wages rise dramatically, so do domestic prices. The net impact is positive
(with the sole exception of the Republic of Korea), but much smaller than
the gross changes in either wages or price levels. For countries running
deficits, the adjustments are the opposite of the surplus countries, and
of similar magnitudes, though welfare losses are much more substantial.
Finally, the authors track the changes due to rebalancing through global
value chains. A country’s welfare changes due to global rebalancing are
strongly positively correlated with whether it exports mostly to the deficit
or to surplus countries. Thus, multilateral trade relationships are crucial
for fully understanding the importance of rebalancing.
2.4 Monetary, Exchange Rate Policy and Business Cycle Analysis in
Light of GVCs
Continuing with a macroeconomic focus, Chinn (Chapter 8) offers a
broad look at how GVCs change the measurement and estimation of
key macroeconomic variables and relationships. In a world where all
trade is in final goods and all goods are traded, the real exchange rate
is easily defined and measured as the nominal exchange rate net of the
price level for final goods at home and abroad. In the presence of global
value chains, real exchange rates are conceptually difficult. Chinn reviews
two approaches in the literature, which turn on whether consumers have
Implications for trade, incomes and economic vulnerability 9
preferences over value- added (i.e. consumers care about each stage in
production and so real exchange rates must reflect where each stage took
place), or only over the final good, in which case global value chains only
matter to the extent that multi- stage production reduces the price of that
good. This literature shows that accounting for GVCs gives a picture
of the RER that differs significantly from conventional measures. For
example, using a GVC adjusted RER, the PRC’s effective exchange rate
appreciated 11.4 percentage points more than was implied using conven-
tional measures. These adjusted measures also significantly change our
measurement and interpretation of how the RER affects trade quantities
(i.e. the elasticity of trade with respect to movements in the RER) and
prices (the degree of pass- through).
Chinn next turns to business cycles. A number of researchers have
claimed that deeper integration via global value chains causes a greater
degree of business cycle synchronization. Chinn provides static and
dynamic exercises to examine whether there have been changes in theextent
of synchronization in Asia over time. First, he calculates thecorrelation of
quarterly GDP growth for Asian country pairs over the 1990–1996 and
1999–2012 periods, using a variety of techniques (HP filters, quadratic and
log detrending) to isolate business cycle components. Correlation coeffi-
cients among Asian country pairs rise significantly, especially those pairs
involving the PRC. As an accompanying exercise focused on dynamics,
Chinn estimates a non- structural VAR to evaluate the impulse response of
each country to output gaps in other countries.
Finally, Chinn analyzes whether global value chains alter the conduct
of monetary and exchange rate policy. The starting point is the idea that
policymakers will value a stable exchange rate when there is more produc-
tion sharing, and therefore more commercial transactions whose value will
be made uncertain by a fluctuating exchange rate. Further, if countries
desire to stabilize, do they stabilize against the US dollar or, owing to the
centrality of the PRC in Asian value chains, do they stabilize against the
Chinese yuan (CNY)? Previous work using daily currency movements has
shown that central banks now place more weight on the CNY than they
did prior to 2005. Chinn extends this work to longer horizons, monthly
and quarterly movements, and confirms the primary finding that the CNY
has risen in importance as a nominal anchor for the region’s currencies.
2.5 The Progression of People’s Republic of China’s Trade through GVC
Participation
We turn next to two chapters that are focused on the microeconomics
of global value chains at the firm level. Previous chapters in the volume
10 Asia and global production networks
have employed input–output tables to measure GVCs. This is a standard
approach, which is useful for comparability across countries and over
time, but it fails to capture significant heterogeneity across firms within
industries. An alternative approach is to rely on firm-level data that pro-
vides a highly detailed picture of which firms are deeply integrated into
GVCs, relying on foreign suppliers and selling to foreign customers, and
which are not. Chapters by Swenson (Chapter 6) and Ma and Van Assche
(Chapter 5), make use of Chinese customs data that provides a rich picture
of these transactions, including product and origin country information
for inputs and product and destination detail for exports. These data are
further broken out by “processing firms”, which import inputs free of
charge and sell their products outside the PRC, and “ordinary firms”,
which do not enjoy duty free imports, but can sell output domestically and
abroad.
One of the central questions of development relates to the progression
of countries through a rising level of production sophistication. At the
crudest level this can be characterized as a switch from agriculture to
“light” manufacturing to more complex manufacturing, and the literature
has provided a variety of ways to characterize technological sophistica-
tion. The rise of global value chains upends these traditional distinctions.
While a laptop computer may be a highly complex piece of machinery,
embodying advanced parts and technology, not all stages of its produc-
tion are complex or sophisticated. Some assembly stages may be labor
intensive, produced capably by workers with few skills or training. This
raises the question of whether the apparent rise in the sophistication of
Chinese exports (for example, a switch from textiles and apparel to elec-
tronics) simply captures Chinese participation in the simplest stages of
production.
Swenson (Chapter 6) uses the rich detail in Chinese customs data to
characterize changes in the production stage position of PRC firms. Key
to her analysis are measures of “upstreamness” and “stages” in production
developed by Fally (2012 a, 2012b). Suppose we have a production process
involving 10 sequential steps. A firm that produces the seventh step has six
previous “stages”, and is “upstream” from three subsequent steps. By using
very detailed IO tables to measure how far a production stage is from final
consumption, then matching this data to traded products, Fally is able
to characterize the “upstream” and “stage” measure of a given product.
Taking these measures, Swenson can then characterize where Chinese
firms sit in sequencing based on the inputs they purchase and the outputs
they produce. Over time, a firm can change its position in two ways. For a
given production process it can move closer to the point of final consump-
tion (increasing stages and decreasing upstreamness), or further away. Or
Implications for trade, incomes and economic vulnerability 11
it can switch to a more complex production process involving more steps
(conceivably increasing both stages and upstreamness).
In the aggregate, Swenson finds that Chinese firms have increased
both the stages and upstreamness, consistent with the view that they are
switching to production processes that involve increasingly long produc-
tion chains. Swenson next provides an alternative measure of complexity,
the number of distinct inputs used in production. Based only on a count
of distinct HS6 product lines imported, there is a decline in the number
of inputs. This could reveal falling complexity, or it could reveal a move
along the production chain further from final consumption. For example,
production of a microchip could involve relatively few parts, while
assembly of a laptop computer could involve many parts.
The initial work focuses on aggregate behavior of the Chinese economy
so Swenson next exploits firm-level data. She relates growth in imports and
exports to the position of these products in the value chain as measured by
Fally’s stages/upstreamness variables, while using fixed effects to control
for unobservables. There are striking differences between imports and
exports. Import growth is greater for products that exhibit higher stages
and upstreamness (products with longer chains), while export growth is
smaller for these products. Swenson also explores an alternative way to
see a similar relationship. She focuses on the probability of exit, that is,
identifying products that were imported (or exported) at some point by
a Chinese firm, but then cease to be, as a function of their position in
the value chain. Here the results are mixed and depend highly on goods
type. All in all, this chapter represents a wholly novel way to evaluate the
changing advantages of firms within multi- stage production processes.
2.6 Trade Policy Shocks and Production Relocation by Processing Firms
in the People’s Republic of China
Ma and Van Assche (Chapter 5) also employ the PRC customs data, but
in pursuit of a very different objective. They are interested in how global
value chains allow firms to circumvent trade policy barriers. The authors
begin with a model of heterogeneous firms similar to Melitz (2003), but
introduce two vertical stages of production: headquarters services pro-
duced at home, and manufacturing, which is footloose. The mobility of
manufacturing makes it profitable for some firms to circumvent tariffs and
produce abroad. A key insight is that global value chains increase the elas-
ticity of bilateral exports with respect to tariffs. The reason is that a tariff
hike has two effects. First it raises prices and lowers export sales for firms
who continue to produce at home. Second, it induces a subset of firms to
stop exporting and relocate production to avoid the tariff. Note that while
12 Asia and global production networks
global value chains amplify the effect of the tariff on manufacturing at
home, it dampens the effect on headquarters activities, which continue to
operate and provide services to manufacturing plants abroad. This result
is complementary to recent studies that find offshored assembly activities
are more vulnerable to business cycle shocks than corresponding domestic
activities.
Next, Ma and Van Assche investigate the prediction that vertically spe-
cialized trade is more sensitive to a country- specific tariff hike than exports
that are part of local value chains. They draw on both firm- level (2000–
2006) and provincial level (1997–2009) data from the PRC’s customs sta-
tistics, distinguishing Chinese firms based on customs regimes (processing
and ordinary trade). The processing trade regime is used primarily by
exporting firms in the PRC that are part of a global value chain, while the
ordinary trade regime is used by exporting firms that have more extensive
domestic value chains. Apart from legal treatment, this distinction is clear
in the data: processing exports embody less than half as much domestic
value added than ordinary exports, and foreign- owned firms play a much
more dominant role in the processing trade regime than in the ordinary
trade regime. To measure country- specific trade policy shocks, they use
antidumping cases against the PRC at the HS6 digit level as identified in
the World Bank’s Global Antidumping Database (GAD). Ma and Van
Assche find strong evidence that processing exports are more sensitive
to the imposition of antidumping measures than ordinary exports, and
consistent with the theoretical model, this is mostly due to the extensive
margin effect.
2.7 Measuring Global Value Chains
We conclude with two chapters that address broad conceptual issues high-
lighting the rise and future development of global value chains in Asia.
Escaith (Chapter 9) returns to the issue of measurement of global value
chains, setting in context the varied efforts by researchers and policy
institutes around the world. He strongly advocates for a process of theory
before measurement, or put another way, for researchers to understand
what questions they are trying to answer, and what measurement and data
organization tools are appropriate in that context. He reviews work on
input–output table based approaches, such as those used in the chapters
by Walmsley et al., Puzzello and Raschky, and to some extent in those by
Chinn and by Levchenko and Zhang. While these authors draw on exten-
sive work elsewhere and employ it in varied applications, readers may
find their explanations somewhat terse. Escaith’s chapter provides a more
detailed exegesis, including the economic assumptions implicit in these
Implications for trade, incomes and economic vulnerability 13
calculations. As an example, Chinn describes two methods for calculation
of the real exchange rate in the presence of GVCs, and these approaches
turn on whether consumers have preferences over value added or prefer-
ences over final goods. This is conceptually very close to the problem
described by Escaith in terms of using network theory to understand
GVCs. Can we think of consumers valuing electronic components from
Thailand independently of the way they are integrated into the network of
computer production throughout Asia?
When a methodology becomes dominant, as the MRIO approach has
in measuring GVCs, it can become easy to forget its limitations. Escaith
reminds us of these problems, and then highlights the different sorts of
conceptual questions and problems that can be answered with reference to
firm-level data. This points clearly to the strengths of the data approaches
employed by Swenson and by Ma and Van Assche.
As we noted at the outset of this chapter, the study of global value
chains has progressed beyond infancy but is at best an adolescent litera-
ture. There remain a host of interesting questions about GVCs that are
little understood. Indeed, Escaith’s simple enumeration of “what should
be counted” with respect to GVCs illustrates the fairly limited dimen-
sions of “what has been counted” in the literature extant. Ultimately
Escaith’s chapter provides a useful overview of the work to date, and
a rich outline of work to do for the ambitious researcher or concerned
policy maker.
2.8 The Development and Future of Production Networks in Asia
In a similar vein, Baldwin and Forslid’s Chapter 10 provides a useful over-
view of how global value chains arose in Asia, and where they are going.
They begin with the history, describing globalization as two unbundlings
driven first by lower trade costs (tariffs, transportation costs), and second
by improvements in information and communication technology (ICT).
The first unbundling allowed production and consumption to be sepa-
rated by great distances, but production stages remained bundled locally,
in factories and industrial districts. The ICT revolution unbundled the
factories themselves. They illustrate these facts with a series of data dis-
plays meant to illustrate the sharp changes in trade volumes and patterns
of trade in value added corresponding to the period of the ICT revolution.
These displays also provide a useful set of indicators going forward to
track the extent and growth of GVCs.
The second part of the chapter provides some simple conceptual theory
to help the reader understand driving forces between the second unbun-
dling. The first organizes production into a TOSP (tasks, occupations,
14 Asia and global production networks
stages, and products) hierarchy, where tasks, or the most granular activi-
ties, are bundled in groups to workers of particular occupations, who are
themselves bundled into stages, with these stages ultimately bundled into
products. For a product like a laptop computer, we could separate design,
parts production, assembly, and marketing into four distinct stages. The
design stage could involve occupations like electrical engineers or soft-
ware coders, each of whom has a large set of discrete tasks that must be
completed to design a microchip or the computer’s hardware BIOS.
With this setup in hand, the challenge is to think in terms of the optimal
aggregation of occupations and stages, that is, how many tasks should be
completed by each occupation, and how occupations should be bundled
into a given stage. The ICT revolution lowers the cost of communicating
between disparate stages (making it lower cost to disaggregate occupa-
tions), but it also lowers the marginal benefit of specialization as automa-
tion enables individual workers to master more tasks without the loss of
efficiency. This simple framework helps us to think through the extent of
unbundling, trading off efficiency and coordination costs. A key point
here is that relationships are not monotonic; in other words, the model
reveals tipping points at which offshoring can increase rapidly or even
decrease as costs fall. Further, these costs interact with traditional sources
of comparative advantage that may itself evolve. In short, it is not at
all obvious whether global value chains in Asia will continue to grow in
size and complexity, or whether we have hit a high water mark in their
importance.
NOTES
1. Figure 1.1 was drawn with the help of Cytoscape, an open- source platform for complex
network analysis and visualization (www.cytoscape.org). The network graph extends
across all country pairs, involving more than 3000 connections. To avoid clutter, only
the top 5 percent are shown on this map. Also omitted from the map are value added
transfers to and from the rest of the world aggregate, as well as self- looping arches in
relation to countries’ domestic value added. Shown are the top 5 percent of value added
flows among country pairs in 2009, connected by arches whose width is proportional
to source countries’ value added embodied in recipient countries’ exports. Individual
economies are shown as nodes whose size relates to the gross value of goods and services
exports. Darker shades denote economies with lower shares of domestic value added in
gross exports, compared to more brightly shaded nodes. The method is described further
in Ferrarini (2013).
2. In fact, exports by the US (89 percent) contain a considerably higher share of domestic
value added compared with that of Germany (73 percent) and the PRC (68 percent).
Implications for trade, incomes and economic vulnerability 15
REFERENCES
Arndt, S.W. and H. Kierzkowski (2001), Fragmentation: New Production Patterns
in the World Economy, Oxford University Press.
Cattaneo, O., G. Gereffi, and C. Staritz (eds) (2010), Global Value Chains in a
Postcrisis World A Development Perspective, The World Bank, Washington,
DC.
Elms, D.K. and P. Low (eds) (2013), Global Value Chains in a Changing World,
Fung Global Institute, Nanyang Technological University, and World Trade
Organization.
Fally, T. (2012a), ‘Production staging: measurement and facts’, University of
Colorado, Boulder, Manuscript.
Fally, T. (2012b), ‘Data on the fragmentation of production in the U.S.’,
University of Colorado, Boulder, Manuscript.
Ferrarini, B. (2013), ‘Vertical trade maps’, Asian Economic Journal, 105–123.
Grossman, G.M. and R.- H. Esteban (2008), ‘Trading tasks: a simple theory of
offshoring’, American Economic Review, 98, 1978–1997.
Hummels, D., J. Ishii, and K.- M. Yi (2001), ‘The nature and growth of vertical
specialization in world trade’, Journal of International Economics, 54, 75–96.
IDE/JETRO (Institute of Developing Economies/Japan External Trade
Organization and World Trade Organization) (2011), Trade Patterns and Global
Value Chains in East Asia: From Trade in Goods to Trade in Tasks, Geneva:
World Trade Organization.
Johnson, R.C. and G. Noguera (2012), ‘Accounting for intermediates: produc-
tion sharing and trade in value added’, Journal of International Economics, 86,
224–236.
Kimura, F. (2006), ‘International production and distribution networks in East
Asia: eighteen facts, mechanics, and policy implications’, Asian Economic Policy
Review, 1, 326–344.
Melitz, M.J. (2003), ‘The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and
aggregate industry productivity’, Econometrica, 71, 1695–1725.
OECD (2013), Interconnected Economies Benefitting from Global Value Chains,
OECD Publishing.
Park, A., G. Nayyar, and P. Low (eds) (2013), Supply Chain Perspectives and Issues
– A Literature Review, Fung Global Institute and World Trade Organization.
UNCTAD (2013), World Investment Report 2013 Global Value Chains: Investment
and Trade for Development, Geneva: United Nations.
World Economic Forum (2012), The Shifting Geography of Global Value Chains:
Implications for Developing Countries and Trade Policy, Cologny/Geneva,
Switzerland.
16
2. Developing a GTAP- based multi-
region, input–output framework for
supply chain analysis
Terrie L. Walmsley, Thomas Hertel and
David Hummels*
1. INTRODUCTION
With the global economy increasingly inter- connected through interna-
tional trade in intermediate inputs as well as consumer goods, the demand
for analytical tools that trace out the implications of these linkages has
grown significantly. Examples include studies of international supply
chains and trade in value added (Koopman et al., forthcoming; and
Johnson and Noguera, 2012), virtual water trade (Konar et al., 2013), life
cycle assessment of environmental impacts (Hendrickson et al., 1998), and
greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions associated with global trade flows (Peters
et al., 2011). All of these studies require a global database that traces out
these trade flows between sectors and between producers and consumers
of final goods and services, that is, a multi- region, input–output (MRIO)
database. In response to these demands, several projects have been formed
with the goal of producing new MRIO databases, including EXIOBASE
(Tukker et al., 2009), WIOD (Timmer, 2012), OECD- TiVA (OECD,
2012) and Eora (Lenzen et al., 2013 and Lenzen et al., 2012).
An alternative source of global economic data suitable for MRIO-type
analysis is the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) database
(Narayanan et al., 2012), first released in 1993, which has been updated
and encompasses eight releases covering the period 1990 to 2007; a 2011
update is being prepared. The GTAP database is most commonly used as
the foundation for global computable general equilibrium (CGE) models.
At its core, it is very similar to a MRIO database in that there is an input–
output structure for each country that is linked via trade flows to partner
countries. However, while it contains far more policy detail than a MRIO,
the existing GTAP data contains less import- sourcing detail than is found
in a typical MRIO database. Rather than tracing bilateral trade flows to
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 17
individual agents (intermediate and final), the existing GTAP database
aggregates these flows at the border. In this chapter we adopt procedures
found in the MRIO literature to disaggregate these flows, thereby creating
a complete MRIO from the GTAP database. The benefit of adapting the
GTAP database is that it offers broad geographical coverage, and has long
term support from a community of researchers and policy makers who
employ and update the data on an ongoing basis.
A MRIO database is most useful if it is integrated with tools that can be
used to understand the evolution of supply chains in response to changes
in technology, final demands, policy and other shocks. That is, global
supply chains represent a complex set of general equilibrium interdepend-
encies between countries that reflect a combination of preferences, tech-
nology, endowments, and policy. Shocks to income or changes in trade
policy, for example, may result in subtle ripple effects throughout supply
chains that are difficult to understand by considering only retrospective
patterns of output and trade, or by fixing relative prices in prospective
analyses. By relaxing these restrictive assumptions, CGE analysis of global
supply chains can be considerably more flexible and powerful.
In its simplest form, MRIO- based supply chain analysis investigates
the strength of forward and backward linkages from a critical sector or
region to the rest of the global economy. If the Japanese automobile sector
expands by 10 percent, we can use MRIO tools to calculate the quantity of
Korean steel and Thai electronics embodied in a Japanese car, and assume
these sectors expand accordingly. This type of fixed- price, IO- multiplier
analysis relies on some very strong assumptions. In particular, it requires
that there is an infinitely elastic supply of factors available to the economy.
In contrast, CGE analysis would typically take supplies of factors as fixed
and allow prices to adjust and factors to be reallocated across sectors in
order to achieve a new, general equilibrium. That is, an expansion of the
Korean steel sector incurs an opportunity cost in terms of output fore-
gone elsewhere in the Korean economy and the adjustment mechanism is
through changes in factor and commodity prices that cascade throughout
the economy.
We can then think of MRIO supply chain analysis as a special case
of CGE analysis in which there is a perfectly elastic supply of primary
factors that can expand or contract at constant wage and rental rates.
By imposing these factor supply conditions as special restrictions on the
CGE model, we can alternately explore the implications of a given shock
in the presence of MRIO assumptions or in a more general environment in
which these assumptions are relaxed.
Having built a GTAP- based MRIO, this chapter illustrates its use-
fulness through two applications, which have been selected in order to
18 Asia and global production networks
highlight key features of MRIO analysis and extensions thereof. First,
we examine the global labor market implications of economic growth.
We start with a fixed- price IO multiplier model then sequentially relax
the model’s closure assumptions to demonstrate the flexibility of the full
CGE. This application also capitalizes on recent work to disaggregate
labor endowments in GTAP into five occupational categories to under-
stand how economic growth will affect direct and indirect labor market
demands in major Asian markets. We find that the linkages within Asia
and between Asia and the rest of the world make it a true engine for
growth in the world economy. However, sourcing splits are ultimately
endogenous – suggesting that more formal economic modeling is required
to understand how these are likely to evolve.
Our second application highlights both the importance of disaggre-
gating import sources in a MRIO database, and of analyzing them in a
CGE policy setting. Specifically, a key aspect of developing a full MRIO
is attributing import sources for both intermediate and final demands to
individual source countries. For example, it might be that both Thailand
and Japan export large volumes of electronics, but Thailand exports elec-
tronics inputs while Japan exports electronics final goods. To illustrate
this distinction we analyze the effect of eliminating tariffs on imported
intermediates, while leaving tariffs on final goods unchanged. We find
that the additional detail on sourcing can significantly improve our ability
to examine the impact of trade liberalization policies aimed specifically
at firms. Indeed we find that different sourcing shares can affect the size
of the tariff shock and the extent to which other countries gain from
increased exports.
2. BACKGROUND TO MRIO DATABASES
With the increased interest in life cycle and supply chain analyses at the
global or multi- regional level there has been a significant escalation in the
development of databases linking country input–output tables (IOT).
1
Since the motivation behind the development of these datasets is the exami-
nation of supply chains, these databases require information on the value of
imports of commodity
i
by agent (firms, government, households etc), from
source
s,
by region
r.
At this time, however, there is no global source for this
kind of detailed information and data on individual countries (databases
built by IDE- JETRO using industry surveys being the exception). Most of
the global datasets must therefore rely on the proportionality assumption
or the use of the UN Broad Economic Classification (or BEC concordance)
with HS6 COMTRADE data to split imports sources by agent.
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 19
Table 2.1 can be used to better explain the challenge faced by those
undertaking global MRIO analyses. (The table follows GTAP notational
conventions, since they are widely used and well defined.) In an ideal
world data would be available on the commodity
(
i
)
,
source
(
s
)
,
destina-
tion
(
r
)
,
and agent (
intermediate firms (1 . . . j),
VIPMS
i,s,r
:
household private consumption,
VIGMS
i,s,r
:
Government consumption
(
G
)
and
VIEMS
i,s,r
:
Investment).
2
Country IO tables or supply and use tables provide the total purchases
of intermediate inputs by firm
j
(
VFM
i,j,r
)
and the total purchases of final
goods by households, government and for investment
(
VPM
i,r
VGM
i,r
and
VEM
i,r
)
,
as well as the value of domestic sales
(
VDM
i,r
)
and the
value of imports
(
VIM
i,r
)
.
Note that the latter are typically not broken
out by source. In some tables there may also be reasonable detail on
the split of intermediate and final purchases into domestically pro-
duced
(
VDFM
i,j,r
,VDPM
i,r
,VDGM
i,r
and
VDEM
i,r
)
and imported items
(
VIFM
i,j,s,r
,VIPM
i,s,r
,VIGM
i,s,r
and
VIEM
i,s,r
)
,
but again, none of these
imports are disaggregated by source country. Rather, imports are simply
aggregated into a single category.
From the United Nations’ COMTRADE database we can obtain
imports
(
VIMS
i,s,r
)
of commodity
(
i
)
by source
(
s
)
and destination
(
r
)
,
but these are not disaggregated by use within the importing country and,
once aggregated, they do not match the data reported in the IO tables.
Two approaches have therefore been used to estimate
VIFMS
i,j,s,r
and
VIPMS
i,s,r
,VIGMS
i,s,r
and
VIEMS
i,s,r
,
thereby constructing an MRIO
database.
Table 2.1 Creating a multi- region input–output database
Sources Intermediate Final Constraints
Sectors 1. . .j Investment Private
Consumption
Government
Consumption
Import
sources 1. . .s
VIFMS
i,j,s,r
VIFMS
i,s,r
VIPMS
i,s,r
VIGMS
i,s,r
VIMS
i,s,r
(COMTRADE)
Domestic r
(IO Data)
VDFM
i,r
VDEM
i,r
VDPM
i,r
VDGM
i,r
VDM
i,r
(IO data)
Constraints
(IO Data)
VFM
i,j,r
VEM
i,r
VPM
i,r
VGM
i,r
Note: COMTRADE = United Nations Commodity Trade Statistics Database; IO =
input–output.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
20 Asia and global production networks
2.1 The Proportionality Method
This is the simplest method, and has therefore been frequently used in the
MRIO literature. It assumes that all uses of a good are sourced in the same
way. That is, if 10 percent of all Chinese imports of electronics come from
Thailand, we assume that the same 10 percent share applies whether they
are used as intermediate inputs, investment, by the government sector or
household final demand, so that:
VIFMS
i,j,s,r
a
s
VIFMS
i,j,s,r
5
VIPMS
i,s,r
a
s
VIPMS
i,s,r
5
VIGMS
i,s,r
a
s
VIGMS
i,s,r
5
VIEMS
i,s,r
a
s
VIEMS
i,s,r
5
VIMS
i,s,r
a
s
VIMS
i,s,r
2.2 The BEC Concordance Method
This method uses the detailed BEC concordances to split commodities at
the HS6 level into intermediate goods, final goods or mixed. Within elec-
tronics, for example, a microchip would likely be classified as an interme-
diate input, while a laptop could be a final good. Using the COMTRADE
HS6 data with source countries disaggregated, in conjunction with these
BEC- derived splits into final, intermediate and mixed, then allows us
to determine the sourcing shares of both intermediate and final goods
independently. If in the trade data Thailand exports microchips and the
People’s Republic of China (PRC) exports laptops, we will obtain differ-
ent sourcing shares for the aggregated category of electronics, even though
we have no independent information on sourcing shares at the HS6 level.
These BEC- influenced sourcing shares for aggregated commodities
are then applied and the data are rebalanced to ensure the adding up
constraints given in Table 2.1. Given the limited information about sourc-
ing in the BEC concordance, this method only provides sourcing shares
for total intermediates (i.e.,
VINMS
i,s,r
5 S
j
VIFMS
i,j,s,r
) and total final
goods
(
VILMS
i,s,r
5
VIPMS
i,s,r
1
VIGMS
i,s,r
1
VIEMS
i,s,r
)
.
3
It does not
distinguish between the sources of, for example, imported steel used in the
motor vehicle industry as opposed to the coal industry for a given desti-
nation country. Nor does it distinguish between the sources of imported
leather for private consumption as opposed to investment or government
uses. To further split these data across intermediate or final uses the
proportionality assumption must be used. Hence:
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 21
VIFMS
i,j,s,r
a
s
VIFMS
i,j,s,r
5
VINMS
i,s,r
a
s
VINMS
i,s,r
and
VIPMS
i,s,r
a
s
VIPMS
i,s,r
5
VIGMS
i,s,r
a
s
VIGMS
i,s,r
5
VIEMS
i,s,r
a
s
VIEMS
i,s,r
5
VLMS
i,s,r
a
s
VLMS
i,s,r
But
VINMS
i,s,r
a
s
VINMS
i,s,r
VLMS
i,s,r
a
s
VLMS
i,s,r
A number of efforts are currently being undertaken to develop regional
and/or global MRIO datasets. Some of these tables do not yet include the
additional MRIO detail on sourcing by agent, while others have devel-
oped MRIO variants using the proportionality method for example,
EXIOBASE (Tukker et al., 2009) and various GTAP- based MRIOs
(Andrew and Peters, 2013 and Johnson and Noguera, 2012). The World
Input–Output Database (WIOD) (Timmer, 2012), the TiVA database
(OECD, 2012) and the GTAP- Inter- Country Input–Output (GTAP-
ICIO) (Koopman et al., 2010) are examples of global databases where the
BEC concordance has been used to improve the sourcing splits. Table 2.2
lists some of these projects and the differences in their approaches to the
inclusion of the supply chain detail.
4
Since IO tables are not produced on an annual basis, all of the datasets
discussed above will have had to rely on external data to update the MRIO
to a consistent ‘base year’ and/or ‘fill in’ missing information in the IO
tables to ensure consistency in the data across countries. Another feature
of many of these datasets is the availability of time series. The underlying
idea/assumption behind the updating of these IO tables to a new base year
or the creation of time series data is that it is the IO shares that matter and
that these shares do not change significantly between releases of new IO
tables by statistical agencies. In some cases the producers of these datasets
have chosen to release only those years for which they have IO tables
(e.g., the OECD- WTO TiVA and JETRO databases), while in other cases
constrained optimization techniques have been used to fill in missing years
using the structure given in the IO table for another year as the starting
point and updating it with additional macroeconomic and/or production
data (e.g., WIOD and Eora). In the case of GTAP and EXIOBASE the
data are released for one year (or two in the case of the recent GTAP v.8
22 Asia and global production networks
Table 2.2 Summary of datasets
Database Reference Primary
approach used
to include
supplychain
detail
Balancing
IDE- JETRO
Asian
International
Input–
Output
Tables
Meng et al. (2013) Country foreign
trade data and
imported input
surveys
Manual
identification of
errors/reasons
fordifferences,
followed by
manual
adjustment
OECD- WTO
TiVA
database
OECD (2012) OECD tables
and BEC
concordances
approach
withHS6
tradedata
OECD IO Tables
were adjusted to
ensure balanced
bilateral trade
GTAP
Database
Narayanan et al.
(2012)
Does not include
MRIO detail
Trade data given
priority
GTAP- MRIO Andrew and
Peters (2013)
and Johnson and
Noguera (2012)
Proportional Re- balancing not
required
GTAP- ICIO Koopman et al.
(2010)
BEC
concordance
plus additional
detail on special
processing zones
in People’s
Republic of
China, and
Mexico.
Trade data given
priority
WIOD Timmer (2012) BEC
concordances
approach
withHS6 trade
data
IO/SUT data
given priority. No
balancing undertaken
EXIOBASE Tukker et al.
(2009)
Proportional IOT given priority
but RAS used
torebalance and
ensure non- negative
trade
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 23
database),
5
however, not all IO tables derive from the base year and hence
they use similar optimization techniques to update the data to the relevant
year.
3. BUILDING A GTAP- BASED MRIO
In this section we describe in detail the process of converting the GTAP
database to a global MRIO by disaggregating imports of commodity
i
from source
s
by region
r
into distinct uses (intermediate versus final). By
going through this process in some detail, we gain better insight into the
alternative approaches currently employed in this literature.
Table 2.2 (continued)
Database Reference Primary
approach used
to include
supplychain
detail
Balancing
EORA Lenzen, Moran
et al. (2013)
and Lenzen,
Kanemoto et al.
(2012)
IO tables
where available
and BEC
concordances
approach with
HS6 trade data
Re- balanced:
preferences are
based on estimated
standard deviations.
In current version
national IO
tables(e.g., IDE/
JETRO) have
highest priority,
COMTRADE the
lowest
Notes:
BEC = Broad Economic Classification; EXIOBASE = global, detailed Multi- regional
Environmentally Extended Supply and Use/Input Output; GTAP = Global Trade
Analysis Project; IDE- JETRO = Institute of Development Economics- Japan External
Trade Organization; IO = input–output; MRIO = multi- region, input–output; OECD =
Organisation for Economic Co- operation and Development; SUT = supply and use table;
TiVA = trade in value added; WIOD = World Input–Output Database; WTO = World
Trade Organization.
Primary approach is the primary source of the additional MRIO sourcing detail. Where
the primary source is unavailable other methods, such as proportionality, are likely to have
been used.
Source: Sources of information listed in column 2.
24 Asia and global production networks
3.1 How to Build a GTAP- MRIO
The following sections provide an overview of the assumptions made and
procedures used in constructing our extended GTAP database.
Application of the BEC concordance
As described above, we use a concordance from the UN Broad Economic
Classification (BEC), applied at the HS6 level, to allocate commodi-
ties to intermediate, final or mixed demand. The commodities are then
aggregated from HS6 to the GTAP level using COMTRADE weights to
provide the allocation of bilateral GTAP imports
(
VIMS
i,s,r
)
across final
(
VILMS
i,s,r
)
and intermediate
(
VINMS
i,s,r
)
uses by source (Table 2.3).
6
To
allocate across intermediate sectors and final demand types (private and
government consumption, and investment) the proportionality assump-
tion is then used, as is customary in all those datasets using the BEC con-
cordance (WIOD and GTAP- ICIO). Like Koopman et al. (2010) we also
find significant variation between the sources of intermediate and final
use.
International trade data are available for 45 GTAP commodities, 159
importing regions and 231 exporting regions. Missing commodities include
water, construction, trade, other transport, water transport, air transport,
Table 2.3 Creating a GTAP- MRIO
Sources Intermediate Final Constraints
(GTAP data)
Imports 1. . .s VINMS
i,s,r
VILMS
i,s,r
VIMS
i,s,r
(5S
j
VIFM
i,j,r
) (5VIEM
i,r
1VIPM
i,r
1VIGM
i,r
)
Domestic r VDNM
i,r
VDLM
i,r
VDM
i,r
(5S
j
VDFM
i,j,r
) (VDEM
i,r
1VDPM
i,r
1VDGM
i,r
)
Constraints
(GTAP data)
VNM
i,r
5
g
j
VFM
i,j,r
VLM
i,r
5 VEM
i,r
VPM
i,r
1VGM
i,r
Notes:
GTAP = Global Trade Analysis Project; MRIO = multi- region, input–output.
For ‘Final’, we are using E for investment: VEM
i, j,r
5
g
j
[
cgds
,VFM
i,j,r
in GTAP notation.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 25
communication services, other financial services, insurance, other business
services, recreational services, government services and dwellings. Since
the UN COMTRADE database does not cover services it is not surprising
that these data are unavailable. In these cases the proportionality assump-
tion is used to allocate bilateral GTAP imports
(
VIMS
i,s,r
)
across final
(
VILMS
i,s,r
)
and intermediate
(
VINMS
i,s,r
)
uses by source.
The 159 importers cover a substantial proportion of trade between the
244 countries underlying the GTAP database. However, there are five
primary
7
countries in GTAP that have no import data shares from the
application of BEC: Taipei,China, Egypt, Iran, Lao People’s Democratic
Republic (Lao PDR) and Nepal. Taipei,China is also not recorded as an
exporter, although Egypt, Iran, Lao PDR and Nepal are included in the
231 exporters. In these cases the proportionality rule is applied.
Rebalancing
The aim of this data construction exercise is to create a globally consistent,
bilaterally- sourced GTAP- MRIO database while minimizing changes to
the underlying economic flows recorded in the original GTAP database.
Table 2.3 illustrates the balancing problem. We need to find values for
intermediate
(
VINMS
i,s,r
)
and final
(
VILMS
i,s,r
)
demand by source that
add up to total imports by source
(
VIMS
i,s,r
)
,
and that, when combined
with domestic sales, add up to the total value of intermediate
(
VNM
i,r
)
and
final
(
VLM
i,r
)
demand.
Given the high priority which the GTAP database construction proce-
dures afford the trade data, the decision was first made to benchmark to
the underlying GTAP trade data
(
VIMS
i,s,r
)
,
thereby keeping the trade
data intact. The shares obtained from the BEC concordance are applied
to bilateral trade in GTAP
(
VIMS
i,s,r
)
to provide estimates of intermediate
(
N
)
imports,
VINMS
i,s,r
,
and final imports
(
L
)
,
VILMS
i,s,r
.
This is con-
sistent with what was done by Koopman et al. (2010), although it is not
consistent with what has been done in the WIOD database, where the IO
data are given the highest priority.
8
The first issue that results from this decision is that any changes in
VINMS
i,s,r
and
VILMS
i,s,r
resulting from application of the BEC shares will
likely cause a deviation from the original total in the standard GTAP data-
base (for instance, in the case of intermediates
S
s
VINMS
i,s,r
2 S
j
VIFM
i,j,r
).
Since this split between domestic and imported goods, is generally
thought to be the weakest part of the IO table construction, it would seem
to make sense to allow these splits to adjust to reflect the new informa-
tion contained in the BEC shares. Under this assumption, these changes
will need to be offset by corresponding changes in domestic intermediate
(
VDNM
i,r
)
and domestic final
(
VDLM
i,r
)
to retain a balanced IO table and
26 Asia and global production networks
retain total intermediate and final demand (i.e., the final row of Table2.3).
Moreover, if those changes were to cause either of these domestic values
(
VDNM
i,r
or
VDLM
i,r
) to fall below zero, then the sourcing implied by
BEC would have to adjust to restore balance. Under this approach,
the only constraints applied in the rebalancing procedure are those
represented by the shaded areas in Table 2.3.
The alternative is to assume that the domestic- import splits in the IO
table do indeed contain meritorious information, therefore suggesting
that the sourcing shares should adjust to retain the domestic/imports split
reported in the IO tables. Under this option the italicized and bolded items
in brackets in Table 2.3 are imposed as constraints on the new database,
along with the GTAP trade data
(
VIMS
i,s,r
)
.
9
Since each approach yields a different MRIO, which in turn may result
in different conclusions from a given study, we construct and compare
outcomes from three alternative datasets in the subsequent analyses:
1. GTAP prop:
10
GTAP sourcing shares (i.e., the proportionality
assumption is applied as in EXIOBASE; Peters et al., 2011; and
Johnson and Noguera, 2012).
2. GTAP- BEC: BEC sourcing shares are applied to intermediate and
final imports; however the splits between intermediate and final
imports, and hence domestic goods obtained from the GTAP data-
base, are also applied as constraints on the rebalancing. This is akin
to the alternative listed above wherein the italicized items in Table 2.3
are imposed as constraints on the new database.
3. BEC: the IO data are rebalanced, thereby allowing BEC to alter the
intermediate/nal import shares in the IOT, as well as the sourc-
ing shares. The balancing constraints are therefore those shaded in
Table2.3.
For the sake of illustration, Table 2.4 reports the shares of imports of
Japanese wearing apparel to help illustrate what has been held constant
under the three alternative dataset options. There is a considerable dif-
ference between the proportionality assumption (option 1) and using the
BEC concordance (options 2 and 3) in this simple example: Japan imports
much more ‘intermediate’ wearing apparel from the EU and more ‘final’
wearing apparel from the PRC and Viet Nam under the BEC concord-
ance than is suggested by the proportionality assumption. Since it is these
differences in bilateral flows that underlie supply chain analysis, there
appears to be an important role for the BEC concordance in this case.
The difference between GTAP- BEC and BEC is less obvious. Since Japan
imports significantly more wearing apparel overall from the PRC than it
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 27
does from the EU, the share of intermediate goods in total imports goes
down from 3.6 percent to 2.8 percent because Japan purchases mostly final
wearing apparel from the PRC. Hence the share of imported intermediates
in the production of wearing apparel goes down and the share of domestic
increases (and vice versa for final wearing apparel). To keep those import
shares the same (GTAP- BEC), the sourcing shares must adjust back
toward the proportionality shares – in this case the required adjustment in
sourcing shares is relatively small.
Preferences for either the second or the third option will depend on
the extent to which one ‘believes’ that the import shares in the IO tables
(GTAP- BEC) are more realistic than those implied by the BEC shares
(BEC). Which approach is best ultimately depends on the quality of the
IO data relative to the BEC data. Since the split between imports and
domestically produced goods is the weakest part of many IO tables, focus-
ing on total intermediate and final demand as the balancing constraint
(BEC) is a reasonably sound choice. However if a national statistical
office (NSO) has made a serious attempt to estimate these, then it is dif-
ficult to believe that the BEC concordance – one that arbitrarily allocates
goods into mixed, final or intermediate goods at the HS6 level would
produce better import shares by intermediate and final agents than the
NSO. In future work we would hope to utilize the information we collect
Table 2.4 Japanese imports of wearing apparel (%)
Share
in total
imports
Share
in total
demand
Share of imports from
PRC EU Viet Nam
Intermediate
imports
GTAP 3.6 4.3 77.8 9.8 4.2
GTAP- BEC 3.6 4.3 55.4 31.6 0.5
BEC 2.8 3.4 53.8 32.1 0.5
Final imports GTAP 96.4 44.7 77.8 9.8 4.2
GTAP- BEC 96.4 44.7 78.6 9.0 4.3
BEC 97.2 45.0 78.5 9.2 4.3
Notes:
BEC = Broad Economic Classification; EU = European Union; GTAP = Global Trade
Analysis Project; PRC = People’s Republic of China.
Share in total imports = Sum to 100.
Share in total demand = Share of imported intermediate in total intermediated and share of
imported final goods in total final goods. Domestic share = 1 – import share.
Share of imports from People’s Republic of China/European Union/Viet Nam = Sum to
100% across all sources.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
28 Asia and global production networks
from contributors to ascertain how reliable this aspect of each GTAP IO
table might be. Indeed, the best strategy may well be to employ a mixed
approach in which the choice between BEC and GTAP- BEC depends on
the country in question.
Koopman et al. (2010) bring another level of sophistication to the con-
struction of a MRIO database by taking into account the trade reporter
reliability indexes prepared in constructing the underlying GTAP trade
data as discussed in Gehlhar et al. (2008). This suggests that there may
be a preference for data reported by the exporter in some cases, thereby
overruling the importer- based data. It is hoped that once the MRIO con-
struction process is rolled into the GTAP database construction process,
the underlying BEC shares would come from the same source as the
trade data, namely the work of Mark Gehlhar, and hence the reliability
of reporters will have been taken into account. This would increase the
quality of the implied BEC shares and our belief in them.
One can also alter the objective function used in the constrained opti-
mization, rebalancing exercise. For example, Koopman et al. (2010) use
a quadratic optimization process, while we use an entropy- based objec-
tive function. The Koopman et al. (2010) approach targets total inter-
mediate and final demands in the GTAP IO table shares, and therefore
their data are more akin to option 3: BEC, although there are additional
differences in their procedures that would cause other differences in their
database.
Figure 2.1 offers a summary of the resulting demand for Asia’s exports
under the BEC database produced for this chapter. It clearly illustrates
that intra- regional trade within Asia is dominated by intermediate goods:
approximately 75 percent of Asian exports to inside Asia are intermediate,
while less than 50 percent of Asian exports to outside Asia are interme-
diate. This is consistent with the characterization of ‘Factory Asia’ by
Baldwin and Forslid elsewhere in this volume. (Comparable figures for the
GTAP- BEC and GTAP proportional methods can be found in Appendix
2A.2: at this aggregated level the differences between the datasets are not
significant.)
Other adjustments
Having determined the aggregated intermediate and final import source
splits, these are then applied within the broad categories of intermediate
and final demands, using the proportionality rule (i.e. across sectors in the
case of intermediates, and across private and government consumption
and investment for final demands). Adjustments are also made to separate
any taxes, import duties and transportation margins by agent, assuming
the same rate regardless of the agent purchasing the import.
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 29
An aside on labor splits
Since the impact of supply chains on value added and employment is
an important consideration for this chapter, we also incorporate recent
work that splits labor into five categories within the GTAP- MRIO. These
five categories are based on International Labour Office (ILO) data and
include labor cost shares by sector for:
Professionals
Technicians and associate professionals
Clerks
Service workers, shop and sales workers
Agricultural, machine operators, assemblers and unskilled workers
Details on how the ILO data were processed and incorporated into the
GTAP database can be obtained from Weingarden and Tsigas (2010) and
Walmsley and Carrico (2013).
Asia’s exports
100.0%
Inside Asia
43.8%
Final demand
10.2%
Final demand
exported to rest of
the world
70.7%
United States
27.4%
European Union
23.8%
Rest of the world
19.5%
Final demand
exported to Asia
29.3%
Intermediate
33.6%
Outside Asia
56.2%
Intermediate
26.5%
Final demand
29.7%
United States
27.4%
European Union
23.8%
Rest of the world
19.5%
Final demand
exported to rest
of the world
70.7%
United States
27.4%
European Union
23.8%
Rest of the world
19.5%
14.7
18.9
4.4
22.1
Source: Based on Asian Development Bank (2010), p. 33.
Figure 2.1 Final demand for Asia’s exports: broad economic classification
database
30 Asia and global production networks
3.2 Comparing the Alternative GTAP- MRIO Data Sets
For purposes of this chapter the final GTAP- MRIO database is then
aggregated into 20 commodities and 22 regions (Table 2.5). The choice of
aggregation reflects the fact that we are interested in examining the impact
of Asia- Pacific growth on the developing member countries of the Asian
Development Bank.
In comparing the three alternative datasets, there are two shares that
are of special interest. First, we look at the share of intermediate (or final)
imports to total imports under option 3 compared to the same GTAP
share.
11
a
r
VINMS
i,r,s
a
r
VINMS
i,r,s
1
a
r
VILMS
i,r,s
vs
a
j
VIFM
i,j,s
a
j
VIFM
i,j,s
1VIPM
i,s
1VIGM
i,s
1VIEM
i,s
Table 2.5 Commodity and regional aggregation
Regions Commodities
Japan Cereals
Korea, Republic of Other crops
China, People’s Republic of Livestock and raw milk
Taipei,China Forestry and fishing
Other East Asia Resources
Singapore Meat and dairy
Philippines Processed rice
Thailand Other food
Indonesia Textiles
Malaysia Wearing apparel
Viet Nam Lumber and paper
Other Southeast Asia Resource products
India Chemicals, rubbers and plastics
Bangladesh Metals
Pakistan Metal products
Other South Asia Motor vehicles
Central Asia Electronic goods and other equipment
Pacific Islands Other manufactures
Australia and New Zealand Non- tradable services
European Union Services
North America
Other developing countries
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 31
The comparison shows that in all but two cases the main differences
between he original GTAP shares and the BEC shares (option 3) are
in the agricultural commodities. This could be due to a number of
factors.
First, certain countries (e.g., Australia) require that agricultural goods,
such as sugar or processed rice, be sold first to a domestic firm which then
checks and packages the product before selling it to final consumers. The
BEC concordance misses these types of country specific issues, while the
IO table is likely to capture these idiosyncrasies.
Second, many IOT/SUTs do not include individual agriculture com-
modities, reporting instead flows only for a single agricultural industry.
This single industry is then disaggregated/processed in- house at the GTAP
center using econometric estimates based on FAO data which means that
there is no country- specific inter- industry information brought to bear at
the sub- sector level.
In those countries that do break out agriculture in the IO tables we often
find that the distinction between raw and processed agricultural products
(such as rice and grains) is more complicated than the BEC concordance
would suggest. In some cases basic processing may take place on the
farm and/or unprocessed or semi- processed grains may be sold directly to
households, particularly in developing countries.
The countries appearing more than twice in the top 100 are listed in
the right hand column of Table 2.6. While 17 commodities continuously
appear in the top 100, many more countries (57) appeared in the top 100
differences, suggesting this is more of an issue with agriculture than with
specific countries. Not surprisingly, developing countries were more likely
than developed countries to be in the top 100. Of the Asian countries,
Mongolia, India, Sri Lanka, Kazakhstan and the Kyrgyz Republic appear
twice in this list. The top 25 commodity- country pairs, in terms of largest
differences between GTAP and BEC, for the aggregation presented in this
chapter, are listed in Appendix Table 2A.1.
The second key point of comparison in the databases is the sourcing
shares and the differences between sourcing of intermediate and final as
opposed to using the proportional assumption
VINMS
i,r,s
a
r
VINMS
i,r,s
vs
VIMS
i,r,s
a
r
VIMS
i,r,s
or
VILMS
i,r,s
a
r
VILMS
i,r,s
vs
VIMS
i,r,s
a
r
VIMS
i,r,s
In Appendix Table 2A.2, the top differences between these shares in the
aggregated data are listed. As in the case above, the differences are most
pronounced in agriculture, with processed rice featuring most prominently.
32 Asia and global production networks
Other goods include wearing apparel and non- tradable services, which is
related to electricity imports by Thailand from neighboring countries.
4. GTAP- SC ANALYSIS
In order to accommodate this MRIO database, we have also constructed
a new version of the GTAP model, complete with sourcing splits, and
designed to be used in analyzing supply chains. We call this new model
GTAP- SC and illustrate its use through several applications in this section.
In the first section, we use a special closure and parameters file to turn
the GTAP- SC model into a fixed- price IO multiplier model. We then use
this model to examine the impact of a 10 percent increase in net national
income in each country under a succession of three alternative datasets
Table 2.6 Largest changes in the share of intermediate imports to total
imports in disaggregated GTAP 8 Database
Commodities
appearing in
top 100
Number of times
commodity appears
in top 100
Countries
appearing more
than twice in
top 100
Number of
times country
appears in top
100
Grains 21 Morocco 6
Processed rice 19 Ethiopia 6
Other animal
products
10 Bolivia
Turkey
Kenya
Honduras
Ivory Coast
Ghana
Malawi
4
4
4
3
3
3
3
Cattle 9
Vegetables and fruit 9
Oil seeds 6
Paddy rice 5
Fish 4
Forestry 4
Sugar 3
Plant fibers 2
Vegetable oils 2
Wheat 2
Electricity 1
Other meat 1
Wool 1
Wearing apparel 1
Sum 100
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 33
(options 1–3 discussed above). The assumptions underlying the fixed- price,
IO multiplier model are then progressively relaxed. Overall, the results
show insignificant differences resulting from the incorporation of the
sourcing splits and the different balancing assumptions used – particularly
when contrasted with the very large changes which result from relaxing the
economic assumptions behind the fixed- price multiplier model.
To illustrate how the additional sourcing information can alter results,
we then use GTAP- SC as a policy- oriented CGE model to examine the
impact of removing tariffs on all intermediate imports. We compare the
results from the GTAP- SC model under the three alternative datasets with
those obtained from the GTAP model using the standard GTAP database.
Here, the differences are more significant, suggesting that the approach to
construction of MRIO databases is indeed an important topic for further
investigation.
4.1 The GTAP- SC Model
In the standard GTAP model for every region, each agent (firms, gov-
ernment, and private households) chooses quantities of domestic and
imported intermediate inputs (Figure 2.2, left hand side). The three
demands for imports are then aggregated, as indicated below the dashed
line in the left hand side of Figure 2.2 to obtain total demand for imports.
Finally, sourcing decisions for those imports are made at this aggregated
level. This was done because of the lack of data on sourcing by agents and
to keep the model tractable computationally as the number of regions in
the database proliferated.
In GTAP- SC (Figure 2.2, right hand side) for each region, individual
agents choose quantities of domestic and imported intermediates, as well
as determining where to source those imported intermediates (
QIFS
i,j,s,r
,
where
Q
is used for quantity). This acknowledges the fact that firms may
source the same goods from different sources than private households or
government, as shown above. Agents therefore make their decision on the
price paid by them for the imported good, including any taxes and tariffs.
The Armington assumption is still in place, it is just now at the agent level.
Similar structures exist for private and government consumption.
Importantly, this treatment in GTAP- SC allows import prices to differ
by agent, as would be the case if there are differential import taxes or duties
applied to intermediate vs. final goods. Such differences are pervasive at the
GTAP commodity level, once the BEC concordance is used to aggregate
commodities from the HS6 level, since tariffs vary considerably across HS6
commodities within a given GTAP sector. Another instance in which such
differences in tariffs will arise is in those countries where duty drawbacks
34 Asia and global production networks
are offered on imports used to produce goods produced in export process-
ing zones. Without the additional detail on imports by agent, such differ-
ences in tariffs will not show up in the database. (Of course, a full treatment
of duty- drawbacks requires the disaggregation of sectors into those within
export- processing zones and those producing for the domestic market. For
a GTAP- based application of this approach, see Ianchovichina, 2003).
where:
QO
j,r
:
quantity of output of industry
j
in region
r.
QVA
j,r
:
quantity of value added purchased by industry
j
in region
r
QF
i,j,r
:
quantity of intermediate good
i
purchased by industry
j
in
region
r
QFD
i,j,r
:
quantity of domestic intermediate good
i
purchased by indus-
try
j
in region
r
QIM
i,r
:
quantity of imported goods
i
purchased by ALL agents in
region
r
QFM
i,j,r
:
quantity of imported intermediate good
i
purchased by
industry
j
in region
r
GTAP = Global Trade Analysis Project; SC = supply chains
GTAP GTAP-SC
QO
j,r
QF
i,j,r
QVA
j,r
0
QFD
i,j,r
QFM
i,j,r
Di
QO
j,r
QF
i,j,r
QVA
j,r
0
QFD
i,j,r
QFM
i,j,r
Di
Mi
......QIFS
i,j,s,r
......
Mi
.....QXS
i,s,r
.....
QIM
i,r
= jQFM
i,j,r
+
QPM
i,r
+ QGM
i,r
Note: GTAP 5 Global Trade Analysis Project; SC 5 supply chains.
Source: Authors’ illustration.
Figure 2.2 Firm structure in GTAP and GTAP- SC
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 35
QPM
i,r
:
quantity of imported good
i
purchased by private households
in region
r
QGM
i,r
:
quantity of imported good
i
purchased by government in
region
r
QXS
i,s,r
:
quantity of total imports of good
i
from region
s
in region
r
QIFS
i,j,s,r
:
quantity of imported intermediate good
i
from region
s
in
region
r
s
Di
or
ESUBD
i
(in GTAP): constant elasticity of substitution (CES)
between domestic and imported good
i
(same for all agents)
s
Mi
or
ESUBM
i
(in GTAP): CES elasticity of substitution between
imports by source
s
(same for all agents)
We impose a balancing constraint that the quantity of imports demanded
12
from each source by each agent must equal the quantity exported.
QXS
i,s,r
5
a
j
QIFS
i,j,s,r
1 QIPS
i,s,r
1 QIGS
i,s,r
where:
QIPS
i,s,r
:
quantity of imported good
i
for private consumption from
region
s
in region
r
QIGS
i,s,r
:
quantity of imported good
i
for government consumption
from region
s
in region
r
Note:
QIFS
i,cgds,s,r
:
quantity of imported good
i
for investment from
region
s
in region
r
Finally, the model allows for the possibility that technological change,
taxes and import duties may be applied at different rates depending on the
agent purchasing the commodity, and hence these can be shocked inde-
pendently in GTAP- SC. On the other hand, international transportation
margins are not differentiated by agent.
4.2 GTAP- SC as a Fixed Multiplier Model
Supply chain analysis in its simplest form involves investigation of the
forward and backward linkages from a critical sector/region of the global
economy. This type of ‘multiplier analysisis a special case of CGE analy-
sis in which the aggregate supply of primary factors is perfectly elastic
and can therefore respond endogenously to a ‘shock’ in the economy.
In CGE analysis, the supply of factors is often (but not always) fixed,
and any increase in demand leads to a change in prices and reallocation
of factors across sectors. The closure of a CGE model must therefore be
36 Asia and global production networks
adjusted to convert the model into a fixed- price IO multiplier model as
follows:
1. By fixing real factor prices in all regions and endogenizing their aggre-
gate supplies. As aggregate income rises, demand rises and firms can
simply produce whatever is demanded without an increase in costs.
They are able to do this because their access to factors is limitless.
Output is therefore fully demand- driven.
2. The GTAP model has a non- homothetic demand system (constant
difference of elasticity or CDE) for private consumption that causes
budget shares to change as incomes rise. In order to neutralize these
changes in the budget shares, the non- homotheticity in the CDE func-
tion must be ‘turned off’ by appropriately changing the parameter
file.
13
3. Finally, in order to shock a variable, in this case regional income,
this variable must be fixed. However, in a CGE framework, regional
income is endogenously determined by changes in factor earnings and
net tax receipts. And since we have already artificially endogenized
endowments, it makes sense to fix regional incomes. Of course, fixing
a region’s income destroys the link between expenditure and income
and eliminates the general equilibrium characteristics of the model
and therefore further adjustments must be made. In particular, since
Walras’s Law no longer applies, we must impose equilibrium in the
(normally omitted) market for global savings and investment. In
adding another equation, we must also add another variable – in this
case the global index of primary factor prices, which is normally the
(fixed) numeraire. Since all prices are fixed in this closure anyway, the
issue of a numeraire does not come up.
Exploring the impacts of a 10 percent increase in income
In Table 2.7 we use the fixed price multiplier model to analyze how a 10
percent rise in income within one country results in changes in real GDP
within that country and throughout all other economies. Each column
refers to a separate experiment, with the matrix of results showing the
impact on every country of an increase in its own income (along the diago-
nal), and of an increase in the income of every other country (off diagonal
elements in the table). There are several items worthy of discussion.
First, countries tend to gain most from their own growth, rather than
that of others. However, countries that are more globally integrated (e.g.
Singapore, Malaysia, Thailand and Viet Nam) see a larger share of the
10 percent income shock absorbed by their trading partners. All of these
countries have high import and export shares relative to GDP (Figure 2.3
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 37
and Table 2.8), leading to ‘leakage’ of the income shock into the rest of the
world and vice versa. The higher the import to GDP share the greater the
leakage.
Moreover, larger countries/regions (Japan, the PRC, the EU, North
America and DCs) tend to induce higher growth elsewhere simply because
even a small outward leakage in percentage change terms for them is a
large inward leakage for the smaller economies. Of course this is only part
of the story while the EU and North America are of similar economic
size, the gains from EU growth are much larger due to the region being
more integrated into the world economy. Similarly the gains from the DCs
are closer to those of North America despite being half their size, simply
because they are more integrated with the rest of the world (Table 2.8).
Table 2.8 also shows the contribution of own and others’ growth in
the total percentage change in real imports and exports. Not surpris-
ingly the changes in imports from own and others’ growth tends to
follow the same pattern as the change in real GDP. Exports on the other
hand are not greatly affected by own growth, although they do rise con-
siderably as a result of others’ growth. This follows from the fact that
own growth increases imports, which in turn raises exports of the trade
partners (others). The exceptions are the EU, North America and DCs
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
0 2 4 6 8 10
Share of trade in GDP (%)
Own growth in real GDP (%)
Share of exports in GDP
Share of imports in GDP
Note: GDP = gross domestic product.
Source: Authors’ illustration.
Figure 2.3 Scatterplot of import and export to GDP shares against own
growth in real GDP
38
Table 2.7 Impact of a 10 percent increase (shock) in income on real GDP in own and other economies
Impacted
region
Region in which income is shocked
Japan Korea,
Rep. of
PRC Taipei,
China
OEA Singapore Philippines Thailand Indonesia Malaysia Viet
Nam
OSE
Japan 8.27 0.09 0.41 0.06 0.00 0.03 0.01 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.01 0.00
Korea, Rep. of 0.28 6.60 0.69 0.06 0.00 0.03 0.02 0.03 0.05 0.04 0.02 0.01
PRC 0.37 0.15 6.30 0.06 0.01 0.04 0.02 0.04 0.05 0.04 0.02 0.01
Taipei,China 0.36 0.14 1.06 5.48 0.01 0.03 0.03 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.04 0.01
Other East Asia 0.23 0.13 0.72 0.03 4.41 0.04 0.01 0.05 0.04 0.04 0.01 0.00
Singapore 0.51 0.24 0.93 0.08 0.01 3.07 0.05 0.11 0.27 0.16 0.05 0.02
Philippines 0.39 0.11 0.70 0.05 0.00 0.03 6.68 0.04 0.05 0.05 0.02 0.00
Thailand 0.52 0.13 0.68 0.07 0.01 0.05 0.05 4.72 0.13 0.10 0.06 0.08
Indonesia 0.53 0.17 0.38 0.08 0.00 0.04 0.03 0.05 7.00 0.07 0.02 0.01
Malaysia 0.64 0.21 0.86 0.13 0.01 0.12 0.06 0.12 0.16 3.40 0.05 0.03
Viet Nam 0.56 0.14 0.48 0.08 0.00 0.05 0.08 0.06 0.15 0.09 4.92 0.04
Other Southeast
Asia
0.71 0.21 0.31 0.03 0.00 0.03 0.01 0.42 0.25 0.04 0.05 5.67
India 0.08 0.04 0.25 0.02 0.00 0.02 0.01 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.00
Bangladesh 0.04 0.02 0.12 0.02 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.00
Pakistan 0.04 0.03 0.14 0.02 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.00
Other South
Asia
0.08 0.03 0.15 0.02 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.00 0.00
Central Asia 0.14 0.07 0.43 0.03 0.00 0.03 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.02 0.00 0.00
39
Pacific Islands 0.42 0.09 0.44 0.05 0.00 0.03 0.03 0.06 0.03 0.03 0.01 0.00
Australia and
New Zealand
0.31 0.11 0.38 0.05 0.00 0.04 0.01 0.03 0.04 0.03 0.01 0.00
European
Union
0.09 0.04 0.24 0.03 0.00 0.02 0.01 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.00 0.00
North America 0.07 0.04 0.16 0.02 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.00
Other DCs 0.21 0.09 0.31 0.04 0.00 0.02 0.01 0.03 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.00
Impacted
region
Region in which income is shocked
India Bangladesh Pakistan Other
South Asia
Central Asia Pacific
Islands
Australia
New
Zealand
European
Union
North
America
Other
DCs
Japan 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.05 0.36 0.25 0.33
Korea, Rep. of 0.06 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.03 0.00 0.06 0.77 0.56 0.68
PRC 0.08 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.03 0.00 0.09 1.05 0.94 0.69
Taipei,China 0.07 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.09 0.96 0.98 0.55
Other East Asia 0.10 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.11 2.14 0.95 0.95
Singapore 0.32 0.01 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.01 0.21 1.87 1.10 0.91
Philippines 0.04 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.06 0.74 0.66 0.35
Thailand 0.09 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.21 1.29 0.91 0.81
40
Table 2.7 (continued)
Impacted
region
Region in which income is shocked
India Bangladesh Pakistan Other
South Asia
Central Asia Pacific
Islands
Australia
New
Zealand
European
Union
North
America
Other
DCs
Indonesia 0.12 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.09 0.57 0.38 0.39
Malaysia 0.25 0.02 0.05 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.24 1.42 1.33 0.87
Viet Nam 0.05 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.39 1.27 1.08 0.53
Other Southeast Asia 0.28 0.02 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.21 0.72 0.69 0.31
India 7.96 0.02 0.01 0.03 0.01 0.00 0.03 0.63 0.31 0.50
Bangladesh 0.03 8.17 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.85 0.46 0.22
Pakistan 0.02 0.01 8.58 0.05 0.01 0.00 0.02 0.43 0.27 0.36
Other South Asia 0.20 0.01 0.02 7.82 0.01 0.00 0.03 0.78 0.37 0.38
Central Asia 0.05 0.01 0.01 0.01 5.10 0.00 0.03 1.96 0.47 1.57
Pacific Islands 0.09 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.02 6.39 0.40 1.00 0.43 0.46
Australia and
New Zealand
0.09 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.02 7.87 0.45 0.17 0.34
European Union 0.04 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.02 0.00 0.03 8.69 0.20 0.53
North America 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.02 0.27 9.13 0.22
Other DCs 0.10 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.03 0.00 0.03 1.03 0.47 7.53
Note: DCs = developing countries; OEA = Other East Asia; OSE = Other Southeast Asia; PRC = People’s Republic of China.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
41
Table 2.8 Impact of a 10 percent increase (shock) in income on real values of GDP, imports and exports from own and
other economies
GDP US$
million
Share of
exports in
GDP (%)
Share of
imports in
GDP (%)
% change in real
GDP
% change in
imports
% change in exports
From own
growth
From
others’
growth
From own
growth
From
others’
growth
From own
growth
From
others’
growth
Japan 4 377 945 18.1 16.2 8.29 1.71 7.53 2.47 0.31 9.69
Korea, Rep. of 1 049 236 42.3 38.9 6.61 3.39 5.37 4.63 0.14 9.86
PRC 3 701 129 38.3 30.3 6.31 3.69 5.71 4.29 0.79 9.21
Taipei,China 393 763 71.7 57.5 5.48 4.52 3.85 6.15 0.06 9.94
Other East Asia 36 902 56.8 42.9 4.40 5.60 4.87 5.13 0.01 9.99
Singapore 176 760 132.8 104.1 3.06 6.94 2.25 7.75 0.05 9.95
Philippines 144 071 51.1 46.2 6.69 3.31 4.89 5.11 0.03 9.97
Thailand 247 110 72.4 60.3 4.73 5.27 4.38 5.62 0.04 9.96
Indonesia 432 103 29.8 24.8 7.03 2.97 6.99 3.01 0.09 9.91
Malaysia 186 642 106.8 79.5 3.41 6.59 3.27 6.73 0.06 9.94
Viet Nam 68 435 78.4 93.2 4.94 5.06 4.73 5.27 0.07 9.93
Other Southeast Asia 41 246 48.9 38.8 5.67 4.33 6.57 3.43 0.15 9.85
India 1 232 816 18.8 23.5 7.98 2.02 7.49 2.51 0.09 9.91
Bangladesh 68 416 20.4 27.5 8.20 1.80 7.52 2.48 0.02 9.98
42
Table 2.8 (continued)
GDP US$
million
Share of
exports in
GDP (%)
Share of
imports in
GDP (%)
% change in real
GDP
% change in
imports
% change in exports
From own
growth
From
others’
growth
From own
growth
From
others’
growth
From own
growth
From
others’
growth
Pakistan 143 170 14.6 28.7 8.59 1.41 8.47 1.53 0.02 9.98
Other South Asia 54 651 23.9 39.6 7.83 2.17 7.78 2.22 0.10 9.90
Central Asia 199 769 50.6 39.6 5.12 4.88 6.44 3.56 0.37 9.63
Pacific Islands 31 830 40.8 41.9 6.39 3.61 6.83 3.17 0.11 9.89
Australia and
New Zealand
995 228 20.4 20.9 7.87 2.13 8.13 1.87 0.52 9.48
European Union 17 638 780 35.3 35.3 8.69 1.31 8.53 1.47 5.75 4.25
North America 16 519 626 12.7 17.5 9.13 0.87 8.83 1.17 3.95 6.05
Other DCs 8 091 719 31.6 28.6 7.53 2.47 7.97 2.03 2.20 7.80
Notes:
GDP = gross domestic product; DCs = developing countries; PRC = People’s Republic of China.
‘From own growth’ are the diagonal elements of the matrix in Table 2.6. It shows the gains to a country from its own growth. Others’ growth is the
sum of the off diagonal elements (across the row). It is the gains to a country from growth in all other countries, except itself.
Source: Authors’ calculations and GTAP database.
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 43
that are aggregate regions that trade a lot with other countries in their
regions–hence imports from the EU to the EU also appear as EU exports.
Greater global integration means that a country has more to gain from
positive income shocks (and more to lose from negative shocks), and most
Asian countries have trade to GDP shares significantly greater than 30
percent. This suggests that Asia as a whole will be more affected by interna-
tional shocks. To investigate this, we calculate the average regional growth
for ‘Asia (developing and developed)’ and the rest of world in response to
the 10 percent increase in income in particular economies. We find that on
average ‘Asia (developing and developed)’ gains more than the rest of the
world from growth in income in any given country (Figure2.4). Although
not shown, breaking this down into growth in East vs Southeast vs South
Asia the pattern remains, with Southeast Asia gaining the most and South
Asia the least. In fact the lower integration of South Asia means that its
gains are more in line with the non- Asian regions.
Finally we explore the impacts of these income shocks on employment
of the five labor types (Table 2.9). In the fixed multiplier model, employ-
ment of all endowments rises, as there are no constraints on endowments.
In general, the results are consistent with the overall impact on real GDP
from own and others’ growth, although there are some notable differ-
ences. First, when compared to the other occupational categories, agricul-
tural/unskilled workers gain less from own growth and more from others’
growth in all countries. This is due to the fact that these laborers primarily
work in industries producing tradable commodities. In contrast, highly
skilled professional or technical workers are employed more intensively in
the non- tradable service sectors, which means they are more sensitive to
shocks at home rather than shocks abroad.
Recall that we constructed three alternative MRIO datasets, each dif-
fering in its import sourcing splits. When we applied the same 10 percent
increase in real income shock to each of the three MRIO datasets we found
no differences (at the second decimal point) relative to the results in Tables
2.7–2.9. This suggests that the additional detail on supply chains had no
impact on the results under this scenario.
Introducing economics into the multiplier model
In this section the assumptions underlying the fixed- price, input–output
multiplier model are gradually dismantled, ultimately returning us to a
full- fledged, CGE model. Three alternatives are considered:
1. Multiplier: Results from fixed multiplier model
2. Behavioral: In the fixed multiplier scenario final demand is assumed
to be homothetic, while under this scenario, the standard GTAP
44
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
Japan
Republic of Korea
People's Republic of China
Taipei,China
Other East Asia
Singapore
Philippines
Thailand
Indonesia
Malaysia
Viet Nam
Other Southeast Asia
India
Bangladesh
Pakistan
Other South Asia
Central Asia
The Pacific
Australia and New Zealand
European Union
North America
Other DCs
Growth in Asia (developing and developed) Growth in rest of world
Note: DCs = developing countries.
Source: Authors’ illustration.
Figure 2.4 Impact of a 10 percent increase in income in each country’s growth on real GDP of the Asia region and rest
of the world (excludes own growth)(%)
45
Table 2.9 Impact on employment by labor type of 10 percent shock to regional income
Professionals Technicians
and associate
professionals
Clerks Service workers,
shop and sales
workers
Agricultural, machine
operators, assemblers
and unskilled workers
Own
growth
Others’
growth
Own
growth
Others’
growth
Own
growth
Others’
growth
Own
growth
Others’
growth
Own
growth
Others’
growth
Japan 8.7 1.3 8.3 1.7 8.1 1.9 8.9 1.1 7.3 2.7
Korea, Rep. of 7.4 2.6 6.8 3.2 6.2 3.8 7.5 2.5 6.1 3.9
PRC 7.2 2.8 7.0 3.0 6.2 3.8 6.6 3.4 6.0 4.0
Taipei,China 6.7 3.3 5.8 4.2 5.2 4.8 6.3 3.7 3.8 6.2
Other East Asia 5.5 4.5 4.2 5.8 3.9 6.1 4.5 5.5 4.1 5.9
Singapore 2.7 7.3 3.9 6.1 3.0 7.0 3.6 6.4 2.2 7.8
Philippines 7.3 2.7 7.5 2.5 7.2 2.8 7.6 2.4 6.7 3.3
Thailand 6.2 3.8 4.8 5.2 5.8 4.2 7.2 2.9 4.1 5.9
Indonesia 8.5 1.5 7.6 2.4 7.4 2.6 8.3 1.7 6.7 3.3
Malaysia 3.6 6.4 3.7 6.3 4.2 5.8 4.1 5.9 2.9 7.1
Viet Nam 5.6 4.4 5.2 4.8 5.2 4.8 6.0 4.0 4.5 5.5
Other Southeast
Asia
6.2 3.8 5.7 4.3 6.7 3.3 6.5 3.5 5.8 4.2
India 8.4 1.6 8.4 1.6 7.8 2.2 8.0 2.1 8.0 2.1
Bangladesh 7.6 2.4 8.5 1.5 8.4 1.6 8.3 1.7 7.5 2.5
46
Table 2.9 (continued)
Professionals Technicians
and associate
professionals
Clerks Service workers,
shop and sales
workers
Agricultural, machine
operators, assemblers
and unskilled workers
Own
growth
Others’
growth
Own
growth
Others’
growth
Own
growth
Others’
growth
Own
growth
Others’
growth
Own
growth
Others’
growth
Pakistan 8.6 1.4 8.9 1.1 8.8 1.2 8.8 1.2 8.6 1.4
Other South Asia 8.2 1.8 8.1 1.9 7.8 2.2 8.0 2.0 7.8 2.2
Central Asia 6.2 3.8 6.3 3.7 5.7 4.3 6.3 3.7 5.6 4.4
Pacific Islands 6.8 3.2 6.6 3.4 6.5 3.5 7.1 2.9 5.3 4.7
Australia and
New Zealand
8.2 1.8 8.1 1.9 8.1 1.9 8.4 1.6 7.3 2.7
European Union 8.8 1.2 8.7 1.3 8.6 1.4 9.0 1.0 8.3 1.8
North America 9.2 0.8 9.2 0.8 9.2 0.8 9.1 0.9 8.7 1.3
Other DCs 8.2 1.9 8.4 1.6 8.1 1.9 8.3 1.7 7.8 2.2
Note: DCs = developing countries; PRC = People’s Republic of China.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 47
non- homothetic CDE utility structure causes rising income to shift
consumption shares toward the service sector and away from food.
3. Factors: In the multiplier scenario, factor prices are xed and supplies
are perfectly elastic. In this scenario, total factor employment is xed
for each country, and factor prices adjust to maintain this equilibrium.
Because endowments cannot expand to increase output, factors will
reallocate across sectors and any increase in aggregate labor demand
will cause wages to rise.
The impacts on employment (Multiplier and Income) and on real factor
prices (Factors) of the 10 percent shock in income are shown in Table 2.10.
By introducing non- homothetic preferences, rising income causes consum-
ers to shift away from agricultural products toward services. The impact
of this on the budget shares are shown in Appendix Table 2A.3. They
cause the employment of low skilled agricultural workers to fall relative to
real GDP in both the own growth and others’ growth cases. The worsen-
ing position of agricultural/low skilled workers relative to other workers
becomes most apparent when factor employment is also fixed. In this last
scenario the real wages of these agricultural/low skilled workers actually
falls in some cases as a result of the shock to real income (Table 2.10).
Of course, the differences between analyzing supply chains using a fixed
price IO multiplier and a full CGE approach will depend on the particular
question and experiment at hand. The value of integrating a MRIO into
GTAP is the ability to more fully understand which kinds of adjustments
matter and the magnitudes of those adjustments. In this example we focus
on the distribution of impacts from an income shock. Allowing non-
homothetic preferences and price adjustments does little to change the
country distribution of effects. That is, an income shock in Japan mostly
stays at home while the same shock in Singapore is absorbed abroad.
However, we do see significant effects on both the distribution of activity
across broad sectors (agriculture as compared to services) and large effects
on relative wages for different worker types.
In our example, the way in which income shocks are distributed across
nations depends primarily on the degree of outward orientation and not
on the subtle differences in import sourcing splits between intermediate
inputs and final goods. We turn next to an experiment where these splits
are more central to the story.
4.3 The Elimination of Tariffs on Intermediate Imports
In this section we utilize GTAP- SC to examine the impact of reducing
all tariffs on intermediate imports across the entire world, as well as the
48
Table 2.10 Impact on employment or real factor prices of selected labor types of 10 percent shock to own regional
income (i.e., own growth only)
Technicians and associate
professionals
Service workers, shop and sales
workers
Agricultural, machine operators,
assemblers and unskilled workers
Growth in
employment
Change in
real wages
Growth in
employment
Change in
real wages
Growth in
employment
Change in
real wages
Multiplier Behavioral Factors Multiplier Behavioral Factors Multiplier Behavioral Factors
Japan 8.26 8.34 1.04 8.88 9.00 2.47 7.26 7.10 −1.77
Korea, Rep. of 6.84 7.00 1.57 7.48 7.66 2.89 6.11 5.66 −0.02
PRC 6.97 7.17 1.87 6.59 6.60 1.14 6.03 5.69 −0.32
Taipei,China 5.83 5.95 1.26 6.31 6.41 1.89 3.76 3.53 −2.00
Other East Asia 4.19 4.36 0.69 4.49 4.62 0.99 4.13 4.06 0.02
Singapore 3.91 3.95 1.74 3.59 3.63 1.59 2.17 2.15 0.03
Philippines 7.48 7.99 2.37 7.61 8.27 2.73 6.70 5.76 −0.56
Thailand 4.77 4.86 1.19 7.15 7.37 4.29 4.11 3.63 −0.24
Indonesia 7.56 8.06 2.10 8.34 8.94 3.54 6.73 6.27 −0.61
Malaysia 3.74 3.86 1.29 4.10 4.24 1.68 2.92 2.81 0.05
Viet Nam 5.21 5.78 3.04 5.96 6.59 3.88 4.51 4.50 1.29
Other Southeast
Asia
5.69 6.87 1.66 6.48 7.55 2.58 5.81 5.87 0.24
49
India 8.38 9.00 1.93 7.95 8.54 1.08 7.95 7.16 −0.45
Bangladesh 8.50 9.28 2.31 8.30 9.04 1.83 7.52 7.26 −0.94
Pakistan 8.90 9.52 2.55 8.77 9.35 2.15 8.58 8.00 0.64
Other South
Asia
8.13 9.13 3.30 8.02 9.00 3.05 7.83 6.90 0.77
Central Asia 6.27 6.68 3.06 6.28 6.58 2.98 5.63 5.15 0.84
Pacific Islands 6.62 6.84 2.05 7.13 7.43 2.94 5.34 5.37 −0.46
Australia and
New Zealand
8.10 8.18 1.59 8.41 8.52 2.31 7.32 7.33 −0.33
European Union 8.69 8.74 0.75 9.02 9.12 1.71 8.25 8.08 −0.54
North America 9.19 9.25 1.22 9.06 9.12 0.91 8.67 8.65 −0.94
Other DCs 8.39 8.69 2.21 8.31 8.66 2.24 7.77 6.99 0.07
Note: DCs = developing countries; PRC = People’s Republic of China.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
50 Asia and global production networks
impact of unilateral elimination of these tariffs on intermediates by each
country. The policy experiment is designed to illustrate some of the ben-
efits of using a supply chain model, rather than being a true reflection of
how such a policy might be implemented. Tariffs on all commodities pur-
chased by all firms, producing any commodity, are completely removed.
The fixed price multiplier model, outlined above, is not adequate for this
purpose, since we need a model that will allow for the tariffs’ impact on
price. In the GTAP- SC model the price at which firms in region
r
import
commodity
i
from region
s
(
pfms
i,f,s,r
) depends on the cif price
(
pcif
i,s,r
)
and
the ad valorem tariff
(
tfms
i,j,s,r
)
,
which are now sector and source specific.
This ad valorem tariff on intermediate imports can therefore be eliminated
while leaving all tariffs on final goods unchanged. Moreover the countries
from which intermediates and final goods are sourced differ and there-
fore we would expect the impact of this partial removal of tariffs to have
differential impacts on the source countries.
Three alternative models/data sources are used to examine the impact of
removing tariffs on intermediate goods:
1. BEC: Uses the BEC sourcing shares examined above with the GTAP-
SC model.
2. GTAP- BEC: Using the GTAP- BEC sourcing shares examined above
with the GTAP- SC model.
3. GTAP Proportional: Uses the GTAP based on proportional sourcing
shares examined above with the GTAP- SC model.
In addition to the three experiments above, we are also interested in how
these results compare to those obtained using the standard GTAP model.
The results of two additional experiments are therefore noted:
4. GTAP: Using the standard GTAP model and database.
5. GTAP- SC: Using the BEC sourcing shares but removing tariffs on
both intermediate and final goods.
Overview: impacts on real GDP
The impact of these five experiments on real GDP is shown in Table 2.11.
Taking each panel in the table in turn:
First, as expected the liberalization of trade in intermediate goods
(Columns I- III, Table 2.11) benefits most of the world’s economies, partic-
ularly in Asia where intra- regional trade tends to be primarily in interme-
diate goods (Figure 2.1). With the exception of Japan and Viet Nam, the
impact of the three alternative MRIO datasets is relatively insignificant.
As we dig down deeper into the trade results however, further differences
can be seen, and in this section we focus on the results for Viet Nam.
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 51
Table 2.11 Percent changes in real GDP from the liberalization of tariffs
on intermediate inputs
From world liberalization
of intermediates
From world
liberalization of final
and intermediates
From own liberalization
of intermediates
I
BEC
II
GTAP-
BEC
III
GTAP
Prop
IV
Standard
GTAP
V
GTAP- SC
(BEC)
VI
BEC
VII
GTAP-
BEC
VIII
GTAP
Prop
Japan 0.09 0.18 0.18 0.32 0.31 0.04 0.14 0.14
Korea,
Republic of
0.42 0.48 0.45 0.81 0.95 0.50 0.56 0.51
PRC 2.06 2.06 2.08 2.53 2.55 2.01 2.00 2.01
Taipei,China −0.01 −0.02 −0.02 0.06 0.06 0.05 0.05 0.05
Other East
Asia
0.03 0.02 0.03 0.13 0.15 0.01 0.01 0.01
Singapore 0.03 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.03
Philippines 0.06 0.07 0.07 0.17 0.18 0.08 0.09 0.09
Thailand 0.69 0.68 0.67 1.44 1.50 0.72 0.70 0.71
Indonesia 0.07 0.06 0.06 0.14 0.15 0.06 0.06 0.06
Malaysia 0.43 0.45 0.46 0.58 0.83 0.47 0.48 0.48
Viet Nam 1.85 1.96 2.08 3.26 3.91 1.86 1.93 1.95
Other South-
east Asia
0.12 0.12 0.13 0.30 0.33 0.13 0.13 0.13
India 0.69 0.60 0.61 1.22 1.19 0.68 0.60 0.59
Bangladesh 0.29 0.29 0.29 0.53 0.48 0.24 0.25 0.24
Pakistan 0.24 0.21 0.26 0.42 0.44 0.21 0.19 0.20
Other South
Asia
0.26 0.27 0.24 0.49 0.54 0.20 0.20 0.18
Central Asia 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.10 0.09 0.05 0.06 0.05
Pacific Islands 1.98 1.94 1.92 2.25 2.39 1.89 1.86 1.88
Australia and
New Zealand
0.01 0.01 0.01 0.12 0.12 0.02 0.02 0.02
European
Union
0.01 0.02 0.03 0.08 0.09 0.01 0.01 0.02
North America 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.06 0.07 0.00 0.00 0.01
Other DCs 0.09 0.08 0.08 0.17 0.17 0.09 0.08 0.09
Note: BEC = Broad Economic Classification; DCs = developing countries; GTAP =
Global Trade Analysis Project; PRC = People’s Republic of China; Prop =proportionality.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
52 Asia and global production networks
Second, the differences between the three MRIO databases (Columns
I- III) and the standard GTAP model and database (Column IV) are much
more significant. The reason for this is simply that the standard GTAP
model cannot examine the impact of more complex trade policies that
liberalize tariffs on intermediate and final goods at different rates. Of
course when we compare the standard GTAP model with the GTAP-SC
model applying the same shocks (liberalization of both intermediate
and final imports) the differences between the two models are less stark
(Columns IV and V). However, there are some notable differences in
those countries that are highly integrated into the global supply chain for
processing intermediates (Viet Nam, Thailand and Malaysia), the gains
under the GTAP- SC model are larger than for the standard GTAP model.
India on the other hand is not well integrated into the global supply chain,
and hence the gains are lower under the GTAP- SC model than under the
GTAP model. This is due to the fact that countries that import intermedi-
ates more intensely than final goods are more likely to see greater indirect
benefits from trade liberalization, due to lower costs of production, which
in turn flow on to further increase wages, capital rentals, incomes, final
consumption, investment and so forth.
Third, the benefits from liberalizing trade in intermediates are less than
if all trade was liberalized (see Columns IV and V, Table 2.11), however
for many economies (most notably the PRC,
14
Malaysia, Singapore and
North America) more than half of the benefits that could have been
obtained from liberalization accrue from the liberalization of intermediate
goods.
Columns VI–VIII illustrate the impact on the region of its own liberali-
zation of intermediate tariffs. They reveal that most of these gains from
liberalization of intermediates are due to each country’s own liberalization
(compare Columns I- III with VI- VIII in Table 2.11). In order to focus
in on some of the differences, it is advantageous to consider just one or
two countries. For this reason in the remainder of this section we focus
on Viet Nam and India to see the impact on each economy of its own
liberalizations and consider their sectoral effects.
Sectoral results
As expected, when the tariffs on intermediate goods fall, variable costs
fall, prices drop, and firms substitute toward imported intermediate inputs
(Tables 2.12 and 2.13) and away from domestic inputs. In the GTAP- SC
model where there is a separation of tariffs on imported intermediates and
final goods, final consumers will then substitute toward domestic goods as
the price of these domestically produced goods falls (Tables 2.12 and 2.13),
while the tariffs on their imports of final goods have not changed. This
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 53
effect is somewhat muted by the fact that households will also have more
income as a result of higher returns to factors, and hence their demand for
imports may also rise: this is the case in Viet Nam (Table 2.12), but it is less
apparent in the case of India (Table 2.13).
Production in some sectors rises, while in others it falls as resources
are shifted toward those that benefit most from the liberalization. The
sectors that gain are those with high shares of imported intermediates,
high initial tariffs and price- responsive demand for their products (as
exports or consumer goods), since there is less demand for domestic
intermediates (Tables 2.12 and 2.13). For instance, a comparison of
the other food production and the wearing apparel sectors in Viet Nam
reveals that while both rely on intermediate imports, there are more
opportunities for the wearing apparel industry to switch to cheaper
inputs of textiles and wearing apparel following the liberalization. The
food industry, on the other hand, can purchase cheaper imported food,
but other important primary inputs, such as livestock and raw milk, do
not have high initial tariffs and do not benefit to the same degree as the
apparel industry. Moreover, domestically produced food for intermedi-
ate use is an important element of the demand for food production in
Viet Nam, and the switch to imports causes demand for food produc-
tion to fall significantly. Textiles and wearing apparel on the other
hand are generally produced for export, demand for which rises. As a
result resources move toward textiles and away from food production.
In general production becomes more import intensive and the share of
value added in output also rises as the returns to factors rise (Tables 2.12
and 2.13).
15
Differences in sourcing
While the differences in the macro results for the three different datasets
are quite small, there are sectoral differences owing to the differential
sourcing of the imports underlying the three different datasets. Tables 2.14
and 2.15 show two examples of how differences in shares lead to differ-
ences in the tariff shocks applied and hence differences in the results. Table
2.14 gives the example of the food industry in India. The average tariffs
on cereals and food imported into India are 99 percent and 89 percent
respectively in the BEC database (Table 2.13), and since cereals and food
are important intermediate inputs into the food industry this translates to
some large source specific shocks to the food industry in Table 2.14.
16
As
expected the tariff shock drives the price of food down and final demand
rises. Despite the fall in domestic prices output does not rise as intermedi-
ate demand for domestic food has fallen considerably. For those sources
where Indian tariffs on intermediate inputs into the food industry fall,
54
Table 2.12 Percent changes in Viet Nam’s output, value- added to output shares, intermediate and final demand
resulting from the liberalization of tariffs on intermediate inputs by Viet Nam (BEC)
Sector/Commodity Output by sector Share of value added/
Output by sector
Intermediate input
demand by sector
Private household
demand for commodity
Initial
average
tariff rate on
intermediate
commodity
Initial value
(US$ mn)
Initial After
simulation
Domestic Imports Domestic Imports
All % % % % % % % %
Cereals 4 027 −4.16 66 66 −4.3 5.4 −0.5 4.7 3.9
Other crops 5 520 −4.48 72 73 −4.7 29.1 0.3 3.3 10.1
Livestock and raw
milk
2 558 1.31 48 49 −1.0 −2.9 2.0 4.9 0.9
Forestry and fishing 4 939 −6.77 60 61 −11.0 −6.7 1.8 6.1 1.8
Resources 9 664 −6.02 60 60 −9.6 9.6 2.4 5.8 2.4
Meat and dairy 849 −10.55 21 25 −38.3 17.8 1.6 3.0 18.2
Processed rice 4 616 −3.05 10 12 −4.9 3.4 1.1 9.8 0.0
Other food 10 383 −6.95 23 26 −15.4 17.5 −0.4 5.2 15.5
Textiles 5 097 35.08 29 34 −7.1 86.6 23.3 −6.3 28.9
Wearing apparel 14 259 78.85 27 31 47.9 110.8 19.5 −15.6 16.4
Lumber and paper 5 215 −17.28 21 25 −20.7 12.8 −2.4 9.2 7.8
Resource products 5 603 −17.68 28 32 −19.4 14.3 −6.0 5.5 12.7
55
Chemicals, rubbers
and plastics
7 058 −8.70 20 24 −7.4 13.4 −1.9 7.1 4.5
Metals 1 373 −18.46 3 4 −1.1 0.7 −12.6 8.6 2.5
Metal products 928 −1.28 19 22 10.7 8.4 1.4 3.1 10.9
Motor vehicles 3 904 2.14 25 29 1.9 11.9 5.9 1.9 17.6
Electronic
goods and other
equipment
7 050 −9.94 18 21 −10.8 5.8 −2.1 3.2 4.7
Other manufactures 2 503 −9.04 18 21 −13.1 78.7 2.3 3.5 21.7
Non- tradable
services
18 665 −4.90 72 76 −6.4 20.8 −0.5 25.4 0.8
Services 35 087 4.61 44 50 10.1 15.0 −0.2 10.1 0.0
Notes:
BEC = Broad Economic Classification; mn = million.
The initial average tariff rate on intermediate commodity is the average tariff across all sectors applied on this commodity; it is not the average
tariff on all intermediates purchased by this sector.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
56
Table 2.13 Percent changes in India’s output, value- added to output shares, intermediate and final demand resulting
from the liberalization of tariffs on intermediate inputs by India (BEC)
Sector/Commodity Output by sector Share of value added/
Output by sector
Intermediate input
demand by sector
Private household
demand for
commodity
Initial average
tariff rate on
intermediate
commodity
Initial value
(US$ mn)
Initial After
simulation
Domestic Imports Domestic Imports
All % % % % % % % %
Cereals 43 424 −9.56 48 47 −13.6 514.1 0.8 −12.5 99.6
Other crops 141 160 0.07 71 72 −1.1 85.6 0.6 −3.8 27.6
Livestock and raw
milk
71 741 0.21 66 67 −1.0 23.1 0.6 −4.8 12.2
Forestry and fishing 21 248 −0.74 83 83 −3.5 8.1 0.1 0.4 6.5
Resources 40 645 −4.74 64 63 −25.1 11.6 2.1 −20.8 10.6
Meat and dairy 24 271 0.74 16 16 −1.9 160.1 0.5 −5.3 28.5
Processed rice 33 452 0.79 28 29 −0.4 146.8 0.4 −5.8 33.6
Other food 86 674 −1.97 19 20 −32.4 80.5 1.1 −7.9 89.8
Textiles 57 080 1.50 26 26 −4.1 60.2 0.7 −4.3 15.8
Wearing apparel 22 743 4.68 28 29 −3.8 42.0 0.7 −4.4 12.3
Lumber and paper 23 738 −4.90 30 31 −7.2 32.8 0.7 −2.2 13.5
Resource products 141 450 3.47 13 14 −1.6 14.0 1.8 −11.9 13.9
57
Chemicals, rubbers
and plastics
108 532 −0.66 20 22 −7.2 22.9 2.1 −10.0 13.8
Metals 77 819 −6.11 25 26 −11.3 27.1 4.0 −4.7 16.1
Metal products 45 385 0.97 28 29 −1.0 32.2 1.5 −9.7 14.9
Motor vehicles 51 110 2.17 24 25 0.7 5.2 1.2 −6.2 10.0
Electronic goods and
other equipment
122 836 3.71 20 21 1.2 5.6 5.1 −7.6 10.3
Other manufactures 51 287 2.93 35 36 −0.7 23.4 0.9 −4.9 14.9
Non- tradable services 290 364 −0.83 75 76 −1.3 2.0 0.0 1.6 0.0
Services 876 717 0.89 58 59 1.4 1.4 0.1 0.4 0.0
Notes:
BEC = Broad Economic Classification; mn = million.
Initial average tariff rate on intermediate commodity is the average tariff across all sectors applied on this commodity; it is not the average tariff on
all intermediates purchased by this sector.
Source: Authors’ calculations and GTAP database.
58 Asia and global production networks
Table 2.14 India’s intermediate imports used in the food industry and
production and price response to tariff liberalization of
intermediates
Value of intermediate
imports by source (in
millions of dollars)
%
BEC GTAP-
BEC
GTAP
Prop
BEC GTAP-
BEC
GTAP
Prop
Tariff shock
Price (% change) 4.84 −3.59 −3.51
Output (% change) 1.97 −0.95 −0.81
Tariff rate
Japan 120 103 94 13 12 12
Korea, Republic of 95 83 74 14 14 13
PRC 293 282 315 14 14 14
Taipei,China 30 30 44 12 13 13
Other East Asia 5 4 4 7 6 7
Singapore 163 154 155 9 8 8
Philippines 4 4 4 9 8 9
Thailand 65 37 49 44 20 27
Indonesia 2 546 1 048 778 97 93 92
Malaysia 98 58 127 31 16 50
Viet Nam 5 5 5 25 29 27
Other Southeast Asia 15 29 67 8 22 27
India 0 0 0 0 0 0
Bangladesh 5 6 6 8 13 9
Pakistan 30 25 29 76 54 64
Other South Asia 81 80 74 25 24 13
Central Asia 6 3 13 54 10 75
Pacific Islands 3 1 2 8 11 10
Australia and
New Zealand
49 63 62 13 18 18
European Union 747 714 693 11 11 12
North America 484 496 578 20 21 22
Other DCs 1 446 1 143 1 195 42 40 41
Total/Average 6 289 4 368 4 368 46 34 33
Note: BEC = Broad Economic Classification; DCs = developing countries; GTAP =
Global Trade Analysis Project; PRC = People’s Republic of China; Prop = proportionality.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 59
Table 2.15 Viet Nam’s intermediate imports used in motor vehicle and
transportation production and production and price response
to tariff liberalization of intermediates
Value of intermediate imports
by source (in millions of US
dollars)
%
BEC GTAP-
BEC
GTAP
Prop
BEC GTAP-
BEC
GTAP
Prop
Tariff shock
Price (% change) −1.19 −0.77 −2.13
Output (% change) 2.14 −0.74 0.44
Tariff rate
Japan 205 182 231 10 9 14
Korea, Republic of 126 114 215 7 6 13
PRC 695 634 548 13 12 13
Taipei,China 28 25 132 12 12 8
Other East Asia 0 0 0 4 2 7
Singapore 30 27 32 7 7 11
Philippines 37 35 24 4 4 3
Thailand 195 193 124 5 5 5
Indonesia 87 86 48 9 9 7
Malaysia 100 99 82 2 2 2
Viet Nam 0 0 0 0 0 0
Other Southeast
Asia
15 13 13 0 0 2
India 18 16 16 2 2 3
Bangladesh 0 0 0 13 13 13
Pakistan 0 0 0 10 11 11
Other South Asia 0 0 0 6 6 5
Central Asia 2 2 2 4 4 3
Pacific Islands 0 0 0 1 1 8
Australia and
New Zealand
74 71 60 2 2 2
European Union 518 494 439 7 7 9
North America 42 39 116 4 3 28
Other DCs 195 193 143 15 15 12
Total 2 367 2 225 2 225 9 9 11
Notes: BEC = Broad Economic Classification; DCs = developing countries; GTAP =
Global Trade Analysis Project; PRC = People’s Republic of China; Prop = proportionality.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
60 Asia and global production networks
demand increases (Japan, Indonesia and Thailand), while those where
tariffs are small experience declines.
What is surprising, however, is the extent to which differences in tariffs
among the three different databases in turn alter the results. In the first
case (BEC), inputs used in food production are more intensively obtained
from Indonesia, where tariffs are initially substantially higher than else-
where. This higher share of Indonesian food in India’s food production in
the BEC database raises the average tariff faced by the food industry on
its imported intermediates to 46 percent (as opposed to about 34 percent in
the GTAP proportional and GTAP- BEC databases, see total row, Table
2.14). The reason for the lower tariff in the GTAP- BEC database is that,
while the sourcing data from BEC indicates that the share of imported
food for intermediate use from Indonesia should be higher than that speci-
fied in GTAP prop (40 percent as opposed to 18 percent), this raises the
share of imported intermediates in total imported and domestic use. In
order to adjust for this the GTAP- BEC database must lower the values
to match the original GTAP total intermediate imports (see totals row in
Table 2.14). In doing so the value of imports purchased from Indonesia
must fall in order to maintain balance and the share also falls back toward
the original GTAP share. However, the rebalancing causes the total
intermediate imports to fall, which has the effect of reducing the shares of
imports from Indonesia, thereby reducing the impact of the tariff shock on
the price of food in India.
In the second example, we examine the impact of tariff shocks on the
motor vehicle and transportation sector in Viet Nam. Unlike the previ-
ous example, in this case the BEC shares suggest that Viet Nam’s motor
vehicle and transportation industry purchase more of its intermediate
inputs (metal and motor vehicle parts) from Southeast Asia, where tariffs
are already low due to ASEAN trade preferences. As a result, the removal
of these smaller tariffs on intermediate inputs has a much smaller effect
(in absolute terms) on the price of motor vehicles than would have been
the case if the proportionality assumption had been used (–1.19 percent as
opposed to –2.13 percent).
Turning to GTAP- BEC, the increased use of imports from Southeast
Asia raises intermediate imports relative to final imports under BEC, which
means that the total value of intermediate imports must fall again to the
GTAP level under GTAP- BEC. As a result of the rebalancing, the value
of intermediate imports falls, but the share of Southeast Asian imports
remains high.
17
The result is that tariffs are still lower than in GTAP (see
totals row in Table 2.15) and intermediate imports are also lower. The
result is that the impact of the tariff shock on the price of motor vehicles is
even less pronounced (–0.77 percent as opposed to –1.19 percent).
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 61
Given these changes in prices resulting from the three alternative data-
sets, the large positive change in production of motor vehicles under the
BEC database, as compared to the negative change in the GTAP- BEC, is
somewhat unexpected. The reason for the increase in production under
BEC is an increase in demand for domestic motor vehicles for invest-
ment purposes. Under BEC, motor vehicles are mainly imported for
intermediate use, rather than final use (or investment). Hence the share
of imported (domestic) motor vehicles in investment is lower (higher) in
the BEC database. Moreover, trade liberalization generally results in an
expansion in investment, due to the higher rates of return on capital in
Viet Nam following trade reforms. Thus the slightly larger domestic share
of motor vehicles in investment in the BEC database means that the rise
in investment will result in an additional source of demand for domestic
motor vehicles that, in turn, causes production to rise in the BEC case, as
opposed to falling in the other case.
5. CONCLUSIONS
With firms increasingly reliant on international trade to source their
intermediate inputs into production, the need to be able to undertake
supply- chain analyses has risen. This is particularly true in Asia, where the
inter- connectedness of trade and production has made the region a pow-
erful engine for growth. Our aim in this chapter has been to develop and
examine some of the tools that can be used to understand the evolution of
supply chains in response to policy and other shocks.
In order to do this, however, we first needed to construct a global MRIO
database suitable for supply chain analysis. We found that this could be
done using the GTAP database as our foundation. The benefits of starting
from the GTAP database are clear: the GTAP database offers a publicly
available and continuously updated source of globally reconciled trade
data covering 134 countries/regions and 57 sectors. As in other MRIO
datasets, the GTAP database can be augmented with shares obtained from
the trade data and application of the BEC concordance.
Like others (Koopman et al. 2010), we find that there are significant
differences in the sourcing of intermediate versus final goods, obtained
through the use of BEC concordances, and that these differences are
important for the analysis of supply chains. We find, however, that
there is still a great deal of work to be done on improving the quality of
these data and reconciling it with the underlying trade and IO tables in
GTAP. Most of the work done to date in this area has invoked extreme
assumptions aimed at simplifying the task of creating a MRIO. Future
62 Asia and global production networks
efforts must factor in more information on the provenance of source data
and how this should influence the relative priority given to conflicting
information.
With our database in hand, the task of developing tools for analysis of
supply chains was then considered. Using the GTAP model as our starting
point, we implemented the additional detail on supply chains (GTAP-SC)
and then used ‘closure’ swaps and parameter changes to turn the GTAP-SC
model into a fixed price multiplier model. From this we were able to see
very clearly the linkages between economies and how growth in aggregate
demand in one region could affect other regions through trade. We found
that the Asian region in particular, through its interconnectedness with
the rest of the world, was a powerful driver behind the spread of growth.
However, we also found that the addition of the sourcing information did
not significantly affect this result. Moreover, the assumption that prices
are fixed had a significant effect on the results and limited our ability to
analyze trade policy.
For this reason we then chose to use the GTAP- SC in its original CGE
form to show how CGE models can be used to analyze some of the key
issues in supply chain analysis. We then used this model to examine the
impact of removing all tariffs on imported intermediate goods, as the PRC
and others have done for export- oriented firms in the special economic
zones. We find that the additional detail on the sourcing of imports by
agent can have considerable effects on the impact of trade liberalization,
particularly in countries that are highly integrated in global supply chains,
such as Viet Nam, Malaysia and Thailand. We also find that a large pro-
portion of the gains from full trade liberalization can be achieved from the
removal of these tariffs on intermediate goods. There is a general increase
in intermediate imports as firms switch to foreign sources for their inter-
mediate inputs and away from domestic sources, resulting in growth in the
PRC and abroad. The source of these new imports depends on the current
sourcing of intermediate inputs and the tariffs imposed. We find that the
tariffs can differ significantly as a result of the additional information on
the supply chains.
The scope for future analysis in this area is considerable. Currently, the
differences in tariffs between intermediate and final goods reported here
are due only to differences in weights applied in aggregating up from the
GTAP level. There are other sources of differences that are not captured
here. First, these differential weights should be applied when aggregating
tariffs from the HS6 level up to the GTAP level. This is likely to have a
considerable impact on the tariffs applied on intermediate versus final
goods and hence for the results of this analysis. Moreover, countries may
have differential policies with regards to the treatment of intermediate and
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 63
final imports, such as the duty drawbacks schemes in the PRC and other
countries. By factoring in these differences into a global MRIO database
and supply chain model, future analysis can better capture the impacts of
exogenous shocks as well as policy reforms on the global supply chain.
NOTES
* This chapter has been commissioned as part of the Asian Development Bank study on
Supply Chains in Asia, led by David Hummels and Benno Ferrarini. The authors would
like to thank Angel Aguiar for discussions comparing the various new MRIO datasets.
1. Supply and use tables may also be used where input–output tables are not available.
2. GTAP notation is being used where possible.
VIFMS
is Value of Imported Intermediate/
Firm goods at Market prices from Source s. In general, note
V
is value,
I
is imports,
D
domestic output,
M
market prices,
F
firms,
P
private consumption, and
G
government
consumption. Where a letter is missing it means that the variable is aggregated over that
set or type: for example, if
D
or
I
is missing then the variable is aggregated over domes-
tic output or imports; and if
S
is missing then the value is aggregated over all sources.
Instead of using the GTAP notation for invEstment (
VIFM
i.cgds,r
),
E
is used
(
VIEM
i.r
)
to
emphasize its place in final demand. Below
N
and
L
are also used to represent aggregate
iNtermediate demand (i.e., the sum of 1 to j in intermediate demand F) and aggregate
finaL demand (the sum of P – private consumption, G – government consumption and
E – Investment).
3. N and L are also used to represent aggregate iNtermediate demand (i.e., the sum of all
1. . . j
in intermediate demand
F
) and aggregate finaL demand (the sum of P private
consumption, G government consumption and E Investment). In Table 2.1 these are
shown by the double bordering around final and intermediate imports.
4. Appendix 2A.1 provides a summary of a number of initiatives in the area of Global
MRIO datasets. A full summary of the approaches can be found in Murray and Lenzen
(2013).
5. The GTAP 8 database was released with two base years, 2004 and 2007. It is expected
that GTAP will update all previous years and add (at least) one additional base year
with each new release in future. The decision to expand to multiple base years reflects
the fact that the GTAP data construction techniques and the data inputs have continu-
ously improved and expanded with each version, making comparison of GTAP data-
bases across versions difficult.
6. Table 2.3 is similar to Table 2.1, except that Table 2.3 simplifies the problem in terms of
aggregated intermediates and final demand.
7. Primary countries in GTAP are those countries that have an IO table and are therefore
separately identified in the GTAP database. Other countries may also be missing from
the BEC, however they are contained in regional aggregates in the GTAP database and
therefore their non- inclusion in BEC is less significant, since the sourcing shares can be
obtained from other countries in that aggregated region.
8. The decision of which data to prioritize depends on your beliefs about which data are
most reliable. In the case of GTAP there are many more countries included than in
other databases, and not all IO tables are of equal quality. Moreover, the ultimate aim
of this database is for use with a CGE trade model that requires that the IO table be
globally balanced. Country IOTs are not globally balanced and any attempt to keep
all the trade information in country IOTs results in negative trade with the rest of the
world (as in WIOD). Given the ultimate use of the GTAP database, negative trade is
not an option and hence the data are benchmarked against the trade data.
9. Note that the shaded items will also be maintained since the initial GTAP database is
already balanced.
64 Asia and global production networks
10. Where ‘prop’ stands for proportionality.
11. Note that there is no difference between the GTAP shares and the GTAP- BEC shares
(option 2) since these shares are benchmarked in option 2.
12. Note that investment is a sector and therefore part
QIFS
i,j,s,r
13. This is equivalent to using the ‘altertax’ closure in RunGTAP (Malcolm, 1998).
14. Note that we have not taken into account any pre- existing duty drawbacks. It was
assumed that at the GTAP sectoral level all tariffs on intermediate and final goods were
the same. Once the data are aggregated, however, these tariff rates on intermediate and
final goods will differ due to differences in the import shares of intermediate and final
demand goods.
15. Although this is very small, since the GTAP- SC assumes a Leontief structure at the top
level.
16. Note that we assumed that tariffs in the GTAP database applied equally to
intermediate and final goods. Hence all differences in tariffs across the three datasets
are the result of aggregating tariffs using different weights from GTAP to the aggrega-
tion provided in Table 2.4. Further differences in tariffs are likely to be considerable if
these alternate weights are applied to aggregate tariffs from the HS6 level to GTAP.
17. This is in stark contrast to the Indian food case where the share of Indonesian imports
falls in order to restore balance in intermediate imports.
REFERENCES
Andrew, R., and G. Peters (2013), ‘A multi- regional input–output table based
on the Global Trade Analysis Project Database (GTAP- MRIO)’, Economic
Systems Research, 25, 99–121.
Asian Development Bank (2010), Institutions for Regional Integration – Toward an
Asian Economic Community, Manila: Asian Development Bank.
Gehlhar, M., Z. Wang, and S. Yao (2008), ‘GTAP 7 Data Base documentation –
Chapter 9.A: Reconciling merchandise trade data’, in B. Narayanan and T.L.
Walmsley (eds), Global Trade, Assistance, and Production: The GTAP 7 Data
Base, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University.
GRAM (2012), Ein globales Modell zur Berechnung der Ökologischen Rucksäcke
des internationalen Handels, Sustainable Europe Research Institute (SERI),
Wien, Austria.
Hendrickson, C., A. Horvath, S. Joshi, and L. Lave (1998), ‘Economic input–
output models for environmental life- cycle assessment’, Environmental Science
and Technology Policy Analysis, 32, 184A–191.
Ianchovichina, E. (2003), ‘GTAP- DD: A model for analyzing trade reforms in the
presence of duty drawbacks’, GTAP Technical Papers 21, Center for Global
Trade Analysis, West Lafayette, IN, USA.
Inomata, S., and B. Meng (2013), ‘Transnational interregional input–output
tables: an alternative approach to MRIO?’, Chapter 4 in J. Murray and
M. Lenzen (eds), The Practitioners Guide to Multi- Regional Input–Output
Analysis, Champaign, IL: Common Ground.
Johnson, R.C., and G. Noguera (2012), ‘Accounting for intermediates: produc-
tion sharing and trade in value added’, Journal of International Economics, 86,
224–236.
Konar, M., Z. Hussein, N. Hanasaki, D.L. Mauzerall, and I. Rodriguez- Iturbe
(2013), ‘Virtual water trade flows and savings under climate change’, Hydrology
and Earth System Sciences, 10, 67–101, doi:10.5194/hessd- 10- 67- 2013.
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 65
Koopman, R., W. Powers, Z. Wang, and S. Wei (2010), ‘Give credit where credit
is due: tracing the value- added in global production chains’, NBER Working
Paper No. 16426, available at http://www.nber.org/papers/w16426.
Koopman, R., Z. Wang, and S. Wei (forthcoming), ‘Tracing value- added and
double counting in gross exports’, The American Economic Review.
Lenzen, M., K. Kanemoto, D. Moran, and A. Geschke (2012), ‘Mapping the
structure of the world economy’, Environmental Science & Technology, 46,
8374–8381.
Lenzen, M., D. Moran, K. Kanemoto, and A. Geschke (2013), ‘Building Eora: a
global multi- region input–output database at high country and sectoral resolu-
tion’, Economic Systems Research, 25, 20–49.
Malcolm, G. (1998), ‘Adjusting tax rates in the GTAP data base’, GTAP Technical
Paper No. 12, Center for Global Trade Analysis, West Lafayette, IN, USA.
McDougall, R. (1999), ‘Entropy theory and RAS are friends’, GTAP Working
paper No. 6, Center for Global Trade Analysis, West Lafayette, IN, USA.
Meng, B., Y. Zhang, and S. Inomata (2013), ‘Compilation and application of
IDE- JETRO’s international input–output tables’, Economic Systems Research,
25, 122–142.
Murray, J., and M. Lenzen (2013), The Practitioners Guide to Multi- regional Input–
Output Analysis, Champaign, IL: Common Ground.
Narayanan, G.B., A. Aguiar, and R. McDougall (2012), Global Trade, Assistance,
and Production: The GTAP 8 Data Base, Center for Global Trade Analysis,
Purdue University.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co- operation and Development) (2009),
OECD Input–Output Tables: 2002, 2006 and 2009 Editions, Paris, France:
OECD.
OECD (2012), Measuring Trade in Value- Added; An OECD- WTO Joint Initiative,
Paris, France: OECD.
Peters, G., R. Andrew, and J. Lennox (2011), ‘Constructing an environmentally
extended multi- regional input–output table using the GTAP Data Base’,
Economic Systems Research, 23, 131–152.
Reimer, J. (2010), ‘The domestic content of imports and the foreign content of
exports’, International Review of Economics and Finance, 20, 173–184.
Rutherford, T., J. Carbone, and C. Böhringer (2011), ‘Using embodied carbon
to control carbon leakage’, paper presented at the 14th Annual Conference on
Global Economic Analysis, Venice, Italy.
Timmer, M.P. (2012), ‘The World Input–Output Database (WIOD): contents,
sources and methods’, WIOD Working Paper No. 10.
Tukker, A., E. Poliakov, R. Heijungs, T. Hawkins, F. Neuwahl, J. Rueda- Cantuche,
S. Giljum, S. Moll, J. Oosterhaven, and M. Bouwmeester (2009), ‘Towards
a global multi- regional environmentally extended input–output database’,
Ecological Economics, 68, 1929–1937.
Walmsley, T.L., and C. Carrico (2013), ‘Disaggregating labor payments by skill
level in GTAP’, Unpublished manuscript, Center for Global Trade Analysis.
Weingarden, A., and M. Tsigas (2010), ‘Labor statistics for the GTAP Database’,
paper presented at 13th Annual Conference on Global Economic Analysis,
Malaysia, Penang.
66 Asia and global production networks
APPENDIX 2A.1 OVERVIEW OF DATASETS
1
IDE- JETRO Asian Input–Output Tables
The Institute of Developing Economies Japan External Trade
Organization (IDE- JETRO) is the longest standing producer of inter-
national input–output tables, with more than 30 years of experience in
producing input–output tables for the Asia- Pacific region (Inomata and
Meng, 2013). Recently the IDE- JETRO released its latest version of the
Asian International Input–Output tables covering 10 countries, 76 sectors
and value- added (compensation of employees, operating surplus, capital
depreciation, and net indirect taxes less subsidies). The base year for these
tables is 2005. The MRIO information is obtained from each country’s
trade statistics (concordances are used if required) and this is supple-
mented by imported input surveys. The rebalancing involves manually
identifying differences/errors in data sources, analyzing causes and then
making adjustments to remove the cause and the error (Meng et al., 2013).
The OECD Input–Output Tables and TiVA Database
The OECD tables (OECD, 2009) include 37 independent, harmonized,
industry by industry country IO tables covering 48 sectors, two of which
are in food and agriculture, and two endowments (capital and labor). In
2006 the OECD released version 3 with a base year of 2000, and they are
working on version 4. The OECD obtains input–output or supply and use
tables from the various national statistical offices and then process the
data to harmonize the structure and sectoral coverage in- house; no recon-
ciliation with other external data sources or to ensure any cross- country
balance constraints is undertaken.
These OECD tables have been used to produce trade in value added
measures (TiVA: OECD, 2012) in a joint initiative by the OECD and
WTO. The TiVA database includes indicators for 57 economies (includ-
ing all OECD countries, Brazil, the PRC, India, Indonesia, Russian
Federation and South Africa) and 18 industries. It also covers the years
1995, 2000, 2005, 2008 and 2009. The TiVA database reconciles bilateral
trade and uses BEC concordances and the proportionality assumption to
allocate trade when other data are not available. The IO table for the PRC
has also been revised to include export processing zones, as was done in
the GTAP- ICIO database below. Available indicators include: decompo-
sition of gross exports by industry into their domestic and foreign content;
the services content of gross exports by exporting industry (broken down
by foreign and domestic origin); bilateral trade balances based on flows
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 67
of value added embodied in domestic final demand; and intermediate
imports embodied in exports.
The GTAP Database
The GTAP database (Narayanan et al., 2012) is the most longstanding
of all the global datasets, with version 8.1 released in 2013. The current
version has two base years (2004 and 2007) and covers 134 regions (includ-
ing approximately 20 rest of world
2
aggregates). The underlying country
data are based on contributed
3
input–output or supply and use tables.
The GTAP database covers 57 industries/commodities, including 8 food
and 12 agricultural products, and 5 endowments (land, capital, skilled
and unskilled labor
4
and natural resources). Satellite datasets also include
CO
2
emissions, energy volumes, international migration and 18 agro-
ecological zones. Unlike the other global datasets, the GTAP database
was established by economists and policy makers interested in trade policy
analysis and hence special attention has been paid to the trade data and
to reconciling the country data to the trade and macro (GDP, private and
government consumption and investment). Trade is taken from the UN
COMTRADE database and reconciled depending on the reliability of the
reporter (importer versus exporter). Trade is therefore globally reconciled,
although trade balances do not match national statistical office data.
Estimates are also produced for international transportation margins and
protection on imports and exports; as well as for energy commodities.
A number of research papers (Peters et al., 2011; Andrew and Peters,
2013; Johnson and Noguera, 2012; Rutherford et al., 2011; Reimer,
2010; Ianchovichina, 2003) have taken the GTAP Database and used the
proportionality assumption to further split imports by agent by source,
thereby producing a basic MRIO.
GTAP- ICIO Database
Koopman et al. (2010) utilized additional information from the trade
data to construct a GTAP MRIO that more accurately depicts the dif-
ferences between agents’ sourcing of imports. They constructed a global
ICIO table from the GTAP 8 database using detailed trade data from UN
COMTRADE and processing export information from two additional IO
tables Mexico and the PRC. Emphasis is placed on minimizing deviation
from the original GTAP data, and in particular in the sectoral bilateral
trade data. They also utilized the reliability indexes used to reconcile
the standard GTAP trade data to assist them in obtaining the sourcing
shares by agent, and hence produce more reliable estimates. The resulting
68 Asia and global production networks
database covers 63 countries/regions and 41 sectors for the two base years,
2004 and 2007.
WIOD
The World Input–Output Database (Timmer, 2012), released in 2012, was
funded under the European Commission 7th framework program. It is a
time series database (1995–2009) covering 41 countries (including Rest of
World), 35 industries and 59 commodities, two of which are in food and
agriculture, and four endowments (capital and three labor). The underly-
ing country data are based on publicly available input–output (IOT) or
supply and use (SUT) tables, usually from national statistical offices.
5
Two versions are produced, an industry by industry variant and a com-
modity by industry version. Special attention was paid to keeping with
UN SNA concepts, such as price definitions, the treatment of domestic
margins and changes in stocks; and to limiting the number of changes
made to the underlying country data from the national statistical offices.
Sectoral output and macro aggregates (private and public consumption
and investment) were reconciled over time to the national account statis-
tics. Trade was taken from the country IO or SUT data and hence trade
balances match the underlying country statistics. International trade data
were then used to obtain bilateral imports by use and adjustments were
made for international margins. Since trade is not globally reconciled
and differences were included as a residual in exports to rest of the world,
exports to the rest of the world could be negative. Detailed bilateral trade
data are also used to obtain estimates of imports by intermediate and final
demanders and hence it is a MRIO. The method used by WIOD is similar
to that undertaken in this chapter for the GTAP- MRIO database.
EXIOBASE
The EXIOBASE Database, first released in 2010, was funded under the
European Commission 6th framework program (Tukker et al., 2009).
The base year is 2000 and covers 44 countries (including Rest of World),
129 industries/commodities, with extensive coverage of food and agricul-
ture, and numerous endowments (capital, 3 types of labor, land, and 80
resources and water). The EXIOBASE database also includes around 30
emissions and 60 IEA energy carriers. The underlying country data are
based on input–output (IOT) or supply and use (SUT) tables, usually
from national statistical offices. Trade was taken from the country IOT
or SUT, and hence trade balances match underlying country statistics.
International trade data were then used to obtain bilateral imports by use,
Developing a GTAP- based multi- region, input–output framework 69
and adjustments were made for international margins. Unlike WIOD,
RAS
6
was used to reconcile the trade and ensure no negative residuals.
The proportionality assumption was used to produce a MRIO, as done by
Peters et al., 2011 and others with the GTAP database (discussed above).
The Eora MRIO
The Eora MRIO database (Lenzen et al., 2013) is a time series database
covering the period 1990–2011 and 187 countries. Each country has a
unique set of sectors (between 25 and 400) depending on the underlying
data from the original source. The database also includes around 35 envi-
ronmental indicators and estimates of the level of uncertainty or standard
deviations associated with each element of the global matrix. Behind the
Eora database is an optimization program that ensures that conflicting
data are reconciled and the global IO table is balanced.
70
Source: Authors’ calculations using GTAP-BEC database.
Figure 2A.1 Using final demand for Asia’s exports: GTAP-BEC database
Asia’s exports
100.0%
Inside Asia
43.8%
Final demand
11.1%
Final demand
exported to Asia
30.0%
Intermediate
32.7%
Outside Asia
56.2%
Intermediate
27.4%
Final demand
28.8%
Final demand
exported to rest
of the world
70.0%
United States
27.3%
European Union
23.4%
Rest of the world
19.3%
14.3 18.4
4.6
22.8
APPENDIX 2A.2 SUMMARY OF FINAL DEMAND FOR ASIA’S EXPORTS
7
71
Source: Based on Asian Development Bank (2010), p. 33.
Figure 2A.2 Using final demand for Asia’s exports: GTAP proportionality database
Asia’s exports
100.0%
Inside Asia
43.8%
Final demand
10.7%
Final demand
exported to Asia
29.4%
Intermediate
33.1%
Outside Asia
56.2%
Intermediate
24.8%
Final demand
31.4%
Final demand
exported to rest
of the world
70.7%
United States
27.8%
European Union
23.0%
Rest of the world
19.9%
14.5
18.6
4.2
20.7
72
Table 2A.1 Top 25 differences in the share of imported intermediates to total imports in 20 commodities by 22 region
aggregation
Values Shares %
1 Prop 2 GTAP- BEC 3 BEC 1 Prop 2 GTAP- BEC 3 BEC
1 Processed rice Malaysia 209.7 209.7 1.3 62 62 0
2 Processed rice Japan 1 301.5 1 301.5 24.0 67 67 1
3 Processed rice Australia and New Zealand 112.2 112.2 28.3 98 98 25
4 Processed rice Other East Asia 29.1 29.1 0.7 24 24 1
5 Livestock and raw milk Pakistan 6.8 6.8 38.0 10 10 57
6 Processed rice Korea, Republic of 23.2 23.2 5.2 65 65 14
7 Processed rice Philippines 122.4 122.4 0.4 12 12 0
8 Livestock and raw milk India 105.9 105.9 328.5 29 29 89
9 Processed rice PRC 323.5 323.5 68.5 54 54 12
10 Livestock and raw milk Viet Nam 38.2 38.2 131.0 21 21 70
11 Forestry and fishing India 482.7 482.7 1 240.2 38 38 98
12 Other food India 2 350.4 2 350.4 6 364.1 27 27 73
13 Forestry and fishing Bangladesh 30.3 30.3 64.5 47 47 99
14 Processed rice Thailand 2.4 2.4 0.8 47 47 16
15 Cereals PRC 185.1 185.1 348.5 50 50 95
16 Livestock and raw milk Malaysia 34.6 34.6 69.6 36 36 72
73
17 Cereals Central Asia 415.5 415.5 723.3 51 51 89
18 Livestock and raw milk Bangladesh 12.8 12.8 23.4 41 41 74
19 Processed rice North America 309.8 309.8 139.3 46 46 20
20 Other crops India 1 555.4 1 555.4 689.5 41 41 18
21 Processed rice Indonesia 35.7 35.7 1.0 5 5 0
22 Processed rice European Union 683.5 683.5 321.7 42 42 20
23 Processed rice Bangladesh 10.0 10.0 0.1 3 3 0
24 Processed rice Viet Nam 0.7 0.7 0.3 20 20 8
25 Wearing apparel Philippines 266.6 266.6 161.7 56 56 34
Notes: BEC = Broad Economic Classification; GTAP = Global Trade Analysis Project; Prop = proportionality.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
74
Table 2A.2 Top differences in sourcing share in 20 commodities by 22 region aggregation
Commodity Source Destination Values Shares %
1 Prop 2 GTAP- BEC 3 BEC 1 Prop 2 GTAP- BEC 3 BEC
Processed rice Viet Nam Indonesia 27 14 0 74.30 39.44 0.00
Processed rice India Bangladesh 10 5 0 97.97 47.69 0.10
Processed rice Viet Nam Philippines 93 61 0 76.19 50.05 0.01
Processed rice Thailand Viet Nam 0 0 0 45.55 5.47 0.00
Processed rice Thailand Malaysia 125 109 0 59.42 52.01 0.00
Processed rice North America Japan 675 517 0 51.85 39.75 0.02
Processed rice PRC Korea, Rep. of 11 7 0 47.94 31.83 0.03
Processed rice Other
Southeast Asia
Viet Nam 0 0 0 33.41 13.33 0.00
Processed rice Other DCs Indonesia 0 1 1 0.07 1.49 51.82
Processed rice Other DCs Philippines 0 0 0 0.02 0.14 41.06
Processed rice Viet Nam Malaysia 68 74 0 32.43 35.44 0.00
Processed rice Other DCs Bangladesh 0 0 0 0.01 0.23 33.77
Processed rice Pakistan Other South
Asia
7 8 0 24.91 28.07 0.00
Processed rice India Thailand 0 0 0 18.91 2.74 0.00
Processed rice Other DCs Malaysia 0 1 1 0.18 0.28 44.10
Processed rice Thailand Indonesia 9 12 0 24.23 33.56 0.00
Processed rice Pakistan Thailand 0 0 0 20.85 16.56 0.00
Processed rice Other DCs Japan 8 13 13 0.64 0.96 52.10
Processed rice Thailand India 0 0 0 17.27 0.00 0.00
Processed rice Thailand Japan 220 265 0 16.93 20.37 0.00
Processed rice Other DCs Other East Asia 0 0 0 0.22 0.92 39.11
75
Processed rice Thailand Philippines 28 51 0 22.62 41.31 0.01
Processed rice Thailand Other East Asia 21 9 0 72.93 30.46 7.31
Processed rice Taipei,China Bangladesh 0 0 0 0.00 0.11 16.31
Processed rice Indonesia Philippines 0 0 0 0.01 0.06 17.33
Wearing apparel Philippines Malaysia 30 0 0 8.49 0.00 0.00
Processed rice PRC Japan 217 262 0 16.64 20.11 0.01
Processed rice Thailand Pakistan 0 0 0 12.24 0.00 0.00
Processed rice North America Korea, Rep. of 5 5 0 20.82 20.41 0.07
Processed rice Indonesia Malaysia 0 0 0 0.08 0.12 18.87
Processed rice Thailand Pacific Islands 9 0 0 20.49 0.22 0.19
Processed rice Other
Southeast Asia
Indonesia 0 0 0 0.02 0.40 13.91
Processed rice Indonesia Bangladesh 0 0 0 0.00 0.07 10.49
Processed rice Taipei,China Japan 3 5 5 0.26 0.38 20.72
Processed rice Viet Nam Bangladesh 0 0 0 0.00 0.07 9.91
Processed rice Other
Southeast Asia
Philippines 0 0 0 0.00 0.04 11.07
Processed rice Philippines Indonesia 0 0 0 0.02 0.37 13.03
Processed rice Viet Nam Japan 89 119 0 6.84 9.12 0.00
Processed rice Australia and
New Zealand
Pacific Islands 8 0 0 17.76 0.26 0.23
Processed rice Other DCs Viet Nam 0 0 0 3.82 19.03 36.41
Non- tradable services Malaysia Thailand 6 18 92 6.27 19.42 43.74
Processed rice Thailand Korea, Rep. of 1 2 0 5.42 7.91 0.00
Wearing apparel PRC Bangladesh 12 1 2 37.81 3.68 5.19
Processed rice Other DCs Korea, Rep. of 1 2 2 6.01 9.28 40.08
Other crops Other
Southeast Asia
India 180 57 0 11.60 3.67 0.04
76
Table 2A.2 (continued)
Commodity Source Destination Values Shares %
1 Prop 2 GTAP- BEC 3 BEC 1 Prop 2 GTAP- BEC 3 BEC
Processed rice Australia and
New Zealand
Thailand 0 0 0 11.10 2.50 0.04
Processed rice Philippines Malaysia 0 0 0 0.05 0.07 11.39
Processed rice Pakistan Viet Nam 0 0 0 5.46 5.65 0.00
Other manufactures PRC Pakistan 5 1 1 36.32 4.16 5.09
Cereals Thailand Viet Nam 1 1 61 0.19 0.30 13.69
Other crops PRC Singapore 97 8 6 21.53 1.78 1.35
Processed rice Malaysia Bangladesh 0 0 0 0.00 0.04 6.41
Processed rice Philippines Bangladesh 0 0 0 0.00 0.04 6.34
Metals Taipei,China Viet Nam 555 0 1 8.97 0.00 0.02
Forestry and fishing Australia and
New Zealand
Australia and
New Zealand
29 13 4 32.65 14.70 5.07
Livestock and raw
milk
Taipei,China Viet Nam 4 0 0 9.96 0.00 0.06
Other food Pacific Islands Thailand 191 0 0 5.89 0.00 0.00
Processed rice Other DCs Thailand 0 0 0 10.68 18.62 44.79
Processed rice Korea, Rep. of Philippines 0 0 0 0.00 0.02 6.32
Other manufactures PRC North America 5 553 887 1 808 41.54 6.63 9.75
Wearing apparel PRC North America 4 256 1 557 973 52.83 19.32 15.84
Processed rice Taipei,China Indonesia 0 0 0 0.01 0.19 6.75
77
Processed rice European
Union
Indonesia 0 0 0 0.01 0.19 6.70
Processed rice Australia and
New Zealand
Japan 81 109 0 6.23 8.39 0.01
Resource products Taipei,China Viet Nam 1 351 42 121 18.97 0.59 1.67
Forestry and fishing Viet Nam Other Southeast
Asia
3 2 0 47.15 43.79 13.53
Processed rice Taipei,China Philippines 0 0 0 0.00 0.02 5.37
Metal products Taipei,China Viet Nam 72 2 2 11.16 0.24 0.25
Processed rice Indonesia Other East Asia 0 0 0 0.04 0.18 7.87
Other manufactures Other DCs North America 1 888 7 083 8 681 14.12 52.98 46.82
Note: BEC = Broad Economic Classification; DC= developing countries; GTAP = Global Trade Analysis Project; PRC = People’s Republic of
China; Prop = proportionality.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
78
Table 2A.3 Percent changes in private households’ budget shares of selected commodities resulting from non-
homothetic preferences due to a 10 percent increase in every region’s income
Cereals Other
crops
Livestock
and raw
milk
Forestry
and
fishing
Meat
and
dairy
Processed
rice
Wearing
apparel
Motor
vehicles
Electronic
goods
and other
equipment
Non-
tradable
services
Services
Japan −9.77 −9.57 −1.49 −0.84 −1.53 −9.75 −0.29 0.32 0.34 0.33 0.38
Korea, Rep. of −9.49 −9.65 −1.94 −1.79 −2.09 −9.49 −0.35 0.68 0.69 0.68 0.79
PRC −4.41 −4.58 −1.91 −2.33 −1.93 −4.55 −1.01 0.32 0.54 0.90 2.06
Taipei,China −9.30 −9.28 −2.40 −2.80 −2.47 −9.28 −0.58 0.53 0.62 0.61 0.75
Other East Asia −4.39 −4.30 −1.17 −1.25 −1.19 −4.26 −1.26 −0.43 −0.44 0.55 1.32
Singapore −9.47 −9.53 −2.02 −2.21 −2.09 −9.65 −0.60 0.19 0.20 0.18 0.32
Philippines −5.20 −5.11 −2.25 −2.49 −2.32 −5.20 −1.37 0.17 0.49 0.73 2.03
Thailand −6.17 −5.98 −3.01 −3.35 −3.10 −6.13 −1.53 0.36 0.56 0.58 1.64
Indonesia −4.90 −4.73 −1.93 −2.57 −2.09 −4.87 −1.04 0.40 0.91 1.21 2.20
Malaysia −7.40 −6.86 −3.34 −3.70 −3.43 −7.15 −1.39 0.65 0.71 0.64 1.09
Viet Nam −4.05 −3.30 −0.21 −0.71 −0.45 −4.06 −0.67 0.50 0.45 1.25 2.95
Other Southeast
Asia
−3.17 −3.94 0.54 −0.02 0.73 −3.76 −0.49 −0.29 −0.37 1.33 2.47
79
India −4.64 −4.59 −0.68 −0.45 −0.89 −4.53 −0.71 0.49 0.51 1.36 2.77
Bangladesh −3.89 −3.77 1.07 0.51 0.92 −3.86 −0.22 1.07 −0.03 1.79 2.94
Pakistan −3.89 −4.03 −0.84 −1.14 −0.94 −3.93 −0.51 0.82 0.88 1.43 2.12
Other South Asia −4.00 −4.36 1.06 −0.89 −0.51 −4.42 −0.41 0.71 0.35 1.79 2.54
Central Asia −6.13 −4.87 −1.83 −0.25 −2.26 −6.33 −0.26 1.95 1.44 1.79 2.35
Pacific Islands −6.23 −6.15 −3.39 −1.68 −3.45 −6.27 −1.82 −0.13 0.25 0.35 1.31
Australia and
New Zealand
−9.68 −9.68 −1.40 −1.37 −1.48 −9.78 −0.35 0.19 0.21 0.20 0.28
European Union −9.59 −9.58 −1.76 −1.02 −1.63 −9.71 −0.35 0.20 0.23 0.21 0.41
North America −9.10 −9.62 −1.66 −0.34 −1.31 −9.76 −0.30 0.10 0.13 0.12 0.22
Other DCs −5.49 −5.53 −2.30 −1.25 −2.81 −6.22 −0.76 0.81 0.96 1.00 1.61
Note: DC= developing countries; PRC = People’s Republic of China.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
80 Asia and global production networks
Notes
1. Another dataset not discussed here is GRAM (2012). The Global Resource Accounting
Model (GRAM) is a multi- regional input–output (MRIO) model, covering 53 countries
and 48 sectors and the years 1995 and 2005. It is based on an OECD IOT and trade data.
2. The reason for 20 ‘rest of’ regions is to facilitate the analysis of regional free trade agree-
ments, the main reason for the development of the GTAP database in the early 1990s.
3. The GTAP project relies on individuals from the network contributing their country
data. These country data may be based on data from the national statistical office or on
other data sources if national statistical office data do not exist. Contributions are then
checked and reviewed in- house.
4. In the database used in this chapter labor includes five categories, raising the number
of endowments to eight. This new feature is expected to be included in version 9 of the
GTAP database.
5. Not all of the countries in the WIOD database are based on official country data, a
limited number were engineered.
6. RAS is an iterative scaling method commonly used for balancing matrices (McDougall,
1999).
7. Figures are based on Asian Development Outlook, 2010, p. 33. Asia includes all 18 Asian
countries, country groups and Pacific Islands listed in Table 2.5.
81
3. The vulnerability of the Asian
supply chain to localized disasters*
Thomas Hertel, David Hummels and
Terrie L. Walmsley
1. INTRODUCTION
There are good reasons to believe that globalization of supply chains leads
to significant productivity gains for national economies. But heightened
interdependence comes with a down side: shocks to one economy may
create ripples, or in some cases, tidal waves which come crashing down on
the economies of its trade partners.
Economic shocks to global supply chains can take many forms. At the
micro scale, key input suppliers may fail to meet quality and scheduling
targets or simply go out of business. Shocks of this sort can be extraor-
dinarily harmful to agents with close vertical links to the failing firm, but
may have few discernible effects on the economy as a whole. In contrast,
macro scale shocks such as deep recessions, wars and terrorist attacks, and
large natural disasters may create widespread damage. Regrettably, there
is good reason to believe that the severity of these macro scale shocks is on
the rise. The Great Recession and subsequent trade collapse of 2008–2009
represents the largest downturn in international transactions on record.
Climate change is expected to increase the frequency and intensity of
natural disasters. And high profile terrorist attacks against vital infra-
structure, waged in person or online, may significantly impede movements
of goods, services and people.
In this chapter, we use the GTAP- SC (Supply Chain) CGE model to
explore the consequences of two major disruptions to Asian trade and
global production networks: a natural disaster that significantly damages
Taipei,China’s electronics equipment sector, and a severe disruption of
Singapore’s port and entrepot operations. By examining these two, very
different, types of supply chain disruptions, we seek to learn more about
the way in which disasters that are specific to a given industry or entrepot
spread around the world.
82 Asia and global production networks
The existing literature, detailed below, has focused on several dimen-
sions of response to natural disasters. We extend previous work in a
number of ways. First, we introduce a globally consistent multi- region
input–output (MRIO) framework (see Chapter 2 by Walmsley, Hertel and
Hummels for details) that provides an exhaustive framework for global
supply chain analysis. Notably, we can measure the effect of a well- defined
shock to final demand, outputs, and trade. Second, and in contrast to
input–output multiplier approaches, we model temporary scarcities and
market- mediated economic adjustments to the disaster. That is, rather
than assuming that all foreign market outputs adjust costlessly to absorb
the shock, we consider how market prices of goods and factors will adjust
to supply chain disruptions. Third, we address a common criticism of
computable general equilibrium (CGE) analysis, namely that it focuses
excessively on the post- shock, long run equilibrium. In the same spirit as
the analysis of regional impact of municipal water supply disruptions by
Rose and Liao (2005), we develop model variants that replicate short run
versus long run adjustments within the context of a global supply chain.
These include: allowing labor to be imperfectly mobile across sectors,
allowing for short run changes in aggregate employment levels, and allow-
ing for different degrees of substitutability across input sources in response
to price changes.
The existing literature has examined how natural disasters affect trade,
firm- level outcomes, and economy- wide growth. The focus on disasters
and global supply chains is especially relevant because important theo-
ries of offshoring have at their core the possibility of supply disruptions.
In these models (for example, Antras and Helpman, 2004), firms face a
choice between producing inputs internally and offshoring those inputs.
Internal production comes at higher cost but with no chance of supply dis-
ruption, while external production is lower cost but subject to the chance
that foreign suppliers will not deliver the input. In these models the disrup-
tion is often cast in terms of agency problems, often a deliberate defection
by the foreign supplier. But these models can also be understood in terms
of a disruption caused by a natural disaster or political unrest.
The empirical literature on disasters, output and trade employs two dis-
parate approaches. The first focuses on a particular outcome and relates
changes in that outcome to the event of natural disasters. For example,
Noy and Nualsri (2007) employ country- level, panel data to look at the
impact of disasters on economic growth in a dynamic context.
1
Leiter et al.
(2009) delve into firm-level data in order to analyze the impact of flooding
in Europe on firm-level productivity, employment, capital accumulation
and growth. Several papers use panel data on natural disasters and trade,
and estimate the decline in bilateral trade for countries afflicted by natural
The vulnerability of the Asian supply chain 83
disasters of varying severity. In Chapter 4 of this volume, Puzzello and
Raschky show that natural disasters have greater effects on trade volumes
when two countries have tightly linked supply chains.
These analyses excel at showing, retrospectively, the effects of observed
shocks on particular outcome variables. A limitation of these exercises is
that one cannot trace through broader impacts, nor can one definitively
identify the channels (income effects, supply disruption, and price changes
that induce substitution in sourcing, etc.) through which a shock affects
trade or output. To capture these ‘higher order’ effects, one needs a model-
based analysis (Okuyama, 2008). Input–output and general equilibrium
analyses allow for this more in- depth treatment and these approaches are
therefore highly complementary to the econometric studies.
There is a large literature that uses input–output (IO) analysis in order
to track the impact of a disaster all the way through the supply chain
(Lin and Polenske, 1998). This approach has been deployed in a number
of cases to analyze the impact of localized disasters that result in shocks
to output or demand (Okuyama, 2008), or a port shutdown in the case
of Rose and Wei (2013). MacKenzie et al. (2012) offer a recent MRIO
analysis of the 2011 earthquake and tsunami in Japan.
2
In his review of
modeling methods used to analyze the macro- economic consequences
of terrorist attacks, Rose (2013) highlights the many limitations of IO
analysis for accurately assessing these effects. Foremost among these is the
absence of any role for scarcity- driven, market adjustments.
In the companion Chapter 2 of this volume, we describe in detail how
IO multiplier analysis can be thought of as a special case of full CGE anal-
ysis that applies under a very particular set of (strong) assumptions. To
wit, factor supplies are treated as perfectly elastic so that sectoral output
can freely expand in response to the shocks. In contrast, in this chapter, we
explore how factor scarcity and varying degrees of factor mobility, in the
face of a shock, give rise to factor and goods price changes that mediate
the kinds of adjustments that can take place.
2. METHODS
Overview
A MRIO analysis is a common approach to providing economy- wide,
supply- chain analysis of shocks. An example of this methodology is
portrayed in Figure 3.1. With primary factors in perfectly elastic supply,
output prices are fixed and the product supply curve is horizontal.
Therefore, output is demand- driven. Now, suppose income in the foreign
84 Asia and global production networks
country declines due to an exogenous event. The quantity of exports
demanded falls in proportion to the foreign agents’ share of the market,
from D to D’, and output falls by an equal amount from Q to Q’ We can
mimic this behavior in the CGE model by fixing primary factor prices and
allowing their supply to adjust freely in the wake of the demand shock (see
Chapter 2). In this case the drop in foreign incomes will result in a con-
traction in labor demand and an increase in unemployment in the home
market.
There are several problems with this demand- driven input–output
analysis. First, any increase in domestic unemployment will translate into
lower domestic income and a further decrease in demand (from D’ to D”
in Figure 3.2). The CGE approach, which we employ here, captures this
inward shift in demand. Second, supply adjustment is likely to be costly,
especially in the short run, which can be captured with an upward sloping
supply curve in Figure 3.2. This could reflect capacity constraints among
input suppliers, or rival uses for primary factors in other sectors of the
economy, as we see below. Contrasting Figures 3.1 and 3.2, not only are
the quantity responses different, but other response margins (prices, factor
supplies) are accounted for, thereby lending considerable advantage to the
CGE approach.
The simplest way of introducing a supply chain disruption and the one
most readily available in MRIO analysis would be through an exogenous
shock to the quantity of output in the affected sector. However, in reality,
output is not an exogenous factor in the context of most disasters. A more
realistic way to handle disruptions is to assume that production capacity
Price
Quantity
Supply
D
D'
Q' Q
Source: Authors’ construction.
Figure 3.1 Impact of a demand shock in a MRIO framework
The vulnerability of the Asian supply chain 85
is either destroyed, or firms in the industry experience reduced efficiency.
Depending on market prices and response horizons, plant operators may
respond to the shock by reducing output, laying off workers, or by altering
the input–output intensity of certain factors of production in an attempt
to come to grips with this loss in productivity. Following this approach,
output remains endogenous, with quantity and price adjustments explic-
itly modeled so that adjustments in both factor and commodity prices
become a key part of the story. The CGE approach employed here allows
us to overcome these limitations of partial equilibrium, MRIO analysis.
By enforcing a link from income to expenditure, we capture the depend-
ence of total demand on earnings in the economy. By shocking technology
instead of output, we allow for affected firms to respond to the disaster
by applying more capital, labor and materials, subject to availability and
relevant incentives. And by endogenizing firms’ output decisions, we are
able to allow affected industries to respond to the natural disaster in a
rational manner a point which Rose and Wei describe as ‘resilience’
(Rose and Wei, 2013). However, and contrary to occasional critiques (e.g.,
Okuyama, 2008), we are not assuming long run equilibrium applies in our
CGE analysis. Rather, we can vary our assumptions to allow for adjust-
ments that may occur at different time horizons (see also Rose and Liao,
2005 on this same point).
In order to capture the short run nature of the supply chain disruptions,
we invoke a special set of factor market assumptions. While one might
initially think about fixing all factors of production, a bit of reflection
Q' Q
Price
Quantity
Supply
D
D'
D"
Q"
Source: Authors’ construction.
Figure 3.2 Impact of a demand shock in a CGE framework
86 Asia and global production networks
makes it clear that this is not a reasonable assumption. With all factors
of production fixed, and no short run substitution possibilities between
materials and value- added, output in the model is also fixed in all sectors.
With output fixed in all sectors, there can be no supply- side adjustment
and any production shortfall will be met with dramatic price increases,
while any reduction in demand will be accompanied by a collapse in prices.
So the absence of any supply adjustment seems unrealistic and the ques-
tion becomes: Where is the supply- side adjustment most likely to occur in
the short run?
In our base case, we choose to fix capital stock in each sector in the
short run closure. This seems reasonable, since opportunities for adjusting
manufacturing capital in the wake of a natural disaster appear to be quite
limited. On the other hand, we allow for the free movement of unskilled
labor across sectors in response to the shock. In addition, we fix real wages
for unskilled workers and allow for changes in the rate of employment.
While clerks and other low- skill workers must be given notice prior to
layoffs in many economies, we believe that some adjustment along these
lines is likely. As part of our robustness checks, we explore the implications
of restricting unskilled labor mobility in the presence of a supply shock.
The final primary factors of interest are the skilled labor categories.
Here, due to the sector- specific skills of workers, we assume that there is
less labor mobility. With imperfect labor mobility, skill premia are allowed
to emerge across sectors over the short run. In addition, we assume firms
that have invested in these workers are reluctant to lay them off, and
therefore there is no change in the aggregate employment rate for skilled
workers in this closure.
Experimental Design
A convenient way of thinking about the impact of different types of dis-
ruptions along the global supply chain is through the global inter- industry
matrix depicted in Figure 3.3. When these flows are converted to a per- unit
output basis, we refer to this as the ‘A’ matrix in deference to customary
notation in IO analysis. The columns in the A matrix portray the amount
of input required from every industry in every region of the world in order
to produce one unit of output in a given country, where each block of
rows/columns corresponds to a given country and each individual row
depicts the domestic sales of an industry within that country. Due to the
proclivity of industries to source products from domestic suppliers, this
matrix tends to be block diagonal. The density of the off- diagonal blocks
reflects the dependence of a given industry/country on foreign suppliers
and export sales.
87
JPN
Agriculture
TAP
Agriculture
TAP
Apparel
TAP
ELE
MAL
Services
MAL
Agriculture
SIN
Apparel
SIN
ELE
SIN
Machinery
SIN
ROW
Services
JPN Agriculture
TAP Agriculture
TAP Apparel
TAP ELE
MAL Services
SIN Agriculture
SIN Apparel
SIN ELE
SIN Machinery
SIN …
ROW Services
Outputs
Inputs
Notes: JPN = Japan; TAP = Taipei,China; MAL = Malaysia; SIN = Singapore; ROW = rest of the world. The actual technology matrix has 22
× 21 (= 462) rows and 22 × 21 columns to fully represent the 22 sectors in each of the 21 regions, for a matrix with 462 × 462 (= 213,444) cells. The
diagonally shaded regions represent Taipei,China’s ELE sector as an input into potentially 462 distinct region x sectors, and a purchaser of inputs
from up to 462 distinct region x sectors.
Source: Authors’ construction.
Figure 3.3 Global inter-industry matrix
88 Asia and global production networks
In this chapter, we explore the impact of two different types of global
supply disruptions. In the first case, we consider the situation in which a
given industry (electrical equipment) in a given country (Taipei,China)
experiences a natural disaster. This is motivated by the 21 September 1999
earthquake in Taipei,China that temporarily disabled two plants produc-
ing the vast majority of highly specialized semiconductor chips used by
electronics manufacturers worldwide (Barry, 2005). This supply disrup-
tion resulted in global shortages in products for which these chips were
critical components. It laid in stark relief the vulnerability of the global
supply chain for manufactures, which has evolved into a highly integrated
system in recent decades.
When viewed in terms of Figure 3.3, the first round of this supply
chain disruption can be thought of as a shock to the purchasers of
Taipei,Chinese semiconductor chips represented by the narrow shaded
row of the A matrix. Furthermore, any slow- down in chip manufacturing
in Taipei,China will also affect those industries supplying the semiconduc-
tor industry a set of transactions reflected in the first shaded column
in Figure 3.3. And there will be second round and third round effects
beyond these direct effects. For example, in many cases the products in
which these chips are used are themselves intermediate inputs into other
products. Therefore, in order to deduce the combination of direct and
indirect effects implicit in this infinite chain of sales dependencies, we must
compute the elements of the matrix: (I − A)
−1
. Herein lies the heart of IO
analysis. In the CGE model, these same direct and indirect elements come
into play when the model is solved for a new equilibrium following an
exogenous shock. However, in addition to these inter- industry dependen-
cies, we have the income effects and factor market interactions described
in Figure 3.2.
The inter- industry flows matrix in Figure 3.3 can also be used to con-
ceptualize the second experiment to be considered in this chapter. Here, we
explore the case in which a natural or man- made disaster hits Singapore–
the key entrepot in Southeast Asia, through which a large share of the
region’s trade passes. In the case of this entrepot disruption, it is the
external transactions between Singapore and her trading partners that
are directly affected. These are represented by the larger shaded blocks of
off- diagonal columns and rows in Figure 3.3 (rows and columns beginning
with SIN). These blocks are quite dense when it comes to Singapore’s trade
with Southeast Asia. Therefore, anything that disrupts these flows can
have a significant impact in the region, and even in the global economy.
As with the Taipei,Chinese semiconductor disruption, any disruption to
these flows in the A matrix will have further knock- on effects, as these
traded intermediate inputs are used in other products further down the
The vulnerability of the Asian supply chain 89
supply chain. These effects can be captured by computing (I A)
−1
or
equivalently, by solving the CGE model.
In keeping with our desire to allow outputs to adjust endogenously in
the face of a supply chain disaster, both of these experiments are imple-
mented as shocks to the underlying technology variables. In the case of the
Taipei,Chinese electronic equipment sector, we postulate a 40 percent pro-
ductivity loss.
3
Thus, rather than eliminating production altogether, we
assume that, if no additional inputs are applied, production would drop
to 60 percent of initial levels. In fact, with this kind of adverse productiv-
ity shock, in the context of a competitive global economy, output may fall
more, or less, depending on demand and supply conditions. This point will
be illustrated in our robustness analysis later in the chapter.
In the case of the Singaporean trade disruption, we postulate an 80
percent reduction in productivity of international trade margin activi-
ties between Singapore and all her trading partners (both imports and
exports).
4
One way of thinking about this would be that Singapore’s
vaunted electronic customs clearance system is disrupted such that all of
these transactions must be handled by hand. Alternatively, a hurricane or
tsunami might destroy some of the port facilities. In any case, the upshot is
a sharp increase in the cost of trading with Singapore and hence of trading
within the Southeast Asia region. Therefore, some of the shipments that
had previously passed through Singapore must now be diverted along
other routes, thereby raising the cost of delivered products.
3. MODEL, DATA, PARAMETERS AND CLOSURE
CGE Model
The CGE model, which is used for this study, is a modified version of the
GTAP model of global trade (Hertel, 1997). GTAP is a relatively stand-
ard, global CGE model in which products are differentiated by region of
origin. For this chapter, we assume that all of the adjustment to scarcity
is at the intensive margin (higher prices for existing varieties). There are
other versions of the GTAP model that also feature an extensive margin
of adjustment (entry and exit of new varieties and product differentiation
by firm, for example by Francois, 1998 and by Hertel and Swaminathan,
1996); however, we do not believe that the extensive margin of adjustment
is relevant for the short run analyses undertaken here.
Another important feature of the standard model is the treatment of
international trade and transport activities. Rather than treat these activi-
ties as a pure trade barrier, akin to tariffs, bilateral merchandise trade
90 Asia and global production networks
is facilitated by the application of international transport services. The
GTAP database measures the associated transport and insurance serv-
ices obtained from national exports and provided to the global trade and
transport sectors of which there are three distinct modes in the database
(air, sea and land). Thus when entrepot trade is disrupted via productiv-
ity deterioration, trade must either contract, or transport services exports
must rise in order to cover the gap left by the drop in efficiency associated
with Singaporean trade flows.
Finally, and most important for the present study, we extend the
standard model to include bilateral sourcing of imports by agent. Thus the
global CGE model must embody the full Amatrix shown in Figure 3.3.
Therefore, for example, the intensity of Japanese imports of Taipei,Chinese
electronic equipment must be allowed to vary by sector and use (consump-
tion, government purchases, investment, and intermediate inputs).
Data
For the purposes of this study, we use the GTAP 8.1 database (Narayanan
et al., 2012). This was the latest available version of the GTAP database
at the time we undertook this research. It is benchmarked to the year
2007 and disaggregates global economic activity into 57 sectors and 129
countries/regions. This means that the dimensions of the A matrix in
Figure 3.3 are (57x129) rows and (57x129) columns. While inverting a
matrix of this dimension no longer presents a computational challenge, it
does render analysis rather difficult. As a consequence, and given the focus
of this chapter on manufacturing supply chains in Asia, we have aggre-
gated the GTAP 8.1 database to 21 sectors (largely manufacturing) and
to 22 economies/regions. There are 19 Asia economies/regions separately
identified in this study, as well as three non- Asian regions: the European
Union (EU), North America and Other.
Since the GTAP database does not track imports to individual sectors,
some further adjustments were required in order to match the schematic
called for in Figure 3.3; the details are provided in Chapter 2. Essentially, the
procedure involves application of the UN Broad Economic Classification
(or BEC concordance) at the harmonized system (HS6) trade level in order
to identify which suppliers are sending products primarily to intermediate
uses and which are supplying imports for final demand. It should be noted
that this approach does not really employ product sourcing information.
Such data can only be obtained by conducting detailed industry surveys,
which are generally not available at present. The other important limita-
tion to note is that Taipei,China is not a reporter in the HS6 trade data
obtained from the United Nations. Therefore the sourcing of imports
The vulnerability of the Asian supply chain 91
by agent for Taipei,China is done in a strictly proportional fashion. (See
Chapter 2 for more details and for a comparison of BEC- based versus
proportional sourcing of imports.)
Given our interest in labor markets, we also take advantage of the
more refined disaggregation of labor categories, following the work of
Weingarden and Tsigas (2010), as implemented by Walmsley and Carrico
(2013). Rather than just two categories of labor (skilled and unskilled), we
have five categories, disaggregated by occupation using source data from
the International Labour Organization (ILO). These categories include:
office managers and professionals, technicians and associate profession-
als, clerks, service and shop workers, and finally, agricultural workers and
other low- skill employees. For ease of discussion below, when we refer
to skilled workers, this category will encompass the first two groups of
workers (office managers and professionals plus technicians and associate
professionals). Accordingly, unskilled workers will refer to the final three
categories (clerks; service and shop workers; and agricultural and other
low- skill workers).
Parameters and Model Closure
We begin with the standard GTAP parameter file and modify these
values as appropriate to this study. The constant difference of elasticities
(CDE) consumer demand system parameters are based on international
cross- section estimates following the approach of Reimer and Hertel
(2004). Trade elasticities are based on the international cross- section
estimates of Hertel et al. (2007) using bilateral imports, tariff and trans-
port cost data for six countries in the Americas, as well as New Zealand.
Production side parameters are specified in terms of elasticities of sub-
stitution among inputs in the nested constant elasticity of substitution
(CES) production functions, and are based on a review of the econometric
literature as reported in Hertel et al. (2009).
In addition, the GTAP model parameter file includes elasticities of
transformation governing the inter- sectoral mobility of land, labor and
capital. For example, in order to move labor from one sector to another, it
must be ‘transformed’, say from manufacturing capital to services capital.
These elasticities of transformation range from zero (sector- specificity,
which is what we assume for capital and land) to infinite (perfect mobil-
ity, which is what we assume for unskilled labor). In the case of skilled
labor, we allow for partial mobility. Specifically, we assume a value of
−1.0, which means that there is incomplete labor mobility such that wages
can diverge across sectors. Later, we will explore the implications of also
making unskilled labor imperfectly mobile.
92 Asia and global production networks
The final aspect of our model closure that is relevant for this study is our
treatment of unemployment. Given the short run nature of this study, we
allow for unemployment of unskilled labor. This is achieved in the model
by imposing real wage rigidity. With real wages for unskilled workers
fixed, equilibrium is restored after the shock by changing the overall
employment rate. In the case of skilled labor, we assume that the aggregate
employment rate is unaffected by the disaster.
4. RESULTS FROM THE INDUSTRY- SPECIFIC
SHOCK
We begin with an analysis of the adverse shock to the Taipei,Chinese elec-
trical equipment sector. The 1999 earthquake in Taipei,China notwith-
standing, it is unlikely that such an event will only affect one sector of the
economy. In practice, given the spatial distribution of industries, one would
expect multiple sectors to be affected. However, by focusing on a single
sector, we are able to draw out more sharply the implications of a shock
that is not economy- wide in nature. How will this affect other sectors in the
Taipei,Chinese economy? How will it affect competing sectors in other econ-
omies? In short, this targeted shock to productivity is a useful way to think
about supply disruptions that disproportionately affect a single industry.
The electrical equipment (ELE) sector in Taipei,China is dispropor-
tionate in size, accounting for roughly 10 percent of the country’s gross
domestic product (GDP), and more than 8 percent of global ELE exports
in the year 2007. (In contrast, Japan’s ELE sector accounts for less than
3 percent of GDP.) Taipei,China’s ELE sector is also heavily integrated
into the Asian supply chain, with two- thirds of its exports destined for
Asia. The majority of these flows (43 percent of total ELE exports) are
destined for the People’s Republic of China (PRC).
When the ELE sector experiences this adverse productivity shock, we
anticipate a variety of different impacts on the global economy. First
of all, consumers will face higher priced goods due to the ensuing short-
age. While this effect will likely be most sharply felt in the domestic
economy, consumers in other economies that are closely integrated with
Taipei,China (e.g., the PRC) will also be affected. In addition, ELE firms
in other regions will be affected by this supply disruption. In their case,
they stand to benefit from this event both through higher prices for
existing sales, as well as through increased sales volume to export markets.
Other sectors will also be affected by this productivity shock –particu-
larly those, such as the automotive industry, which rely on the electrical
equipment sector for intermediate inputs.
The vulnerability of the Asian supply chain 93
Finally, we expect the rest of the Taipei,Chinese economy to be affected
by this disruption. Tradable sectors may benefit from the availability of
additional unskilled workers – that will hinge critically on the mobility of
the labor force, as discussed above. We also anticipate this shock being
accompanied by a real exchange rate depreciation. As Taipei,Chinese ELE
exports shrink, other exports must rise and/or imports must contract, in
order to restore balance of payments equilibrium, given a fixed capital
account. This will stimulate the other tradable sectors. On the other hand,
the ensuing reduction in spending due to income losses incurred in the
wake of this disaster will likely harm the non- tradable sectors, which rely
on consumer spending to drive sales.
Domestic Impacts
The 40 percent drop in Taipei,Chinese ELE productivity results in an
81 percent reduction in output of that sector in the short run (Table 3.1:
baseline – other columns will be discussed below), as the ELE sector loses
competitiveness and sheds workers (capital stock is fixed in the short
run). ELE exports drop even more sharply (–85 percent: Table 3.2). In
order to restore external balance, exports of other sectors must rise (Table
3.2), a development that is facilitated by a real depreciation, with the real
exchange rate in Taipei,China dropping by 19 percent in the baseline
case (Table 3.1). As a result, output in nearly all the other sectors of the
Taipei,Chinese economy rises. The only non- ELE sectors that experience
a decline in output are the two service sectors and the food industry. These
sectors rely heavily on sales to domestic consumers, who experience a
strong drop in real income following this disaster (–14 percent: Table 3.1,
baseline). Overall the contraction in domestic demand results in a fall in
short run employment of unskilled workers in the economy by 7 percent
(unskilled production workers), 11 percent (clerks) and 13 percent (service
workers).
As noted above, a critical piece of this analysis is the treatment of factor
markets. In our baseline model, we treat capital as sector- specific, and
therefore immobile in the short run. Skilled labor is partially mobile, and
unskilled labor is perfectly mobile. What if unskilled labor is also imper-
fectly mobile? This change in assumption means less supply- side flexibil-
ity in the economy and the associated outcomes are reported under the
heading ‘lowmobile’ in the tables of results. Comparing across the first two
columns in Tables 3.1 and 3.2, we see that further restricting factor mobil-
ity results in less contraction of the ELE sector, less expansion of output
and exports in the other heavily traded sectors of the economy, a stronger
real depreciation, a larger decline in employment and a greater fall in
94 Asia and global production networks
real income (two percentage points more decline). In short, the impact of
this disaster on the Taipei,Chinese economy is considerably worse when
unskilled workers cannot readily shift their sector of employment.
The foregoing analysis has focused on the supply- side. However, the
demand side characteristics are also critical to supply- chain adjustment
to an industry- specific disaster. Here, the most important parameters
are the trade elasticities governing the potential to substitute away from
Taipei,Chinese ELE products. If there is little potential to replace these
products with substitute goods in the short run, then the adverse impact
of the disruption will be much larger, and the beneficial effects for com-
petitor economies will be smaller. The trade elasticities employed in the
standard GTAP model were estimated by Hertel et al. (2007). These esti-
mates employed data at the HS6 level, but were pooled across disaggregate
commodities, with the estimated elasticities constrained to be equal within
GTAP commodity categories. As such these elasticities of substitution
between products sourced from different regions reflect longer run adjust-
ments. This contrasts with short run estimates of trade elasticities, such as
those by Gallaway et al. (2003) who report much smaller trade elasticities.
Therefore, it seems appropriate to evaluate the impact of sharply reducing
these parameter values in the context of a ‘demand- side’ sensitivity analy-
sis. For purposes of the current chapter, we adopt short run values which
are just one- third of the longer run values and we dub this experiment
‘lowelast’ for reporting purposes.
The third columns in Tables 3.1 and 3.2 report the change in selected
economic variables for the Taipei,Chinese economy following the ELE
Table 3.1 Impact of ELE disruption on Taipei,China economy
(percentage change)
Variable Baseline
scenario
Lowmobile
scenario
Lowelast
scenario
Low/low
scenario
Real income −14 −16 −18 −18
Real exchange rate −19 −22 −26 −27
ELE output −81 −74 −57 −52
Employment of:
Clerks −11 −14 −17 −18
Service workers −13 −16 −21 −22
Unskilled production workers −7 −9 −9 −6
Note: ELE 5 electronics equipment sector.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
The vulnerability of the Asian supply chain 95
productivity shock in the context of these smaller trade elasticities, while
retaining the baseline assumptions about the factor markets. Not surpris-
ingly, lower trade elasticities make it harder for other firms to shift away
from Taipei,Chinese ELE products and output now falls by less (–57
Table 3.2 Impact of ELE disruption on Taipei,China output and exports,
by sector (percentage change)
Sector Output Exports
Base-
line
scenario
Low-
mobile
scenario
Low-
elast
scenario
Low/
low
scenario
Base-
line
scenario
Low-
mobile
scenario
Low-
elast
scenario
Low/
low
scenario
Agriculture 1 0 −2 −2 36 36 33 32
Processed food −1 −2 −6 −6 47 52 31 33
Resources 4 2 5 2 3 5 15 11
Textiles 24 9 20 11 25 10 22 13
Apparel 12 4 4 0 53 40 33 29
Leather 19 8 11 7 26 14 18 14
Lumber 23 9 16 10 33 15 23 15
Paper products 6 2 0 0 57 47 32 31
Petro-
chemicals
3 −1 0 −2 3 4 2 3
Chemical,
rubber and
plastics
14 6 11 7 22 14 16 12
Mineral
products
5 2 2 2 44 36 26 23
Iron and steel 15 7 13 8 14 9 15 10
Nonferrous
metals
20 9 17 11 29 18 20 14
Fabricated
metals
19 7 14 8 42 24 30 20
Motor vehicles 6 2 −2 −2 36 33 25 25
Transport
equipment
22 8 14 7 40 21 31 21
Electrical
equipment
−81 −74 −57 −52 −85 −78 −61 −56
Machinery
equipment
19 7 14 8 29 16 22 15
Other
manufactures
15 5 8 4 28 16 21 16
Non- trade
services
−5 −5 −7 −6 144 198 57 63
Services −5 −5 −9 −8 60 75 32 36
Note: ELE 5 electronics equipment sector.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
96 Asia and global production networks
percent vs –81 percent in the baseline experiment). However, less intuitive
is the much stronger real exchange rate depreciation and the sharper rise
in unemployment. Aggregate employment of service workers now falls
by 21 percent. This stems from a more indirect mechanism namely the
smaller trade elasticities in other sectors of the economy. In this ‘lowelast’
scenario, it is much harder for the non- ELE sectors to expand in the wake
of the ELE disaster. Their ability to displace imports in the Taipei,Chinese
market is greatly muted, as is their ability to penetrate foreign markets
with increased exports. As a consequence, the increase in non- ELE exports
is much smaller under the ‘lowelast’ scenario than under the baseline
scenario despite the fact that unskilled workers are perfectly mobile
under this experiment. Therefore, in order to restore external balance, the
real exchange rate depreciation must be much larger, and the consequences
of real wage rigidity for unskilled employment are more significant when
there is greater demand side rigidity in the supply chain.
It is also interesting to explore how the inelastic supply and inelastic
demand scenarios interact. The final (fourth) columns in Tables 3.1
and 3.2 report results for selected Taipei,China variables when both the
supply- and demand- side rigidities are imposed simultaneously. In this
case, the real exchange rate depreciation is somewhat larger, as are the
employment decreases for clerks and services workers. However, the
employment reduction for production workers is now diminished even
relative to baseline – due to the lesser decline in Taipei,China’s ELE
output, as both supply- and demand- side forces conspire to retain workers
in the ELE sector. In short, inelasticity on the demand and supply sides
is not always mutually reinforcing that is, the combined impact on key
variables is not always as expected from a simple addition of the indi-
vidual effects.
Global Impacts
Table 3.3 reports the impact of the ELE productivity shock on other
regions in the global economy. The first block of columns reports
the impact on domestic firms’ prices for ELE products in these non-
Taipei,China regions. (All price changes are reported, relative to the
numeraire, which is a global index of primary factor prices.) We expect
upward pressure on ELE prices for several reasons. Firstly, Taipei,Chinese
ELE components represent an intermediate input to ELE manufacturing
in many of these regions. So higher priced components raise the cost of the
final product. Ceteris paribus, this will result in a decline in ELE output,
as consumers purchase less in the face of higher prices. However, there is
another important factor at work, which is the outward shift in demand
97
Table 3.3 Impact of ELE disruption on other regions’ ELE output, terms of trade and real income (percentage change)
Region ELE price ELE output
Baseline
scenario
Lowmobile
scenario
Lowelast
scenario
Low/low
scenario
Baseline
scenario
Lowmobile
scenario
Lowelast
scenario
Low/low
scenario
Japan 2.3 4.3 4.5 7.2 5.2 4.1 3.4 2.4
Korea, Republic of 2.8 4.7 4.2 6.3 3.8 3.2 4.3 3.4
China, People’s
Republic of
2.7 4.6 3.8 5.8 5.5 4.0 4.7 3.7
Other East Asia 1.8 3.8 1.4 3.3 6.2 4.9 4.9 4.2
Singapore 2.9 4.7 4.7 6.4 1.2 1.7 1.6 1.9
Philippines 3.4 5.3 6.6 8.4 1.2 1.1 0.5 0.2
Thailand 3.2 5.1 5.0 7.1 2.3 1.8 3.3 2.3
Indonesia 2.5 4.7 2.8 5.2 8.1 5.6 8.5 6.2
Malaysia 2.9 4.7 4.1 6.0 3.5 3.0 4.0 3.3
Viet Nam 2.3 4.3 2.6 4.7 10.3 7.8 9.1 7.6
Other Southeast Asia 1.6 3.3 1.4 2.6 2.2 2.1 1.5 1.6
India 1.1 2.9 0.8 2.0 4.5 4.6 2.8 3.1
Bangladesh 2.2 4.1 2.4 4.3 2.0 1.7 2.5 2.2
Pakistan 1.5 3.2 5.8 5.6 1.5 1.5 1.0 1.0
Other South Asia 1.5 3.2 0.6 0.8 3.1 3.0 1.5 1.6
Central Asia 1.0 2.9 0.3 1.7 2.8 2.4 1.5 1.5
Pacific Islands 1.2 2.8 0.6 1.5 3.6 4.0 2.4 2.8
Australia and
New Zealand
1.4 3.2 0.4 1.7 5.6 5.4 4.3 4.4
European Union 2.0 3.8 2.0 3.6 4.3 4.1 3.9 3.7
North America 1.7 3.5 1.4 2.8 5.6 5.3 4.6 4.6
Rest of world 1.7 3.4 1.1 2.4 3.2 3.2 2.6 2.6
98
Table 3.3 (continued)
Region Terms of trade Real income
Baseline
scenario
Lowmobile
scenario
Lowelast
scenario
Low/low
scenario
Baseline
scenario
Lowmobile
scenario
Lowelast
scenario
Low/low
scenario
Japan 0.3 0.5 2.5 3.3 0.1 0.2 0.8 1.1
Korea, Republic of 0.4 0.8 0.9 1.5 0.3 0.6 0.9 1.4
China, People’s Republic of −0.2 −0.2 −0.9 −0.9 −0.1 0.0 −0.4 −0.4
Other East Asia −0.1 −0.2 −0.4 −0.5 0.0 −0.1 −0.2 −0.3
Singapore 0.1 0.3 0.1 0.4 0.2 0.5 0.3 0.8
Philippines 1.3 2.0 3.6 4.7 0.9 1.4 2.3 3.0
Thailand 0.3 0.5 0.4 0.6 0.3 0.6 0.5 0.8
Indonesia 0.0 0.0 −0.2 −0.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 −0.1
Malaysia 0.4 0.5 0.5 0.6 0.8 1.1 0.9 1.2
Viet Nam 0.2 0.1 0.3 −0.1 0.6 0.3 0.8 0.1
Other Southeast Asia 0.0 −0.1 −0.2 −0.5 0.0 −0.1 −0.1 −0.3
India −0.1 −0.2 −0.2 −0.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 −0.1
Bangladesh 0.0 0.0 −0.2 −0.5 0.0 0.0 −0.1 −0.3
Pakistan −0.2 −0.2 3.4 2.0 0.0 0.0 1.7 1.2
Other South Asia 0.0 −0.1 −1.5 −3.0 0.0 0.0 −1.0 −2.2
Central Asia −0.2 −0.3 −0.5 −0.7 −0.1 −0.2 −0.3 −0.4
Pacific Islands −0.1 −0.2 −0.4 −0.6 0.0 −0.1 −0.2 −0.4
Australia and New Zealand −0.3 −0.5 −1.0 −1.3 −0.1 −0.1 −0.4 −0.5
European Union 0.0 −0.1 −0.1 −0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
North America −0.1 −0.1 −0.5 −0.7 0.0 0.0 −0.1 −0.2
Rest of world −0.1 −0.3 −0.5 −0.6 −0.1 −0.1 −0.2 −0.3
Note: ELE = electronics equipment sector.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
The vulnerability of the Asian supply chain 99
for ELE products around the world in the face of the sharp reduction in
output (and accompanying price rise) in Taipei,China’s ELE sector. The
strongest price rises are for ELE products produced in the Southeast Asian
economies, led by the Philippines (3.4 percent), Thailand (3.2 percent) and
Malaysia and Singapore (2.9 percent). These are followed closely by the
Republic of Korea, the PRC and Indonesia.
The second panel of columns of Table 3.3 report the percentage changes
in ELE output, by region in response to the adverse productivity shock to
the Taipei,Chinese industry. Recall that there are two competing forces at
work here one is the effect of higher costs, and one is the outward shift
in demand for the country’s ELE output. Both drive prices higher, but the
first does so by raising costs and the second does so by boosting demand.
In addition, the profile of ELE sales to intermediate and final demands,
as well as by region, varies greatly. Therefore, it is not surprising that the
pattern of output increases is somewhat different from the price changes.
The strongest output rises are for Viet Nam (10.3 percent) and Indonesia
(8.1 percent). Australia/New Zealand and North America also experi-
ence significant output rises as domestic producers replace Taipei,China
ELE products in their domestic markets. A more nuanced view of the
impact of the Taipei,Chinese ELE shock on her partner economies is
offered in Figure 3.4, which reports the percentage change in non- ELE
export volumes from Japan and the PRC. In the case of Japan, there
is a much stronger increase in ELE exports and a consistent reduction
in non- ELE exports as resources are drawn away from other sectors to
permit this expansion. From this perspective, Japan looks like a com-
petitor economy with Taipei,China. In contrast, the pattern of non- ELE
export impact is different in the case of the PRC where Figure 3.4 shows
that the trade effects are generally more muted, with ELE expanding much
more modestly, non- ELE exports changing less as well, and, in a number
of cases, non- ELE exports actually expanding. These are exports from
Chinese sectors (iron and steel, non- ferrous metals) that are tied into the
Taipei,Chinese economy and benefit when non- ELE tradable sectors in
that economy expand. In this sense, Taipei,China and the PRC appear to
be complementary economies.
The final two blocks of columns in Table 3.3 report two important
economy- wide indicators for these other economies: the terms of trade
(ToT) and real income. The ToT can be decomposed into three component
parts (McDougall, 1993): the world price effect, the export price effect and
the import price effect. Countries will benefit from the higher average
world prices for ELE products, provided they are net exporters of ELE
goods. Countries can additionally gain from the export price effect if their
differentiated product price rises relatively more than the world average
100 Asia and global production networks
(e.g., the Philippines). Finally, those regions that rely disproportionately
on Taipei,China for ELE imports are expected to lose from this disaster
scenario due to the import price effect, as Taipei,China’s ELE prices rise,
relatively more. In light of these considerations, it is not surprising that
the Philippines experiences a strong ToT gain, as do Thailand, Malaysia,
Japan and the Republic of Korea. The PRC shows a ToT loss which
arises due to its heavy dependence on Taipei,China for component parts.
Other Asian regions that lose on the ToT front include India, Pakistan and
Central Asia.
In the absence of domestic distortions, we expect real income changes to
follow the ToT, being somewhat more muted, with the relative magnitude
being determined by the openness of the economy. However, the presence
of numerous taxes and subsidies in the global economy complicate this
story considerably. From the first column in the final panel of Table 3.3,
–10
–5
0
5
10
15
AGR
PF
RC
TEX
WAP
LEA
LUM
PPP
PC
CRP
NMM
IS
NFM
FMP
MVH
OTN
ELE
OME
OMF
NTS
SVC
% change
Japan
PRC
Note: AGR = agriculture; CRP = chemicals, rubber and plastics; ELE = electrical
equipment; FMP = fabricated metals; IS = iron and steel; LEA = leather; LUM = lumber;
MVH = motor vehicles; NFM = nonferrous metals; NMM = mineral products; NTS =
nontrade services; OME = machinery equipment; OMF = other manufactures; OTN =
transport equipment; PC = petro- chemicals; PF = processed food; PPP = paper products;
PRC = People’s Republic of China; RC = resource products; SVC = services; TEX =
textiles; WAP = wearing apparel.
Source: Authors’ simulation.
Figure 3.4 Impact of ELE productivity shock on non- ELE exports from
Japan and the PRC (percentage change)
The vulnerability of the Asian supply chain 101
we see that the largest gainers from the Taipei,China ELE disaster are
the Philippines (0.9 percent rise in real income), followed by Indonesia,
Malaysia, Thailand and the Republic of Korea. The only regions that
show a decline in real income under the base case are the PRC, Central
Asia, Australia/New Zealand and the rest of the world. The result that
unaffected regions are likely to gain from a single region’s disaster is
consistent with the findings of MacKenzie et al. (2012) who analyze the
impacts of the 2011 Japanese earthquake and tsunami.
The subsequent columns in Table 3.3 explore the changes in ELE prices,
outputs, ToT and real incomes for non- Taipei,China regions under the
low labor mobility, low substitutability in demand and combined sce-
narios. Here, it is clearly evident that more inelastic supply and demand
curves result in significantly higher price changes. Indeed, the price rises
under the combined scenario are more than twice as high as under the
baseline case. Of course, the associated ELE output changes are lower
under the combined low mobility and low elasticity scenarios, as it is more
difficult to move unskilled labor between sectors, and firms find it harder
to change their pattern of sourcing in response to the adverse productivity
shock in Taipei,China. However, if we focus solely on the impact of the
smaller trade elasticities, the results are somewhat more varied. The most
common result is for the inelastic demands to result in smaller output
expansions since Taipei,Chinese ELE output contracts less under this
parameter specification, there is less room for others to expand. However,
this is not universally the case. In particular, a number of the Southeast
Asian economies experience stronger output expansions under the inelas-
tic demand cases. This suggests the presence of more complex, cross- sector
effects.
With larger price changes in the more inelastic supply and demand
scenarios, it is not surprising to see larger ToT effects. Indeed, under
the combined inelastic supply/demand scenario, the Philippines’ ToT
gain reaches 4.7 percent and Japan’s gain rises to 3.3 percent. There are
several cases where a negligible effect becomes significantly negative
under the inelastic scenario (Indonesia, Bangladesh, Other South Asia).
And there are even a few cases of sign reversals. In Pakistan, for example,
the ToT effect is negative in the first two cases, but turns positive in the
context of low elasticities of substitution in use. For the most part, the
larger (in absolute value) ToT effects translate into larger real income
effects, as would be expected.
5
The largest loss is felt by Other South
Asia (–2.2 percent), whereas the largest gain accrues to the Philippines
(3 percent).
102 Asia and global production networks
5. RESULTS FROM THE ENTREPOT SHOCK
Singapore is a key trading hub in Southeast Asia, with a very large share
of regional trade passing through its ports. Our experiment involves
sharply reducing the efficiency with which this trade occurs, as would
arise in the context of a natural disaster, which disrupted the port, or a
cyber- attack, which disabled the country’s customs clearance system. The
entrepot shock contrasts with the preceding experiment in that it affects
the productivity with which goods are traded, rather than the productivity
with which they are produced. This experiment affects all the incoming
and outgoing merchandise trade flows for Singapore. As with the previ-
ous experiment, we explore the impact of this shock in the context of a
baseline experiment in which capital is immobile, skilled labor is partially
mobile with fixed aggregate employment, and unskilled labor is perfectly
mobile, with rigid real wages and variable short run employment levels. As
before, these baseline impacts will be contrasted with scenarios in which,
alternately, supply, demand and then both supply and demand are ren-
dered more inelastic by either reducing unskilled labor mobility, reducing
substitution across import sources, or both.
In all of these entrepot experiments, the 80 percent drop in efficiency of
merchandise trading results in higher bilateral merchandise trading costs
with Singapore, which rise by 400 percent. The impact of this increase
on bilateral prices depends on the share of global trade and transport
services in the cost, insurance, and freight- inclusive (cif) price of imports.
For products such as natural resources and agricultural commodities, this
has a significant impact on prices, while the impact is more moderate for
low margin goods. In any case, the need to offset the reduced efficiency of
Singaporean trade requires additional global trade and transport services,
as does the re- routing of trade around the Singapore entrepot. Given
our treatment of the international trade and transport sector as a single
pool, from which the supply of shipping services are drawn to meet the
global demand for international transport margins, these services must
ultimately be supplied from the pool of national services exports. The
increase in global trade and transport services required to accommodate
this supply chain shock is reported at the bottom of Table 3.4 and ranges
from 4 percent in the baseline to 6 percent when the ability of firms and
households to alter their sourcing patterns is more restricted. (Note that
limiting labor mobility on the supply side does not substantially alter this
figure.)
The main two panels of Table 3.4 summarize the impact on the
Singapore economy of this disruption in trade facilitation. With ‘sand in
the gears’ of Singapore’s usually efficient trading system, the economy
The vulnerability of the Asian supply chain 103
experiences a sharp real exchange rate depreciation, large reductions in
unskilled employment, and a 21 percent decline in real income under the
baseline scenario. Since the shock cuts across the board in the Singaporean
economy, this outcome is little affected by the reduction in labor mobil-
ity (column two). All sectors are hurt by this entrepot disruption, and
unlike the Taipei,China ELE shock, adjustment is less reliant on shifting
labor between sectors. However, when trade elasticities are reduced, the
macro- economic outcome is far worse for Singapore. In this case, the real
exchange rate depreciation, and the reductions in employment and real
income approach 30 percent. The difficulty in changing the sourcing of
products affects not only her trading partners, but also Singaporean pro-
ducers and therefore there is little scope for avoiding the burden of higher
trade costs. This makes the economy much less competitive, thereby
requiring an even greater real depreciation. In short, this is an example
of a supply chain disruption for which the ability to alter the sourcing of
imports is paramount.
Table 3.5 reports the impact of this entrepot disruption on global
merchandise and services trade by commodity. It is hardly surprising
that services exports rise, as the reduction in Singapore’s trade efficiency
requires additional effort to move the same amount of goods. The largest
percentage reduction in global trade volume is for petro- chemicals (–1.12
percent). Singapore is an important refiner of petroleum and related
products and this industry suffers from the higher cost of importing
crude petroleum and exporting refined products. Transport equipment,
Table 3.4 Impact of entrepot disruption on Singapore economy
(percentage change)
Variable Baseline
scenario
Lowmobile
scenario
Lowelast
scenario
Low/low
scenario
Real income −21 −21 −28 −28
Real exchange rate −19 −19 −29 −29
Exports −11 −10 −0.1 −0.1
Employment of:
Clerks −21 −21 −29 −30
Service workers −15 −15 −27 −27
Unskilled production workers −25 −26 −30 −30
Global trade and transport services
4 4 6 6
Source: Authors’ calculations.
104 Asia and global production networks
machinery and equipment and fabricated metal products are also rela-
tively hard hit. As with the earlier results, restricting factor mobility does
not change the results significantly. And in the case of global commod-
ity exports, the smaller trade elasticities have less effect than might be
expected. While the smaller trade elasticities generally reduce the change
in trade volume, as expected, this is not always the case, as shown by the
other transport equipment sector, where the impact of lesser substitutabil-
ity across sources dominates and trade falls even more under the inelastic
demand scenarios.
Table 3.6 reports the impact of this entrepot disruption on the
non- Singaporean economies. In the first block of columns, under the base-
line parameter settings, exports for many of these economies rise, as trade
Table 3.5 Impact of entrepot disruption on global trade volume
(percentage change)
Commodity Global exports by commodity
Baseline
scenario
Lowmobile
scenario
Lowelast
scenario
Low/low
scenario
Agriculture −0.05 −0.05 0.04 0.04
Processed food −0.23 −0.23 −0.07 −0.06
Resources −0.27 −0.27 −0.11 −0.11
Textiles −0.07 −0.07 −0.04 −0.05
Apparel −0.08 −0.07 0.02 0.01
Leather −0.11 −0.11 −0.02 −0.02
Lumber −0.01 −0.03 0.00 −0.04
Paper products −0.33 −0.33 −0.15 −0.17
Petro- chemicals −1.12 −1.13 −0.54 −0.55
Chemical, rubber and plastics −0.28 −0.28 −0.17 −0.17
Mineral products −0.33 −0.33 −0.21 −0.24
Iron and steel −0.21 −0.21 −0.18 −0.18
Nonferrous metals −0.11 −0.10 −0.13 −0.13
Fabricated metals −0.46 −0.46 −0.31 −0.33
Motor vehicles −0.08 −0.08 −0.20 −0.22
Transport equipment −0.98 −0.96 −1.16 −1.14
Electrical equipment −0.29 −0.28 −0.22 −0.23
Machinery equipment −0.46 −0.45 −0.46 −0.45
Other manufactures −0.18 −0.18 −0.19 −0.21
Non- trade services 0.01 0.01 −0.03 0.00
Services 0.80 0.79 1.05 1.04
Source: Authors’ calculations.
105
Table 3.6 Global impact of entrepot disruption (percentage change)
Region Regional exports Real exchange rate
Baseline
scenario
Lowmobile
scenario
Lowelast
scenario
Low/low
scenario
Baseline
scenario
Lowmobile
scenario
Lowelast
scenario
Low/low
scenario
Japan −0.12 −0.14 −1.42 −1.62 0.24 0.30 1.49 1.96
Korea, Republic of 0.15 0.14 −0.36 −0.33 0.49 0.57 1.41 1.62
China, People’s Republic of 0.00 −0.01 0.05 0.04 0.06 0.06 0.01 0.02
Taipei,China 0.03 0.02 −0.02 −0.03 0.13 0.15 −0.01 0.02
Other East Asia 0.07 0.09 0.05 0.08 0.07 0.04 0.04 0.01
Philippines 0.23 0.21 0.54 0.46 −0.18 −0.18 −0.98 −0.97
Thailand 0.16 0.10 0.28 0.25 −0.15 −0.10 −0.71 −0.70
Indonesia −0.52 −0.48 0.78 0.73 −0.91 −1.00 −2.61 −2.87
Malaysia −0.84 −0.84 0.03 0.00 −0.93 −0.90 −1.97 −2.02
Viet Nam 0.46 0.54 1.45 1.68 −1.48 −1.76 −4.14 −5.31
Other Southeast Asia 0.02 0.10 0.43 0.46 −0.41 −0.54 −1.28 −1.49
India −0.02 −0.12 −0.20 −0.33 0.09 0.12 0.38 0.52
Bangladesh 0.07 0.07 0.69 0.66 −0.06 −0.09 −0.67 −0.87
Pakistan 0.11 0.10 −3.41 −1.86 0.03 0.02 3.65 2.22
Other South Asia 0.35 0.35 5.91 7.22 −0.2 −0.22 −6.45 −8.45
Central Asia 0.17 0.19 0.20 0.23 −0.08 −0.16 −0.23 −0.37
Pacific Islands −0.20 −0.18 0.97 1.04 −0.29 −0.36 −1.58 −1.83
Australia and New Zealand 0.19 0.21 1.05 1.12 −0.36 −0.42 −1.89 −2.13
European Union 0.01 0.01 −0.15 −0.19 0.14 0.16 0.53 0.66
North America 0.05 0.06 0.39 0.50 0.04 0.04 −0.32 −0.48
Rest of world 0.16 0.18 0.26 0.30 −0.02 −0.06 −0.22 −0.31
106
Table 3.6 (continued)
Region Terms of trade Real income
Baseline
scenario
Lowmobile
scenario
Lowelast
scenario
Low/low
scenario
Baseline
scenario
Lowmobile
scenario
Lowelast
scenario
Low/low
scenario
Japan 0.15 0.18 1.04 1.19 0.07 0.07 0.34 0.37
Korea, Republic of 0.24 0.27 0.68 0.71 0.26 0.28 0.65 0.68
China, People’s Republic of −0.06 −0.05 −0.10 −0.10 −0.01 0.00 −0.04 −0.03
Other East Asia 0.02 0.04 −0.09 −0.07 0.03 0.04 −0.08 −0.06
Singapore 0.01 −0.03 0.04 −0.01 −0.02 −0.03 0.03 0.01
Philippines −0.29 −0.28 −0.59 −0.54 −0.15 −0.15 −0.36 −0.32
Thailand −0.20 −0.17 −0.51 −0.50 −0.28 −0.25 −0.55 −0.52
Indonesia −1.61 −1.64 −2.72 −2.73 −0.80 −0.79 −1.27 −1.24
Malaysia −1.16 −1.14 −1.74 −1.74 −1.73 −1.68 −2.36 −2.29
Viet Nam −1.05 −1.12 −2.05 −2.25 −1.65 −1.75 −3.66 −4.14
Other Southeast Asia −0.91 −1.03 −1.31 −1.39 −0.67 −0.72 −0.88 −0.89
India 0.09 0.14 0.38 0.49 0.03 0.03 0.16 0.20
Bangladesh −0.17 −0.17 −0.47 −0.46 −0.08 −0.09 −0.26 −0.28
Pakistan −0.01 0.00 1.98 1.10 0.00 0.00 0.94 0.56
Other South Asia −0.30 −0.31 −3.92 −4.80 −0.23 −0.23 −2.96 −3.71
Central Asia −0.16 −0.23 −0.24 −0.34 −0.07 −0.12 −0.14 −0.20
Pacific Islands −0.81 −0.86 −1.46 −1.58 −0.15 −0.19 −0.96 −1.03
Australia and New Zealand −0.60 −0.64 −1.46 −1.55 −0.25 −0.27 −0.67 −0.70
European Union 0.06 0.07 0.22 0.26 0.05 0.06 0.17 0.19
North America 0.01 0.01 −0.21 −0.29 0.01 0.01 −0.06 −0.08
Rest of world −0.13 −0.17 −0.26 −0.33 −0.04 −0.06 −0.11 −0.14
Source: Authors’ calculations.
The vulnerability of the Asian supply chain 107
by- passes Singapore. Indeed the only significant regional export volume
declines are for the most closely related economies of Indonesia, Malaysia
and the Pacific Islands, as well as for Japan. This picture is little altered
by supply- side rigidity in the form of immobile labor (second column of
results). However, once import sourcing is more tightly constrained (final
two columns), there are some sharp differences, with exports from the
Republic of Korea, India, Pakistan and the EU all turning negative as it
becomes more difficult to change sourcing patterns.
The next blocks of columns in Table 3.6 report the impact of this supply
disruption on the real exchange rate, ToT and real incomes for each
economy across the baseline and alternate rigidity scenarios. These vari-
ables are closely related, and an improvement in any one of them reflects
increased export prices, relative to import costs as trade with the entrepot
becomes more costly and trade flows are diverted from Singapore. Not
surprisingly, the Southeast Asian economies – closely linked to Singapore
are hardest hit by the entrepot shock, with ToT losses, real exchange
rate depreciations and real income losses. In contrast, Japan and the
Republic of Korea gain as their ToT improve. These welfare impacts of
Singapore’s entrepot shock are robust to changes in the supply side of the
economy – for the same reason noted above – namely the shock does not
give a strong incentive to reallocate factors of production across sectors.
However, the macro- economic outcome is extremely sensitive to the trade
elasticities. When sourcing of imports becomes more difficult to change
(inelastic demand), the inability to avoid this entrepot shock by readily
substituting imports from other sources significantly raises the costs for
many of the Southeast Asian economies. The ‘Other South Asia’ region
dominated by Sri Lanka is extremely hard hit under this parameter
setting. Meanwhile, the inelastic demand scenario significantly enhances
the gains of Japan and the Republic of Korea.
6. DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS
In conclusion, we find that the GTAP- SC framework is a useful vehicle
for analyzing the impact of sector and entrepot disruptions on the global
supply chain, and indeed, on the global economy. Unlike the econometric
approaches employed elsewhere in this volume, we are able to fully inves-
tigate the general equilibrium determinants of changes in global trade and
production. And unlike the input–output approaches often used in supply
chain analyses, this CGE framework allows us to explore the implications
of rigidities on both the supply and demand sides for transmission of
localized disasters throughout the global economy.
108 Asia and global production networks
We find that the supply chain impacts of local disasters are rather
robust to labor market rigidities when the external shock affects the entire
economy, as is the case with the entrepot disruption. This is due to the fact
that all sectors are adversely affected, and there is less of an incentive to
dramatically change the employment of labor and capital across sectors.
However, this is not the case when the disaster hits a particular industry,
as is the case when Taipei,China’s ELE sector experiences a 40 percent
reduction in productivity. In this sector- focused, supply chain disruption,
the impact, both on the Taipei,Chinese economy, as well as on the global
economy, hinges critically on the mobility of labor out of the damaged
sector and into other sectors of the affected economy, as well as labor
mobility in the trading partners’ economies.
One of the potentially surprising results from the chapter is that even
a major disruption to a critical world supplier of inputs (Taipei,China’s
electronics industry) has modest effects on incomes elsewhere – especially
under our baseline parameter settings. How does this square with our
notion that disruptions to supply chains create havoc worldwide?
In contrast to supply- side rigidities, the impact of both types of disasters
discussed in this chapter is heavily dependent on individual firms’ abilities
to substitute away from products affected by the supply chain disruption.
When we reduce the associated import sourcing elasticities to one- third
of their baseline values, the consequences of the disaster for the affected
region are invariably much worse. And the scope for terms of trade
changes and the associated real income changes in other regions is magni-
fied. Still, it might seem that for some critical inputs there are no substi-
tutes, at least in the short run. If input supply is disrupted, downstream
firms will simply shut down.
To understand this case in light of our model it is important to think
about the role of aggregation. The use of industry data, rather than firm-
level data on inputs can mask two very different realities at the level of
individual firms. One is the case where firms in a given industry share the
same technology, and require all inputs (from all sources) used in that
industry. Disruptions to a particular input are important to the extent
that the input represents a large cost- share for the industry, and that close
substitutes are difficult to come by.
The other case is where individual firms within the industry are
extremely heterogeneous in their technologies and use of inputs. In
this case, it may be that only a small subset of firms needs any par-
ticular input, but these inputs are absolutely critical to their operation.
Disruption in input supply shuts these firms down entirely, but since
affected firms represent only a small percentage of all firms in the indus-
try, the impact on aggregate sector output is modest. To be clear, the
The vulnerability of the Asian supply chain 109
composition of output changes looks different in this second case. For
example, we might have 90 percent of firms unaffected by the disruption
and 10 percent of firms shutting down; as opposed to all firms reducing
output by 10 percent. But the aggregate effects at the sector level and
indeed the consequences for labor markets and regional income – are the
same in both cases.
Of course, it could be that an input is both critical for every firm, and
that all these firms lack substitutes. Where this is the case, the input would
likely represent a very large share of input costs prior to the shock.
6
By
using the detailed information on input shares by source country in the
pre- shock equilibrium, we are taking into account whether an input is very
important to a lot of firms or not. Since it is rare to find inputs that have
both large cost shares and no substitutes, we believe that it will be unusual
for supply disruptions to have very large aggregate effects.
NOTES
* This chapter has been commissioned as part of the Asian Development Bank study
on Supply Chains in Asia, led by David Hummels and Benno Ferrarini. The authors
would like to thank Ari Van Assche, Anson Soderbery, and Laura Puzzello for valuable
comments on an earlier draft of this work.
1. For example, they find that adverse shocks to human capital result in a decreased growth
rate, with no eventual return to the previous growth trajectory, while loss of physical
capital seems to have no discernible long- term impact on growth.
2. MacKenzie et al. (2013) explore, alternatively, shocks based on output disruption and
shocks based on demand disruption. The former are an order of magnitude more dam-
aging, largely due to the mitigating role of foreign suppliers and inventory adjustment
in the latter. Overall, they conclude that foreigners likely gained from this disruption,
and that a similar disaster in other countries would be even more beneficial to the com-
petition, due to the relatively large share of intermediates sourced domestically in the
Japanese auto industry.
3. In GTAP notation, this is given by ao(ELE, TWN) 5 −40.
4. In GTAP notation, this is given by ats(“Singapore”) 5 −80, and atd(“Singapore”) 5
−80.
5. Of course, where there are significant efficiency gains and losses, these will likely be more
muted under the low mobility/low elasticity scenarios.
6. Imagine a firm that is a monopoly supplier of some input, without which every firm in
Asia shuts down, and for which no substitutes exist. You can be sure that key input is
supplied at very high prices.
REFERENCES
Antras, P. and E. Helpman (2004), ‘Global sourcing’, Journal of Political
Economy, 112, 552–580.
Barry, L. (2005), End of the Line, New York: Doubleday.
110 Asia and global production networks
Francois, J. (1998), ‘Scale economies and imperfect competition in the GTAP
model’, GTAP Technical Paper No. 14, Purdue University, available at: https://
www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/resources/res_display.asp?RecordID5317.
Gallaway, M.P., C.A. McDaniel and S.A. Rivera (2003), ‘Short- run and long- run
industry- level estimates of U.S. Armington elasticities’, The North American
Journal of Economics and Finance, 14, 49–68.
Hertel, T.W. (ed.) (1997), Global Trade Analysis: Modeling and Applications, New
York: Cambridge University Press.
Hertel, T.W. and P. Swaminathan (1996), ‘Introducing monopolistic competition
into the GTAP model’, GTAP Technical Paper No. 6, Purdue University, avail-
able at: https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/resources/res_display.asp?Record
ID5309.
Hertel, T.W., D. Hummels, M. Ivanic and R. Keeney (2007), ‘How confident can
we be in CGE- based analysis of free trade agreements?’, Economic Modelling,
24, 611–635.
Hertel, T.W., R. McDougall, B. Narayanan and A. Aguiar (2009), ‘Behavioral
parameters’, in B. Narayanan and T.L. Walmsley (eds), Global Trade Assistance
and Protection: The GTAP 7 Data Base, Center for Global Trade Analysis,
Purdue University, available at: https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/data-
bases/v7/v7_doco.asp.
Leiter, A.M., H. Oberhofer and P.A. Raschky (2009), ‘Creative disasters?
Flooding effects on capital, labour and productivity within European firms’,
Environmental and Resource Economics, 43, 333–350.
Lin, X. and K.R. Polenske (1998), ‘Input–output modeling of production proc-
esses for business management’, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 9,
205–226.
MacKenzie, C.A., J.R. Santos and K. Barker (2012), ‘Measuring changes in inter-
national production from a disruption: case study of the Japanese earthquake
and tsunami’, International Journal of Production Economics, 138, 293–302.
McDougall, R.A. (1993), ‘Two small extensions to SALTER’, SALTER Working
Paper Series, No. 12, Canberra: Industry Commission.
Narayanan, G., A.A. Badri and R. McDougall (eds) (2012), Global Trade,
Assistance, and Production: The GTAP 8 Data Base, Center for Global Trade
Analysis, Purdue University.
Noy, I. and A. Nualsri (2007), ‘What do exogenous shocks tell us about growth
theories’, SCCIE Working Paper Series, No. 07- 16, Santa Cruz Center for
International Economics, available at: http://sccie.ucsc.edu/.
Okuyama, Y. (2008), ‘Critical review of methodologies on disaster impact estima-
tion’, mimeo, Global Facility for Disaster Risk Reduction, available at: http://
gfdrr.org/sites/gfdrr.org/files/New%20Folder/Okuyama_Critical_Review.pdf.
Reimer, J.J. and T.W. Hertel (2004), ‘Estimation of international demand behavior
for use with input–output based data’, Economic Systems Research, 16, 347–366.
Rose, A. (2013), ‘Macroeconomic consequences of terrorist attacks: estimation for
the analysis of policies and rules’, in V.K. Smith and C. Mansfield (eds), Benefit
Transfer for the Analysis of DHS Rules and Regulations, Cheltenham, UK and
Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar.
Rose, A. and S. Liao (2005), ‘Modeling resilience to disasters: computable general
equilibrium analysis of a water service disruption’, Journal of Regional Science,
45, 75–112.
Rose, A. and D. Wei (2013), ‘Estimating the economic consequences of a port
The vulnerability of the Asian supply chain 111
shutdown: the special role of resilience’, Economic Systems Research, 25,
212–232.
Walmsley, T.L. and C. Carrico (2013), ‘Disaggregating labor payments by skill
level in GTAP’, unpublished manuscript, Center for Global Trade Analysis.
Weingarden, A. and M. Tsigas (2010), ‘Labor statistics for the GTAP database’,
presented at 13th Annual Conference on Global Economic Analysis Papers,
Malaysia, Penang.
112
4. Global supply chains and natural
disasters: implications for
international trade*
Laura Puzzello and Paul Raschky
1. INTRODUCTION
Every once in a while news reports show the disastrous impact of natural
disasters on local communities. In some cases, the losses in terms of
property and lives are so big that economies struggle for months, some-
times years, before bouncing back. Local production is often affected
and so is the transport of local goods to other areas. There are plenty
of examples of such disasters in the 1990s and more recently: the Kobe
Earthquake (Japan, 1995), the 921 earthquake (Taipei,China, 1999),
Hurricanes Katrina and Rita (United States, 2004), the Japanese Great
Tohoku earthquake and tsunami and the Thai floods (2011).
1
Anecdotal
evidence suggests that the distinguishing feature of these recent disasters
is the global scope of their effects. It is not uncommon for firms abroad
to report production delays and profit losses because suppliers in source
countries struck by natural disasters fail to provide parts in time. For
example, the disruptions in the supply chain caused by the Great Tohoku
earthquake and tsunami events in March 2011, not only forced Japanese
car manufacturers to shut down their plants for a short period, but also
resulted in temporary closures of a General Motors truck plant in the
United States (US).
2
However, the question arises whether these global
supply chain effects are just limited to a small group of extreme cases
of disaster events, or are a more systematic feature of (large) natural
disasters.
In this chapter we provide insights into this matter by examining the
effect of disruptions to global supply chains due to natural disasters on
countries’ exports. Our focus is on natural disasters that have a “large”
impact on the local population or economy. These, in fact, are the disasters
whose extent is capable of delaying a country’s production and exports,
and, through supply linkages, of stretching across national borders.
Global supply chains and natural disasters 113
In order to test whether large disasters affect countries’ exports through
input trade, we first construct measures of supply chain vulnerability to
natural disasters. For each country and product, these measures capture
the proportion of inputs provided by suppliers located in countries struck
by at least one large natural disaster in a given year. We use input–output
(IO) structures from the GTAP database and import data from Base pour
l’analyse du commerce international (BACI) to calculate the total amount
of each input, by origin country, used in the production of each good. We
identify which inputs are produced in countries subject to large natural
disasters in any given year using data from the International Disaster
Database (EM- DAT).
Our measures of supply chain vulnerability capture interesting facts.
For instance, we find that manufacturing products tend to have large
shares of inputs exposed to natural disasters abroad, and small input
shares exposed to domestic disasters. This is exactly what one would
expect given the high incidence of input trade in the manufacturing sector.
We also find that Asia and North America are the regions most vulnerable
to large natural disasters both at home and abroad. That is consistent with
the higher incidence of disasters in these regions and the key role they play
in global production.
Our empirical results suggest that higher supply chain vulnerability to
large natural disasters significantly reduces exports. Intuitively, this is
because the production of goods with high supply chain vulnerability is
more likely to be disrupted by large natural disasters. We also find that
the negative effects on a country’s exports of supply chain disruptions are
bigger when large disasters happen at home. These results are robust to the
identification of large disasters and disappear if one focuses on all natural
disasters. We find that earthquakes, tsunamis and storms striking at home
and floods abroad pose the biggest threat to global supply chains and
trade. Our results further imply that more complex industries are relatively
more resilient if supply shocks are due to large disasters hitting home, but
not other supplier countries.
This chapter relates to a recent literature, which examines the effect of
natural disasters on trade. Gassebner et al. (2010) estimate a gravity model
to identify the causal effect on bilateral trade of disasters in either one of
the trading countries. Their findings suggest that large disasters, whether
natural or technological, decrease a country’s exports, but not necessarily
its imports. Countries’ size and level of democracy turn out to be key deter-
minants of the overall effect of disasters on trade. Andrade da Silva and
Cernat (2012), using a gravity approach, find that domestic natural disas-
ters affect most negatively the exports of small developing countries. Jones
and Olken (2010) examine the effect of a country’s weather on exports
114 Asia and global production networks
growth, and find that higher temperatures reduce substantially the growth
of exports for poor countries, but not for rich countries. We add to this
strand of the literature by focusing on the effects on a country’s exports of
large natural disasters occurring both at home and abroad, emphasizing
failures in supply chains as the potential transmission mechanism.
Our chapter also relates to a few studies that account for the interna-
tional transmission of natural disasters through input trade. MacKenzie
et al. (2012) use a multiregional IO model to show that, following the
earthquake and tsunami of 2011 in Japan, the unavailability of Japanese
inputs decreased substantially both domestic and international produc-
tion. Japanese output decreased the most in the transportation and office
equipment industries, which indirectly affected production in many service
and manufacturing sectors. Abroad, the People’s Republic of China (PRC)
suffered, indirectly, the largest output losses. Despite these findings, the
authors conclude that, overall, other economies might have benefitted
from the Japanese disasters, as their production increased to substitute for
Japanese products both in the domestic markets and in Japan. Martin et
al. (2011) analyze the effect on the United Kingdom (UK) manufacturing
firms’ productivity of extreme weather events at home and abroad. They
account for the fact that climate shocks abroad affect firms from both the
supply side, through input trade, and the demand side, through favorable
shifts in foreign consumer demand. They find evidence that importing
from countries experiencing exceptional heat decreases UK firms’ produc-
tivity, while exporting to these destinations increases it. In contrast to both
these studies, we take a global perspective; our focus is on exports and the
transmission of natural disasters’ effects through supply linkages.
The rest of the chapter is organized as follows. Section 2 presents some
facts on natural disasters, and discusses their potential to disrupt global
production and trade. Section 3 presents the estimating equation. Section
4 describes the data and provides details on our measures of supply chain
vulnerability. Section 5 discusses our estimates. Section 6 concludes.
2. NATURAL DISASTERS AND GLOBAL
PRODUCTION: A FIRST LOOK AT THE DATA
In this section we use data from the EM- DAT database, collected by the
Centre for Research on Epidemiology of Disasters (CRED), to describe
the incidence of different types of disasters, and uncover the geographic
distribution of natural disasters, in general, and large- scale natural dis-
asters, in particular. A disaster is recorded in the EM- DAT database if
at least one of the following occurs: (1) it kills at least ten people, (2) it
Global supply chains and natural disasters 115
affects at least 100 people, (3) a state of emergency is declared, or (4) a
call for international assistance is made. Natural disasters included in our
analysis are listed in Table 4.1.
3
For each disaster, the EM- DAT database
reports information on when the disaster happened, how long it lasted for,
the number of people killed, the total number of people affected,
4
and the
total amount of estimated damage in US dollars.
In this section we also verify whether key input suppliers in global pro-
duction tend to be more often subject to natural disasters. Owing to data
availability constraints, our analysis focuses on the period between 1995
and 2010.
2.1 On Natural Disasters
A natural disaster is an unforeseen natural phenomenon such as an earth-
quake, hurricane, or flood that causes extensive damage, destruction of
properties and loss of lives. Between 1995 and 2010 the world experi-
enced 5479 such disasters, which killed more than a million people and
affected the lives of about 3.6 billion people. In the same period, natural
disaster- related monetary losses tallied $1.5 trillion. Panel A in Table 4.1
reports detailed information on the number of people killed and affected,
and the estimated damages related to each of the disaster types included
in our sample. Panel B in Table 4.1 reports similar statistics for large
natural disasters only. In the spirit of Gassebner et al. (2010) we classify a
disaster as large if at least one of the following occurs: (1) it kills at least
1000 people, or (2) it affects at least 100 000 people in total, or (3) it causes
damages worth at least one billion (2005) dollars.
5, 6
A glance at the first column of Table 4.1 reveals that floods and wind-
storms are the most frequent types of disasters and those classified as large
disasters. They are also among the most costly and affect high numbers
of people. The deadliest disasters, not surprisingly, are earthquakes and
tsunamis. A very interesting implication of Table 4.1 is that, even though
large disasters account for only 20 percent of all natural disasters, they
are responsible for the vast majority of lives lost, people affected and eco-
nomic costs due to natural disasters. This reinforces our belief that one is
more likely to find any effect of disasters on a country’s trade by consider-
ing supply chain disruptions caused by large disasters. Hence, from this
point forward our discussion focuses on large natural disasters.
Table 4.2 reports statistics on the incidence and consequences of large
natural disasters by country or region
7
in our sample. The 15 regions most
often struck by large disasters are highlighted in grey. The country that
experienced the highest number of large disasters between 1995 and 2010
is the PRC, which also reports the highest number of people killed and
116 Asia and global production networks
Table 4.1 Incidence and consequences of natural disasters
Disaster type Number Number killed
(’000)
Number
affected
(millions)
Estimated
damages (2005
bn $)
Panel A All natural disasters, 1995–2010
Drought 261 2.17 894.12 38.29
Earthquake 411 493.60 105.67 384.57
Extreme temperature 298 154.64 87.40 50.51
Flood 2 325 129.91 1 980.36 369.98
Insect infestation 23 0.00 0.50 0.27
Mass movement (Dry) 4 0.16 0.00 0.00
Mass movement (Wet) 73 4.56 2.51 1.29
Slides 238 11.67 2.91 2.72
Storm 288 145.76 74.98 105.03
Volcano 88 0.61 1.69 0.21
Wave/Surge 27 230.01 2.53 10.38
Wild fires 211 1.31 1.77 35.69
Wind storm 1 232 74.34 435.43 520.14
Total 5 479 1 248.75 3 589.87 1 519.08
Panel B Large natural disasters, 1995–2010
Drought 154 2.04 892.78 31.53
Earthquake 80 488.98 102.62 373.89
Extreme temperature 33 134.98 86.93 48.92
Flood 431 96.71 1 959.39 321.23
Insect infestation 1 0.00 0.50 0.00
Mass movement (Dry) 0 0.00 0.00 0.00
Mass movement (Wet) 3 1.89 2.29 0.69
Slides 9 2.74 2.46 1.14
Storm 67 143.02 72.85 86.19
Volcano 5 0.53 0.92 0.16
Wave/Surge 6 228.32 2.39 8.15
Wild fires 15 0.57 1.51 30.13
Wind storm 235 60.02 429.49 462.20
Total 1 039 1 159.78 3 554.13 1 364.23
Note: A natural disaster is classified as large if at least one of the following occurs: (1) it
kills at least 1 000 people, or (2) it affects at least 100 000 people, or (3) it causes damages for
at least one billion (real) dollars.
Source: Authors’ calculation using EM- DAT data.
Global supply chains and natural disasters 117
Table 4.2 Regional incidence and consequences of large natural disasters
(1995–2010)
Number Killed
(’000)
Total affected
(millions)
Total damages
(2005 bn $)
Oceania
Australia 11 0.21 1.57 14.48
New Zealand 1 0.00 0.30 5.87
Rest of Oceania 3 2.24 0.77 0.00
Asia
People’s Republic of China 174 115.58 2 044.57 280.36
Hong Kong, China 0 na na na
Japan 15 5.62 1.91 205.00
Korea, Rep. of 3 0.60 0.50 6.59
Rest of East Asia 14 1.05 14.78 30.10
Taipei,China 5 3.02 3.47 18.68
Rest of Southeast Asia 24 139.16 16.74 4.07
Indonesia 21 175.85 11.85 22.06
Sri Lanka 18 35.75 6.71 1.40
Malaysia 2 0.02 0.20 0.05
Philippines 69 10.57 68.90 3.46
Singapore 0 na na na
Thailand 23 9.73 59.08 2.16
Viet Nam 33 8.03 37.30 6.32
Bangladesh 37 5.87 104.32 10.30
India 78 76.03 757.65 32.40
Rest of South Asia 34 90.20 52.33 16.55
North America
Canada 1 0.03 0.00 1.75
United States of America 69 3.40 23.59 397.78
Mexico 19 1.11 8.55 24.00
Rest of North America 0 na na na
South America
Colombia 11 2.22 7.51 3.04
Peru 9 1.87 6.28 0.35
Venezuela 1 30.00 0.48 3.64
Rest of Andean Pact 9 0.22 2.07 1.36
Argentina 4 0.11 1.65 3.20
Brazil 13 0.55 16.26 4.59
Chile 4 0.60 3.14 27.35
Uruguay 1 0.00 0.12 0.04
Rest of South America 6 0.04 1.53 0.53
118 Asia and global production networks
Table 4.2 (continued)
Number
Killed
(’000)
Total affected
(millions)
Total damages
(2005 bn $)
Rest of the Americas
Central America 21 21.40 11.32 10.54
Rest of Free Trade Area of
The Americas and
Caribbean
23
228.52
16.76
34.65
Europe
Austria 1 0.01 0.06 2.22
Belgium and Luxembourg 2 1.18 0.00 1.15
Denmark 2 0.01 0.00 4.30
Finland 0 na na na
France 10 21.10 4.03 29.46
Germany 6 9.41 0.43 19.16
United Kingdom 5 0.03 0.64 16.77
Greece 1 0.14 0.12 4.84
Ireland 0 na na na
Italy 4 20.42 0.14 21.33
Netherlands 2 1.00 0.25 1.45
Portugal 5 2.77 0.15 6.09
Spain 5 15.12 0.00 9.41
Sweden 1 0.01 0.00 2.80
Switzerland 3 1.06 0.00 4.12
Rest of EFTA 0 na na na
Rest of Europe 3 0.00 1.38 0.00
Albania 2 0.01 0.53 0.00
Bulgaria 0 na na na
Croatia 0 na na na
Cyprus 0 na na na
Czech Republic 2 0.05 0.30 2.19
Hungary 0 na na na
Malta 0 na na na
Poland 2 0.07 0.32 6.93
Romania 1 0.02 0.12 0.13
Slovakia 0 na na na
Slovenia 0 na na na
Estonia 0 na na na
Lithuania 0 na na na
Latvia 0 na na na
Russian Federation 11 58.00 2.68 5.35
Rest of Former Soviet Union 16 0.05 17.75 2.23
Global supply chains and natural disasters 119
affected by large natural disasters. Glancing over the table, other countries
highly vulnerable to large natural disasters are in Asia (India, Philippines,
Bangladesh, Viet Nam, Thailand, Indonesia, and Sri Lanka) and in North
America (the US and Mexico). The US records the largest amount of esti-
mated damages, followed by the PRC. In general, countries subject to a
higher number of large disasters report higher numbers of people affected
and estimated damages. The exception in this respect is Africa, where
regions more vulnerable to disasters report higher numbers of people
affected but not necessarily higher damages.
8
Interestingly, the countries we found most vulnerable to large disasters
are among the most active in the international trade of inputs (Baldwin
and Lopez- Gonzales, 2013). To verify whether this correlation holds
Table 4.2 (continued)
Number
Killed
(’000)
Total affected
(millions)
Total damages
(2005 bn $)
Middle East
Turkey 9 18.50 5.42 33.22
Rest of Middle East 14 30.62 41.27 10.12
Africa
Morocco 1 0.00 0.28 1.04
Tunisia 0 na na na
Rest of North Africa 1 2.27 0.21 5.31
South Africa (SA) 3 0.02 15.40 0.01
Malawi 7 0.57 9.75 0.01
Mozambique 17 1.03 10.72 0.55
Tanzania 3 0.00 5.15 0.00
Zambia 7 0.04 6.60 0.02
Zimbabwe 3 0.07 7.95 0.08
Rest of SA Development
Community and Sub-
Saharan Africa
104
5.15
126.51
0.63
Madagascar 13 1.07 5.97 0.38
Uganda 7 0.31 4.05 0.00
Botswana* 1 0.00 0.14 0.01
Rest of SA Custom Unions* 9 0.10 3.59 0.00
Total 1 039 1 160 3 554 1 364
Note: * 5 not included in the empirical analysis as unmatched in the trade data; na 5 not
available.
Source: Authors’ calculation using EM- DAT data.
120 Asia and global production networks
systematically in our data, we construct two measures of each supplier’s
importance in global production, using IO data from the GTAP database.
The first measure we consider is the quantity of each supplier’s inputs
directly used in the production of one unit of world gross output, which
we compute as follows:
World per unit use of j’s inputs 5
a
h
a
i
a
g
B
ji
(
g, h
)
GO
W
(4.1)
Where B
ji
(g, h) is the amount of good g sourced by region j and used to
produce one unit of country i’s output of good h, and GO
W
is the world’s
gross output. This quantity takes on larger values the more a region sup-
plies to large producers in large sectors.
9
The second measure we construct
captures the extent of a supplier’s production network by counting the
average number of destinations using each of that supplier’s inputs.
10
Formally we compute:
Average number of destinations per input of j 5
1
G
a
g
c
a
i
I
(
B
ji
(
g
)
. 0
)
d
(4.2)
where
I
(
B
ji
(
g
)
.
0
)
takes on the value of 1 if region i uses input g from j
in at least one sector, and G is the total number of inputs g. Figures 4.1
and 4.2 plot the quantities in (4.1) and (4.2), against the number of large
natural disasters in the corresponding supplier region. For readability of
the graphs all the quantities are averaged over the period 1995–2010, but
results are similar if each year is considered separately. In both diagrams
the relationship is positive. In other words, international suppliers that are
large and that have more extended production networks tend to experi-
ence a larger number of large natural disasters. This implies that large
natural disasters might pose a real threat to global production and trade
through their disruptive effect on supply chains.
3. EMPIRICAL MODEL
Natural disasters can be thought of as a combination of natural events
and human activity. Worldwide, a large number of human settlements
and production facilities are subject to at least one type of natural hazard
exactly because the location chosen offers benefits to production and
economic activities. For example, the primary sector heavily depends on
access to freshwater for irrigation or direct access to the actual resource
that is harvested (e.g. fisheries). Manufacturing plants are often located in
Global supply chains and natural disasters 121
the proximity of rivers because freshwater is used as an input factor (i.e.,
cooling) and riverine systems are used as a means of inland transport.
Transport in general is a reason why the vast majority of today’s urban
agglomerations are either in coastal areas or next to riverine systems,
making them vulnerable to floods, hurricanes or other climatic hazards.
More specifically, if a large disaster happens domestically, the produc-
tion of exporting firms might be disrupted because of damage to physical
capital and production facilities, or injuries to workers. Even firms whose
production is not directly affected by the disaster might not be able to
export because of the damage to domestic transport infrastructure.
11
Indeed, the destruction of roads or the temporary closure of ports can
cause major export delays. If a large disaster happens abroad, the produc-
tion of domestic exporting firms might be boosted or depressed depending
on whether the foreign shock translates in higher or lower demand for
their own products.
The existing literature on natural disasters and trade has explored the
empirical relevance of these channels using information on the occurrence
ALB
ARG
AUS
AUT
BAN
BGR
BLX
BRA
CAN
CHE
CHL
PRC
COL
CYP
CZE
GER
DEN
SPA
EST
FIN
FRA
UKG
GRC
HKG
HRV
HUN
INO
IND
IRL
ITA
JPN
KOR
SRI
LTU
LVA
MAR
MDG
MEX
MLT MOZ
MWI
MAL
NLD
NZL
PER
PHI
POL
POR
ROU
RUS
SIN
SVK
SVN
SWE
THA
TUN
TUR
TAP
TZA
UGA
URY
USA
VEN
VIE
XAP
XCA
XCB
XEA
XEF
XER
XME
XNA
XNF
XOC
XSA
XSD
XSE
XSM
XSU
ZAF
ZMB
ZWE
0
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.04
0 2 4 6 8 10 12
World per unit use of supplier region's inputs
Number of large natural disasters in supplier region
Average 1995–2010
Source: Authors’ calculations based on EM- DAT and GTAP data.
Figure 4.1 Suppliers’ size and large natural disasters
122 Asia and global production networks
of disasters at home or in partner countries. In contrast, our focus in this
chapter is on determining the effect on exports of disruptions to supply
chains due to large natural disasters. Independent of whether a large dis-
aster happens at home or abroad, the production of a country’s exporting
firms might be disrupted because inputs from domestic or foreign sup-
pliers are received with delay, if at all. This might happen if domestic or
foreign suppliers are located in areas hit by the natural disaster, but also
if their suppliers or their suppliers’ suppliers fail to provide (on time) key
inputs to production due to the disaster.
In order to capture this additional transmission mechanism of disasters
on exports, we construct a measure of supply chain vulnerability, SCV,
which captures for each country, industry and year the share of inputs
directly and indirectly provided by suppliers located in countries hit by
large natural disasters. The intuition behind this measure is that exporters
that source a higher share of their inputs from suppliers located in areas hit
by disasters are more vulnerable and likely to experience production and
exports losses at any given point in time.
Formally, to test the effect of large natural disasters on region i’s
exports of good h, X
ih
, we estimate the following equation:
ALB
ARG
AUS
AUT
BAN
BGR
BLX
BRA
CAN
CHE
CHL
PRC
COL
CYP
CZE
GER
DEN
SPA
EST
FIN
FRA
UKG
GRC
HKG
HRV
HUN
INO
IND
IRL
ITA
JPN
KOR
SRI
LTU
LVA
MAR
MDG
MEX
MLT
MOZ
MWI
MAL
NLD
NZL
PER
PHI
POL
POR
ROU
RUS
SIN
SVK
SVN
SWE
THA
TUN
TUR
TAP
TZA
UGA
URY
USA
VEN
VIE
XAP
XCA
XCB
XEA
XEF
XER
XME
XNA
XNF
XOC
XSA
XSD
XSE
XSM
XSU
ZAF
ZMB
ZWE
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
0 2 4 6 8 10 12
Average number of destinations per input of supplier region
Number of large natural disasters in supplier region
Average 1995–2010
Source: Authors’ calculations based on EM- DAT and GTAP data.
Figure 4.2 Extent of suppliers’ production network and large natural
disasters
Global supply chains and natural disasters 123
ln X
iht
5 b
1
SCV
iht
1 b
2
NLD
it
1 b
3
NLD*
iht
1 b
4
ln GDP
it
1 b
5
ln GDPpc
it
1 b
6
ln Remoteness
it
1 b
7
GATT
it
1 f
h
1 l
t
1 e
iht
(4.3)
where SCV
iht
is a measure of vulnerability to large natural disasters of the
supply chain of good h produced in region i; NLD
it
is the number of large
natural disasters occurred in i at time t;
NLD*
iht
is good h’s output weighted
number of large natural disasters occurred abroad;
12
GDP
it
and GDPpc
it
are i’s GDP and GDP per- capita; Remoteness
it
is the trade- weighted dis-
tance of exporter i to its importers at time t; GATT
it
is a continuous vari-
able that takes values between zero and one depending on the proportion
of countries within a region that are GATT/WTO members at time t;
13
f
h
and
l
t
denote industry fixed effects and time fixed effects.
We are mostly interested in the estimates of
b
1
.
A negative coefficient
indicates that countries with supply chains more vulnerable to large
natural disasters tend to export less. In equation (4.3) we control for the
number of large disasters that occurred at home and abroad to capture
any effect of these events on trade through channels different from supply
chain disruptions. Consistent with the literature, we expect
b
2
to be nega-
tive. The estimates for
b
3
might be positive if exporting firms benefit from
disasters abroad by becoming relatively more competitive in the world
market. But negative estimates for
b
3
are plausible too: if large produc-
ers of good h abroad are affected by natural disasters, their demand for
intra- industry inputs might decrease impacting negatively on country i’s
exports in that sector.
One should be cautious about the estimates of
b
1
from (4.3) as they
might be endogenous if variables correlated with SCV are omitted. For
instance, large exporters might have a lot of domestic and international
experience, which further strengthens their competitiveness. At the same
time, they might be less vulnerable to large disasters if their experience
allows them to better manage their supply chains. Omitting variables
related to the experience of exporters induces a downward bias on
b
1
.
In the same vein, large producers are often also large exporters. If large
producers source relatively more of their inputs domestically, their supply
chains might be systematically more vulnerable to large disasters because
of their higher exposure to domestic natural hazards. In this case, omitting
variables related to the size of exporters induces an upward bias on
b
1
.
In
our empirical analysis we carefully address this endogeneity issue. Reverse
causation does not seem to be a problem in equation (4.3), as large natural
disasters happen unexpectedly along the supply chain.
Our approach differs from that of previous studies on natural disasters
and trade. Gassebner et al. (2010), and Andrade da Silva and Cernat (2012)
124 Asia and global production networks
estimate gravity models to explain the effect on bilateral trade of disasters.
In addition to standard gravity controls, their specifications control for
the incidence of disasters in the exporting country and importing country
separately.
14
Jones and Olken (2010), instead, estimate the effect on the
growth of a country’s disaggregated exports of the temperature and pre-
cipitation in the exporting country. Even though the estimates from these
studies capture the effect on trade of failures in the exporting or import-
ing country’s supply chains once disasters hit the domestic economy, this
effect is not noted or modelled explicitly. More important, past studies
ignore the fact that disasters hitting countries outside a trading pair can
affect that pair’s bilateral trade, as failures anywhere along the supply
chain affect an exporter’s ability to produce.
Before presenting the estimation results, the next section discusses
the data, and provides details on the construction and features of our
measures of supply chain vulnerability.
4. THE DATA
In addition to the data on natural disasters we use trade data for the
period 1995 to 2010 from the BACI World trade database. These data
have been assembled by Gaulier and Zignano (2010) and made avail-
able online through the Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et d’Informations
Internationales (CEPII). The BACI database provides disaggregated
bilateral trade data for more than 200 countries. It increases the informa-
tion available in the COMTRADE database by combining information
reported by exporters and importers, and adjusting import values for
estimated cost, insurance and freight (cif) rates.
Countries’ domestic and import IO structures are taken from four dif-
ferent versions of the GTAP database: versions 5.4, 6, 7 and 8 with base
years 1997, 2001, 2004, and 2007, respectively. Even though these versions
of the database have the same sectoral disaggregation, the regional aggre-
gation differs. We use the regional representation of version 6 to concord
the data.
15
Regional IO coefficients between 1995 and 2000 are based on
GTAP 5.4 for all the regions that have a match in GTAP 6; for the remain-
ing regions we proxy the 1997 IO data with those available in GTAP 6. IO
coefficients for 2001–2003, 2004–2006 and 2007–2010 are based on GTAP
6, 7 and 8, respectively.
The concordance of the BACI data with the GTAP sectoral and
regional classifications leaves us with 44 sectors and 82 regions. A list
of regions and sectors included in our analysis is reported in Appendix
4A.1.
Global supply chains and natural disasters 125
Data for GDP and population are from the World Development
Indicators (WDI). Each region’s trade- weighted distance from its partners
is constructed using bilateral distance measures from the CEPII. GATT
membership data are from the CEPII gravity database.
4.1 Construction of a Measure of Supply Chain Vulnerability
The key variable in our analysis is an index of supply chain vulnerability
(SCV) to natural disasters that is country and industry specific. To con-
struct this index we first combine the GTAP IO tables with import data
from BACI to determine the total amount of each input, by origin region,
used in the production of each good. Using the EM- DAT data, we identify
which inputs are produced in regions subject to large natural disasters at
any given time.
In more detail, from the GTAP IO tables we obtain values for the
amount of each domestic or imported input g directly employed in the
production of one unit of each region i’s good h. Let us denote these
quantities by B
ji
(g, h) if input g 5 1, . . . , G is sourced domestically, and by
B*
i
(g, h) if input g is imported. We then use the proportionality assump-
tion, commonly adopted in the literature, to impute the distribution of
IO import coefficients by source region j 5 1, . . . , N, in any given year.
According to this assumption, if 10 percent of Chinese imports of steel
are from Japan, then 10 percent of any Chinese sector’s use of imported
steel originates from Japan.
16
Formally, the amount of good g sourced by
region j 5 1, . . . , N and used to produce one unit of country i’s output of
good h, B
ji
(g, h), is imputed as follows:
B
ji
(
g, h
)
5
M
ij
(
g
)
M
i
(
g
)
*B*
i
(
g, h
)
with j 2 i and j 5 1, . . . , N (4.4)
where M
ij
(g) denotes the amount of good g region i imports from j,
and M
i
(g) denotes region i’s total imports of g. Let the matrix B be the
(NG 3 NG) world input–output matrix collecting all the possible B
ji
(g,
h).
17
The total amount of input region j’s input g used in i’s production
of h, A
ji
(g, h), is obtained by taking the
ji 2 gh
th
element of the Leontief
inverse
A
5
(
I
2
B
)
2
1
,
where I is the (NG 3 NG) identity matrix.
Combining the elements in matrix A with the EM- DAT data, we con-
struct, for each industry- region pair, the proportion of inputs potentially
subject to large natural disasters at time t,
SCV
iht
,
as follows:
SCV
iht
5
a
N
j5 1
a
G
g5 1
A
jit
(
g, h
)
A
it
(
h
)
* I
jt
(4.5)
126 Asia and global production networks
where
A
it
(
h
)
is the total per unit use of inputs in region
i
’s sector h at time
t, and I
jt
is an indicator variable that takes on the value 1 if country j is
subject to at least one large natural disaster in t.
The index in equation (4.5) can be further decomposed to account, sepa-
rately, for a SCV to large natural disasters that happen at home or abroad.
We define the SCV index to domestic disasters as:
SCV
home
iht
5
a
G
g5 1
A
iit
(
g,h
)
A
it
(
h
)
* I
it
(4.5a)
and the SCV to disasters abroad as:
SCV*
iht
5
a
N
j2 i
a
G
g5 1
A
jit
(
g,h
)
A
it
(
h
)
* I
jt
(4.5b)
Panel A and Panel B of Figure 4.3 plot the distribution for the SCV
indexes defined in (4.5), and (4.5a) and (4.5b), respectively. For legibility
of the graph, the plots of Panel B exclude values of
SCV
home
and
SCV*
equal to zero. Focusing on Panel A, there are two striking features of the
SCV distribution: first, it is bimodal; second, more of its density is concen-
trated at the lower end of the support. A glance at Panel B shows that the
bimodal nature of the SCV distribution is explained by the origin of the
shock to the supply chains. A large domestic natural disaster potentially
compromises the delivery of all domestic inputs used in the production of
any given good. Given that domestic inputs constitute the largest share of
total input purchases in any production process,
SCV
and
SCV
home
take
on large values if a big disaster strikes at home. When the shock is due
to natural disasters happening abroad a smaller share of total inputs is
affected, so
SCV
and
SCV*
take on small values. The higher concentra-
tion of the
SCV
distribution at the lower end of the support indicates that
most often the origin of (potential) shocks to supply chains is foreign. This
is further confirmed by the fact that
SCV
home
equals 0 in 67 percent of all
possible 57 728 (44 3 82 3 16) industry- region- year combinations.
In order to explore the vulnerability of different sectors to large natural
disasters, Figure 4.4 shows the
SCV
index distribution by aggregate
product categories, with the 44 original sectors included in one of the
following four categories: Food products, Manufacturing, Energy and
Raw agriculture.
18
The SCV distributions are bimodal in each product
category. Most interestingly, relative to the SCV distributions of other
sectors, the manufacturing one is shifted to the right at the lower end of
the support and to the left at the upper end of the support. This tells us
that in the manufacturing sector, regions have a larger share of inputs
that is exposed to natural disasters happening abroad. At the same time,
Global supply chains and natural disasters 127
Panel A) Distribution of the SCV index defined in equation (4.5).
0
2
4
6
Density
0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0
Value of supply chain vulnerability index
Large natural disasters
Panel B) Distribution of the SCV index defined in equation (4.5a, left panel) and equation (4.5b)
0
1
2
3
4
5
Density
0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0
Value of supply chain vulnerability index
Large domestic natural disasters
0
2
4
6
8
Density
0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6
Value of supply chain vulnerability index
Large natural disasters abroad
Note: In panel B, values of SCV
home
and SCV* equal to zero have been dropped for
legibility of the plots.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on EM- DAT and GTAP data.
Figure 4.3 Distribution of SCV indexes
128 Asia and global production networks
a lower percentage of their inputs is exposed to domestic disasters. Both
findings are consistent with the higher incidence of global supply chains in
manufacturing.
To explore the vulnerability of different regions to large natural dis-
asters, Figure 4.5 shows the SCV index distribution by aggregate geo-
graphic areas, with the 82 original regions included in one of the following
six areas: Oceania, Asia, North America, Other Americas, Africa and
Middle East, and Europe.
19
The SCV distributions are bimodal in each
geographic group. Europe stands out as having the most concentrated
SCV density at the lower end of the support and the least concentrated
at the upper end of the support. In other words, Europe is mostly vulner-
able to disasters happening abroad. This is consistent with our findings in
Table 4.2, which show countries in Europe were not struck by many large
disasters during the sample period. Asia and North America, instead, are
characterized by the highest values of the SCV density in the upper end
of the support. This is consistent with the fact that many regions in Asia
and North America received a high number of large disasters during the
sample period. Interestingly, at the lower end of the support, the prob-
ability of SCV taking on relatively high values, between 0.2 and 0.5, is the
0
1
2
3
Density supply chain vulnerability index
0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0
Value of supply chain vulnerability index
Food products Manufacturing
Energy Raw agriculture
Note: Each industry- region observation is weighted by the corresponding export share
in industry exports. The list of sectors included in each product category is reported in
Appendix 4A.1.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on EM- DAT and GTAP data.
Figure 4.4 Distribution of the SCV index by aggregate product categories
Global supply chains and natural disasters 129
highest in Asia and North America. Put another way, countries in Asia
and North America are quite vulnerable to large disasters abroad as well.
This is not surprising given that many of them are extensively involved in
global production networks.
20
5. ESTIMATION RESULTS
5.1 Supply Chain Vulnerability and Exports
Table 4.3 reports the estimation results for equation (4.3). We report
robust standard errors in parentheses, and standard errors clustered at the
region- industry level in square brackets. The significance of our estimates
is not affected by the residuals variance structure unless noted.
Focusing on Column (1) of Table 4.3, the estimates for the country-
specific control variables are as expected when significant. Economically
bigger and less remote regions tend to export more. However, a region’s
income per capita and its GATT membership status do not significantly
affect its exports. The estimates for the weighted average number of
disasters abroad,
NLD*,
imply that a region’s exports in a given sector
0
2
4
6
8
Density supply chain vulnerability index
0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0
Value of supply chain vulnerability index
Oceania Asia
North America Other Americas
Africa and Middle East Europe
Note: Each industry- region observation is weighted by the corresponding export share
in industry exports. The list of regions included in each geographical area is reported in
Appendix 4A.1.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on EM- DAT and GTAP data.
Figure 4.5 Distribution of the SCV index by aggregate geographic areas
130 Asia and global production networks
decrease with the average number of large natural disasters experienced
by other producers abroad. In other words, the benefits of weaker inter-
national competition are more than compensated by the loss of foreign
intra- industry demand for domestic inputs. In contrast to the literature,
the estimates for the number of large disasters at home, NLD, suggest that
thegreater the number of large natural disasters a country experiences, the
higher its exports are. Consistent with our intuition, instead, the estimated
coefficient for SCV is negative and significant, implying that the higher is
the vulnerability of a supply chain to large natural disasters, the lower the
corresponding exports.
To ensure that our estimates on SCV are not biased due to the omission
of variables related to the experience and size of exporters, in Column (2)
of Table 4.3 we add as control variables lagged values of the exporter’s
share in world trade and its size. Our estimate of the SCV coefficient is
only slightly affected. This is not surprising if one considers that large
exporters are big and potentially more experienced. While more experi-
ence allows exporters to improve their supply chain management, their
size makes them rely relatively more on domestic inputs increasing their
vulnerability to (domestic) natural disasters. These biasing effects almost
cancel each other out. Interestingly, controlling for the exporter’s share
and size changes substantially all the other coefficients. While the mag-
nitude of the GDP estimate shrinks, it turns out that richer regions and
members of the GATT do export significantly more. The puzzling posi-
tive coefficient on NLD shown in Column (1) decreases in magnitude and
becomes insignificant in Column (2). This finding put together with the
fact that the estimate on SCV is not affected by the additional controls
suggests that the main channel through which domestic disasters affect
trade is through failures of producers’ supply chains. The coefficient of
NLD*
switches sign in Column (2), implying that the benefits of weaker
foreign competition do, in fact, more than make up for the loss of foreign
intra- industry demand for domestic inputs.
In Column (3) of Table 4.3 we control for annual changes in the trade
weighted GDP of importers to ensure that the negative estimated effect
of SCV on exports is not driven by changes in the demand for domestic
goods from countries affected by large disasters. Our estimated effect of
SCV on exports is robust to this addition.
In order to make sure our estimated effect of SCV on exports is not
affected by any omitted region- time specific effect, we estimate a modified
specification of equation (4.3) where all the region- time specific variables
are replaced by region- time fixed effects. The last column of Table 4.3
shows our results. The size of the SCV coefficient increases in absolute
value, implying that one standard deviation increase in SCV decreases
Global supply chains and natural disasters 131
Table 4.3 Large natural disasters and exports
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Supply chain
vulnerability to large
disasters: SCV
iht
−0.1333***
(0.0326)
[0.0575]**
−0.1392***
(0.0277)
[0.0454]***
–0.1403***
(0.0278)
[0.0454]***
−0.6051***
(0.1731)
[0.2301]***
Number of large natural
disasters at origin o:
NLD
it
0.0329***
(0.0060)
[0.0159]**
0.0013
(0.0052)
[0.0128]
0.0014
(0.0052)
[0.0128]
Gross output weighted
average number of large
natural disasters abroad:
NLD*
iht
−0.1127***
(0.0177)
[0.0165]***
0.0773***
(0.0163)
[0.0192]***
0.0776***
(0.0163)
[0.0193]***
0.0358**
(0.0177)
[0.0168]**
Income:
GDP
it
0.9323***
(0.0074)
[0.0244]***
0.2676***
(0.0099)
[0.0295]***
0.2677***
(0.0099)
[0.0295]***
Income per capita:
GDPpc
it
0.0076
(0.0100)
[0.0334]
0.1504***
(0.0093)
[0.0283]
0.1509***
(0.0093)
[0.0282]***
Log trade
weighted distance:
ln
(
Remoteness
)
it
−0.4473***
(0.0166)
[0.0567]***
−0.4017***
(0.0146)
[0.0457]***
−0.4015***
(0.0146)
[0.0457]***
GATT membership:
GATT
it
−0.0375
(0.0317)
[0.1029]
0.2144***
(0.0281)
[0.0838]**
0.2139***
(0.0281)
[0.0838]**
Lag export share: (
X
X
h
ih
)
t21
19.6374***
(0.5439)
[1.7828]***
19.6330***
(0.5439)
[1.7827]***
19.6111***
(0.8409)
[1.9336]***
Lag gross output:
GO
ih,t
2
1
0.4841***
(0.0074)
[0.0202]***
0.4844***
(0.0074)
[0.0202]***
0.4896***
(0.0100)
[0.0200]***
Change in weighted
income of importers: D
DWGDP
importers
it
−0.2249**
(0.0994)
[0.0715]***
Industry fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes No
Exporter- year fixed
effects
No No No Yes
R- squared 0.6494 0.7558 0.7558 0.7100
N 54 663 51 288 51 288 51 288
Note: Dependent variable is the log of country i’s exports of good h at time t:
ln
(
X
iht
)
.
Robust standard errors are in parentheses. Standard errors clustered by country- industry
are in square brackets. *** Significant at the 1% level; ** significant at the 5% level; *
significant at the 10% level.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from the following databases: BACI, EM-
DAT, GTAP, WDI and CEPII gravity.
132 Asia and global production networks
exports by 21 percent. This is our preferred specification, which we refer
to as baseline specification henceforth.
Table 4.4 reports the baseline results in Column (1). Column (2) of
Table 4.4 displays the estimation results for the baseline specification with
SCV split in SCV
home
and SCV*. This allows us to explore how sensitive
exports are to supply chain disruptions due to large natural disasters at
home and abroad, separately. We now find that, independent of the origin
of disasters, higher supply chain vulnerability lowers exports. Specifically,
we find that while a one standard deviation increase in SCV
home
decreases
exports by about 24 percent, a one standard deviation increase in SCV*
decreases exports by 4 percent. However, the latter estimate loses signifi-
cance once standard errors are clustered at the region- industry level.
In sum, disruptions to supply chains due to large natural disasters
decrease a country’s exports, more so if these disasters strike at home.
21
5.2 Impact of Natural Disasters, Supply Chain Vulnerability and Exports
Our focus so far has been on large natural disasters, as we believe not
all natural disasters affect a country’s production facilities or transport
infrastructures to an extent capable of delaying production and affecting
exports. To test this belief, we construct the SCV measures focusing on all
natural disasters instead of on large natural disasters only. Columns (3)
and (4) of Table 4.4 show how once we use these modified SCV measures
supply chain vulnerability does not matter for trade.
One can argue that we fail to find any effect of SCV to all natural disas-
ters, as we do not account for the impact of each disaster. We address this
concern by constructing an alternative measure of vulnerability, WSCI,
where we weight each input exposed to a natural disaster by a measure of
that disaster’s impact as follows:
WSCI
iht
5
a
N
j5 1
a
G
g5 1
A
jit
(
g,h
)
A
it
(
h
)
* Impact
jt
with Impact
jt
being the simple average of the economic loss in GDP terms
and the percentage of population affected associated to disasters hitting
supplier j at time t.
22
We refer to this measure as supply chain weighted
impact of all disasters, and we report results for our baseline specifications
where we replace SCV with WSCI in Columns (5) and (6) of Table 4.4. Our
estimates suggest that higher values for the supply chain weighted impact
of natural disasters correspond to lower exports. In particular, one stand-
ard deviation increase in the supply chain weighted impact of all disasters,
of all domestic disasters and of all disasters abroad decreases exports
133
Table 4.4 Impact of natural disasters and exports
Large
disasters
Large
disasters
All
disasters
All
disasters
Large
disasters
Large
disasters
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Supply chain
vulnerability to
disasters: SCV
iht
−0.6051***
(0.1731)
[0.2301]***
−0.0290
(0.2139)
[0.3018]
−0.5192***
(0.1823)
[0.2365]**
−0.5161***
(0.1826)
[0.2359]**
Supply chain
vulnerability to
domestic disasters:
SCV
home
iht
−0.7098***
(0.2023)
[0.2827]**
−0.0819
(0.2263)
[0.3077]
Supply chain
vulnerability to
disasters abroad:
SCV*
iht
−0.4587**
(0.1998)
[0.3424]
−0.2526
(0.2211)
[0.3590]
Supply chain weighted
impact of all
disasters: WSCI
iht
−9.0718**
(3.8231)
[3.5805]**
−4.8020
(4.0172)
[3.5028]
Supply chain weighted
impact of all
domestic disasters:
WSCI
home
iht
−8.2556*
(4.2753)
[4.5488]*
−4.2366
(4.4371)
[4.5073]
134
Table 4.4 (continued)
Large
disasters
Large
disasters
All
disasters
All
disasters
Large
disasters
Large
disasters
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Supply chain weighted
impact of all disasters
abroad:
WSCI*
iht
−11.7993*
(6.0889)
[8.6744]
−6.8017
(6.2599)
[8.5676]
Industry fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Exporter- year fixed
effects
Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Other Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 51 288 51 288 51 288 51 288 51 288 51 288 51 288 51 288
R- squared 0.7100 0.7098 0.7076 0.7081 0.7099 0.7099 0.7110 0.7109
Note: Dependent variable is the log of country i’s exports of good h at time t:
ln
(
X
iht
)
.
The heading of each column refers to the disasters
considered in calculating SCV for the relevant specification. All specifications include the following ‘Other Controls’:
(
X
ih
/X
h
)
t2 1
,GO
ih,t2 1
,
and
NLD*
iht
.
Robust standard errors are in parentheses. Standard errors clustered by country- industry are in square brackets. *** Significant at the 1%
level; ** significant at the 5% level; * significant at the 10% level.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from the following databases: BACI, EM- DAT and GTAP.
Global supply chains and natural disasters 135
by 17.0 percent, 21.0 percent and 2.6 percent, respectively. However, as
shown in the last two columns of Table 4.4, these results lose significance
as soon as we control for our original SCV measure, where only large dis-
asters are considered. Put another way, not all natural disasters pose a real
threat to global production and trade, but the large ones do.
Our SCV measures critically depend on the identification of large dis-
asters. To this point we have identified large natural disasters based on
non- normalized measures of impact. We do so following Gassebner et
al. (2010), but recognize that the numbers of people affected or amount
of damages have different implications for small and large countries or
economies. So, in Table 4.5, we report estimates for our baseline specifica-
tions when the large disasters underlying our calculations are identified
based on normalized measures of impact.
In Columns (3)–(4) of Table 4.5, we classify a disaster as large if at least
one of the following occurs: (a) the number of people killed as a percentage
of the population falls in the top 1 percent of the relevant empirical distri-
bution; (b) the number of people affected as a percentage of the popula-
tion falls in the top 10 percent of the relevant empirical distribution; (c)
the economic damages as a percentage of GDP fall in the top decile of the
damage to GDP distribution. Because data on economic damage are only
available in a limited number of cases, in Columns (5)–(6) and (7)–(8) of
Table 4.5 we define a disaster as large if it meets any of the conditions in
(a) and (b), or if it generates economic damage as a percentage of GDP
that falls in the top quintile and the top 5 percent of the damage to GDP
distribution, respectively.
23
Our estimates on the effect of SCV on exports are robust to the alterna-
tive definitions even though they tend to become smaller and weaker.
24
Across Table 4.5, a one standard deviation increase in SCV is estimated
to decrease exports by between 13 percent and 17 percent. A one standard
deviation in the supply chain vulnerability to large domestic disasters and
to large disasters abroad decreases exports by between 15 and 24 percent,
and 0 and 4 percent, respectively. If one considers that when a large dis-
aster hits home, on average about 80 percent of all input purchases are
affected, our estimates imply decreases in exports by between 27 percent
and 43 percent.
In conclusion, large disasters, independent of how we define them, are
detrimental to a country’s trade, especially when they strike at home.
5.3 Supply Chain Vulnerability and Exports: Additional Results
The effect of a natural disaster on a country’s exports through supply link-
ages might vary depending on the number of inputs used in the production
136
Table 4.5 Large natural disasters and exports: robustness to alternative definitions of large disasters
Baseline Bin 1 Bin 2 Bin 3
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Supply chain vulnerability
to large disasters: SCV
iht
−0.6051***
(0.1731)
[0.2301]***
−0.3409*
(0.1743)
[0.1762]*
−0.3739**
(0.1671)
[0.1964]*
−0.4998***
(0.1875)
[0.2145]**
Supply chain vulnerability
to domestic large
disasters:
SCV
home
iht
−0.7098***
(0.2023)
[0.2827]**
−0.3929**
(0.1851)
[0.2151]*
−0.4993***
(0.1824)
[0.2174]**
−0.4769**
(0.1995)
[0.2542]*
Supply chain vulnerability
to large disasters abroad:
SCV*
iht
−0.4587**
(0.1998)
[0.3424]
−0.2146
(0.2246)
[0.3265]
−0.1866
(0.1897)
[0.3101]
−0.5781**
(0.2611)
[0.3866]
Industry fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Exporter- year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Other Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 51 288 51 288 51 288 51 288 51 288 51 288 51 288 51 288
R- squared 0.7100 0.7098 0.7092 0.7094 0.7066 0.7064 0.7108 0.7106
Note: Dependent variable is the log of country i’s exports of good h at time t:
ln
(
X
iht
)
.
All specifications include the following ‘Other Controls’:
(
X
ih
/X
h
)
t
2
1
,GO
ih,t
2
1
,
and
NLD*
iht
.
In Bin 1, a natural disaster is classified as large if it causes damages as a percentage of GDP in the top decile of the
damage to GDP distribution, or the number of people killed as a percentage of the population falls in the top 1 percent of the relevant empirical
distribution, or the number of people affected as a percentage of the population falls in the top decile of the relevant empirical distribution. The
conditions for a disaster to be considered large in Bin 2 and 3 are the same as in Bin 1 except that it must cause damage as a percentage of GDP
in the top quintile and top 5 percent of the damage to GDP distribution, respectively. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. Standard errors
clustered by country- industry are in square brackets. *** Significant at the 1% level; ** significant at the 5% level; * significant at the 10% level.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from the following databases: BACI, EM- DAT and GTAP.
Global supply chains and natural disasters 137
of the goods being traded, i.e., on goods’ complexity. As the number of
inputs used in production goes up, the higher are the chances of at least
a supplier’s failure. However, depending on whether inputs are comple-
ments or substitutes the same supplier’s failure has, respectively, a large or
a small impact on production and trade.
To explore whether more complex goods are more or less vulnerable
to large disasters, we augment our baseline specifications with both a
measure of complexity that is region and industry specific, and its interac-
tion with our measures of supply chain vulnerability to large disasters. We
calculate complexity in two ways using the GTAP IO data. First, we count
the number of distinct inputs used in production of each good. Higher
numbers correspond to more complex goods. Second, we construct the
Herfindahl- Hirschman Index (HHI) of input purchases for each exported
good. In this case, higher numbers imply more concentrated input pur-
chases and lower complexity. Columns (1)–(2) and (3)–(4) in Table 4.6
display our estimates when the count of inputs and the HHI are used as a
measure of complexity, respectively.
The estimates on the interaction term in Columns (1) and (3) suggest
that exports of more complex goods are less vulnerable to large natural
disasters. This is consistent with recent literature, which supports that
more complex production chains cope better with shocks and their
production is less volatile (Koren and Tenreyro, 2013; Krishna and
Levchenko, forthcoming).
In Columns (2) and (4), we explore whether the effect of the interac-
tion between a good’s complexity and its vulnerability to large disasters
depends on whether a disaster happens at home or abroad. The estimates
in Column (4) are the most robust and imply that exports of more complex
goods are less vulnerable to large natural disasters at home, but more
vulnerable to natural disasters abroad. These findings imply that domesti-
cally sourced inputs are relatively easy to substitute but imported inputs
are not.
The last set of results, in Table 4.7, explores a supply chain’s vulnerabil-
ity to large disasters by the category of the disaster. We distinguish two
main categories of disasters: geological and climatic. The former includes:
earthquakes, mass movements (wet and dry), slides, volcano eruptions
and tsunamis. The latter consists of: floods, storms, droughts, wild fires
and extreme temperature.
The results in Column (1) of Table 4.7 suggest that large disasters of
climatic origin do threaten global production chains and trade. To explore
further the effect of climatic disasters on exports through supply linkages,
in Column (2) we analyze the effect of SCV to large floods and storms,
separately. According to our estimates a one standard deviation increase
138 Asia and global production networks
Table 4.6 Large natural disasters, exports and complexity
Count
distinct
inputs
Count
distinct
inputs
HHI of input
purchases
HHI of
input
purchases
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Supply chain
vulnerability to large
disasters: SCV
iht
−1.2491***
0.4352
[0.5192]**
−0.4880***
(0.1695)
[0.2429]**
Supply chain
vulnerability to
domestic large
disasters:
SCV
home
iht
−1.2776***
(0.4631)
[0.5844]**
−0.6233***
(0.1951)
[0.2853]**
Supply chain
vulnerability to large
disasters abroad:
SCV*
iht
−3.6057***
(1.3147)
[2.1726]*
−2.0745***
(0.3441)
[0.6454]***
Complexity: Compl
iht
−0.0137***
(0.0046)
[0.0169]*
−0.0210***
(0.0059)
[0.0094]**
0.2757***
(0.0712)
[0.1507]*
−0.0277
(0.0861)
[0.1839]
Interaction SCV
with Complexity:
SCV
iht
*Compl
iht
0.0153*
(0.0089)
[0.0105]
−0.4084***
(0.1223)
[0.2259]*
Interaction
SCV
home
with Complexity:
SCV
home
iht
*Compl
iht
0.0129
(0.0091)
[0.0112]
−0.4916***
(0.1255)
[0.2296]**
Interaction SCV*
with Complexity:
SCV*
iht
*
Compl
iht
0.0791**
(0.0318)
[0.0528]
2.8226***
(0.5233)
[1.0179]***
Industry fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes
Exporter- year fixed
effects
Yes Yes Yes Yes
Other controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 51 288 51 288 51 288 51 288
R- squared 0.7098 0.7096 0.7099 0.7094
Note: Dependent variable is the log of country i’s exports of good h at time t:
ln
(
X
iht
)
.
The heading of each column refers to the measure of complexity considered in the relevant
specification. All specifications include the following ‘Other Controls’:
(
X
ih
/X
h
)
t
2
1
,GO
ih,t
2
1
,
and
NLD*
iht
.
Robust standard errors are in parentheses. Standard errors clustered by
country- industry are in square brackets. *** Significant at the 1% level; ** significant at the
5% level; * significant at the 10% level.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from the following databases: BACI, EM-
DAT and GTAP.
Global supply chains and natural disasters 139
in a SCV to floods and storms decreases exports by 12 percent and 20
percent, respectively.
Finally, the last two columns of Table 4.7 display the estimated effect on
exports of a supply chain’s vulnerability to large disasters striking at home
and abroad, separately, by disasters category. Higher supply chain vulner-
ability to both large geological disasters and storms hitting home leads to
lower exports, while only higher supply chain vulnerability to large floods
abroad lowers export.
Table 4.7 Types of large natural disasters and exports
(1) (2) (3) (4)
SCV to large geo
disasters:
SCVgeo
iht
−0.4513
(0.3149)
[0.3534]
−0.3155
(0.3231)
[0.3471]
SCV to large climatic
disasters: SCVclim
iht
−0.4861***
(0.1759)
[0.2258]**
SCV to large floods:
SCVflood
iht
−0.3942*
(0.2042)
[0.2611]
SCV to large storms:
SCVstorm
iht
−0.7456***
(0.2486)
[0.3215]**
SCV to domestic large
geo disasters:
SCVgeo
home
iht
−1.1129**
(0.4404)
[0.3976]***
−1.0028**
(0.4255)
[0.3952]**
SCV to large geo
disasters abroad:
SCVgeo*
iht
0.2257
(0.4121)
[0.4919]
0.1695
(0.4202)
[0.4653]
SCV to domestic large
climatic disasters:
SCVclim
home
iht
−0.5147**
(0.2101)
[0.2864]*
SCV to domestic large
floods:
SCVflood
home
iht
−0.1780
(0.2442)
[0.3320]
SCV to domestic large
storms:
SCVstorm
home
iht
−1.5375***
(0.3134)
[0.4230]***
SCV to large climatic
disasters abroad:
SCVclim*
iht
−0.4617**
(0.2106)
[0.3325]
SCV to large floods
abroad:
SCVflood*
iht
−1.0301***
(0.2995)
[0.4270]**
140 Asia and global production networks
6. CONCLUSIONS
This chapter estimates the effect of large natural disasters on countries’
exports, emphasizing failures in supply chains as the potential transmis-
sion mechanism. We construct supply chain vulnerability measures that
capture, for each country, industry and year, the share of inputs pro-
vided by suppliers located in countries hit by large natural disasters. We
find robust evidence that higher levels of SCV imply significantly lower
exports, especially so when large disasters happen at home. Domestic large
disasters that affect a country’s supply chains and its trade include earth-
quakes, tsunamis and storms. Foreign large disasters that pose the biggest
threat to global supply chains and trade include floods.
Our findings are problematic given that countries that are subject to
large disasters frequently include the PRC, the US, India and other Asian
countries, which are key players in global production networks. On a
brighter note, our results also suggest that not all natural disasters pose a
threat to international trade, but the large ones do.
We find evidence that more complex industries are more resilient
to supply chain shocks due to large disasters at home but not abroad.
Recent studies show that developing countries tend to specialize in low-
complexity, high- volatility goods. Thus, our results imply that large
Table 4.7 (continued)
(1) (2) (3) (4)
SCV to large storms
abroad:
SCVstorm*
iht
0.4472
(0.3199)
[0.4898]
Industry fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes
Exporter- year fixed
effects
Yes Yes Yes Yes
Other controls Yes Yes Yes Yes
N 51 288 51 288 51 288 51 288
R- squared 0.7094 0.7071 0.7058 0.6958
Note: Dependent variable is the log of country i’s exports of good h at time t:
ln
(
X
iht
)
.
All specifications include the following ‘Other Controls’:
(
X
ih
/X
h
)
t
2
1
,GO
ih,t
2
1
,
and
NLD*
iht
.
Robust standard errors are in parentheses. Standard errors clustered by country- industry
are in square brackets. *** Significant at the 1% level; ** significant at the 5% level;
*significant at the 10% level.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from the following databases: BACI, EM-
DAT and GTAP.
Global supply chains and natural disasters 141
domestic natural disasters contribute to the higher volatility of production
in developing countries through disruptions of supply chains. Importing
inputs might increase volatility further if international suppliers are
located in regions vulnerable to disasters.
On the one hand, direct disaster damage to physical assets, infra-
structure and human lives could be reduced by increased investment in
appropriate protective measures (i.e., dikes). However, due to diminishing
returns to investment in protection against natural disasters, technological
constraints and limited public funds, it is very often not feasible to provide
protection against certain types of large- scale disasters for all exposed pro-
duction facilities, infrastructure and people. On the other hand, financial
risk- transfer (i.e., insurance) can compensate for the financial damages
to physical assets and infrastructure. While financial risk- transfer pro-
vides necessary liquidity for rebuilding and repairing damaged assets,
it cannot prevent the actual destruction of production facilities and the
resulting disruptions in the supply chain. At its best, it can speed up the
recovery period and decrease the length of the supply chain disruptions.
Considering the limited potential of traditional risk- management methods
to mitigate supply chain effects of natural disasters, an alternative could be
a greater geographical diversification of suppliers, multiple sourcing and
changes in stock- management.
NOTES
* We would like to thank David Hummels, Benno Ferrarini, Pedro Gomis- Porqueras,
and participants of the ADB Global Supply Chain Conference for helpful comments
and suggestions.
1. See Sherin and Bartoletti (2000) and Kumins and Bamberger (2005) for discussions
related to the disruptive effects of the Taipei,China 921 earthquake, and hurricanes
Katrina and Rita, respectively.
2. See ‘Lacking parts, G.M. will close plant’, New York Times, 17 March 2011.
3. The database records both natural and technological disasters. Technological disasters
include industrial, transport and miscellaneous accidents. Our data cover technological
disasters only between 1995 and 2007, so we exclude them from our analysis. We believe
this does not affect our results for two main reasons. First, the correlation between the
number of natural disasters and the number of technological disasters at the regional
level is very high (0.85). Second, even though between 1995 and 2007 there were 3716
technological disasters, only 12 of them were large. Following Gassebner et al. (2010)
we also exclude epidemics from our analysis. In contrast with the rest of the disasters
we consider, the extent of epidemics can be contained as people avoid contact.
4. The total number of affected people include those people injured in the disaster and
medically treated, people needing assistance for shelter/homeless, and people requiring
immediate assistance during the period of emergency (these include people displaced or
evacuated).
5. Because our definition of large natural disasters uses multiple criteria, we are able
to identify large- scale disasters happening both in developed countries (where the
142 Asia and global production networks
economic damage is high) and developing countries (where the economic damage is not
as high, if reported at all, but where many lives are affected or lost).
6. We choose this definition of large disasters following the related literature. In Section
5.2 we discuss alternative definitions of large disasters, which take into consideration
normalized measures of a disaster’s impact.
7. We use the term country and region interchangeably in the text, as our sample consists
of both single countries and aggregated regions. See Appendix 4A.1 for details on the
regional aggregation.
8. This is mostly explained by missing data for estimated damages in Africa.
9. This is evident if one notes that
a
h
a
i
a
g
B
ji
(
g,h
)
GO
W
5
a
h
a
i
GO
W
(
h
)
GO
W
GO
i
(
h
)
GO
W
(
h
)
B
ji
(
h
)
GO
i
(
h
)
,
where
GO
i
(
h
)
is country i’s output in sector h. Calculating (4.1) using total instead of
direct input uses does not affect the results, which are available upon request to the
authors.
10. One could also compute the average number of distinct region- industry pairs using each
of a supplier’s inputs. However, because, as detailed in section 4, we use the proportion-
ality assumption to split import IO structures by source country, calculating that would
not provide additional insights.
11. Disentangling the impact of disasters on supply chains into the effect of destroyed
production capacity and destroyed transport infrastructure is difficult because of data
limitations. With the exception of a few well- studied cases, data collections of natural
disaster events, if at all, only contain estimates about the total damage, but do not dis-
tinguish between damage to plants and infrastructure.
12. Technically,
NLD*
iht
is given by:
a
j
2
i
GO
j
(
h
)
GO
W
(
h
)
*
(
NLD
jt
)
, where
GO
j
(
h
)
and
GO
W
(
h
)
are
region j and the world gross output of good h, and
NLD
ji
is the number of large disasters
occurred in j at time t.
13. At the country level GATT
it
can only take values zero and one.
14. Gassebner et al. (2010) use the number of disasters in the exporting and the importing
country, separately, as controls. In their preferred specifications both measures are
normalized by the relevant country’s land area. Andrade da Silva and Cernat (2012)
control for the occurrence of specific natural disasters in the exporting country only
using a dummy variable.
15. There are two reasons why we do not use the regional aggregation of version 5.4. First,
France and the US would be included in an aggregate ‘Rest of the World’ (ROW).
Second, Asia has a better country disaggregation in GTAP version 6. Given the impor-
tance of France and the US in world trade, and the incidence of disasters and produc-
tion networks in Asia we believe that the regional disaggregation in GTAP version 6
improves our identification.
16. See Winkler and Milberg (2009), Puzzello (2012), and Feenstra and Jensen (2012) for
assessments of the proportionality assumption.
17. The elements of the world matrix B are important for three interrelated strands of the
literature. The first calculates the factor content of trade in the presence of interna-
tional differences in production techniques and trade in inputs (Reimer, 2006; Trefler
and Zhu, 2010; Puzzello, 2012). The second aims to quantify the extent of global
production networks and their effect on an economy’s wage structure (Hummels et al.
2001; Feenstra and Hanson, 1996, 1999). The third examines the value added content
of trade, which depends on a country’s participation in global production chains, and
direct and indirect absorption of domestic output (Johnson and Noguera, 2012).
18. Appendix 4A.1 lists the sectors included in each of the four product categories.
19. Appendix 4A.1 lists the regions included in each of the six geographical areas.
20. Changes in the SCV index over time can occur because of changes in either the input use
or the incidence of large natural disasters across supplier regions. Empirically, changes
Global supply chains and natural disasters 143
in SCV turn out to be explained mostly by changes in the incidence of disasters across
supplier regions between years. If in two consecutive years a country is either hit or not
hit by a large disaster changes in SCV are explained almost completely by changes in
the incidence of disasters in foreign suppliers’ countries. In all other cases, big switches
in our SCV measure are observed and depend almost entirely on the change in the inci-
dence of disasters at home.
21. Any particular exporter or year does not drive these results. Estimates for the baseline
specifications when observations for either an exporter or a year are dropped are avail-
able upon request.
22. We do not measure impact only using the percentage of population affected because
doing so would understate the impact of disasters in wealthy countries where, typically,
the number of people affected is small but the reported economic damage is large and
more likely to be reported.
23. The conclusions drawn from Tables 4.1 and 4.2, and Figures 4.1–4.5 hold independent
of the definition of large disasters, with two main exceptions. First, as we increase the
cutoff for the damage to the GDP distribution, the number of large disasters in the
richer countries decreases. Second, the correlation in Figure 4.2 becomes flatter and
insignificant.
24. Given that the presence of rich countries varies across Bins, the findings imply our SCV
estimates are robust to the exclusion of large disasters in rich countries.
REFERENCES
Andrade da Silva, J., and L. Cernat (2012), ‘Coping with loss: the impact of
natural disasters on developing countries’ trade flows’, Trade Chief Economist
Note – European Commission, 1.
Baldwin, R., and J. Lopez- Gonzalez (2013), ‘Supply- chain trade: a portrait of
global patterns and several testable hypotheses’, NBER Working Paper Series,
No. 18957.
Feenstra, R.C., and G.H. Hanson (1996), ‘Globalization, outsourcing and wage
inequality’, American Economic Review, 86, 240–245.
Feenstra, R.C., and G.H. Hanson (1999), ‘The impact of outsourcing and high-
technology capital on wages: estimates from the United States, 1979–1990’,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 907–940.
Feenstra, R.C., and J.B. Jensen (2012), ‘Evaluating estimates of materials offshor-
ing from US manufacturing’, Economics Letters, 117, 170–173.
Gassebner, M., A. Keck, and R. Teh (2010), ‘Shaken, not stirred: the impact of dis-
asters on international trade’, Review of International Economics, 18, 351–368.
Gaulier, G., and S. Zignano (2010), ‘BACI: International trade database at the
product- level, the 1994–2007 version’, CEPII Working Paper Series, No. 23.
Hummels, D.L., J. Ishii, and K.- M. Yi (2001), ‘The nature and growth of vertical
specialization in world trade’, Journal of International Economics, 54, 75–96.
Johnson, R.C., and G. Noguera (2012), ‘Accounting for intermediates: produc-
tion sharing and trade in value added’, Journal of International Economics, 86,
224–236.
Jones, B., and B.A. Olken (2010), ‘Climate shocks and exports’, American
Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 100, 454–459.
Koren, M., and S. Tenreyro (2013), ‘Technological diversification’, American
Economic Review, 103, 378–414.
144 Asia and global production networks
Krishna, P., and A. Levchenko (forthcoming), ‘Complexity, comparative advan-
tage and volatility’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization.
Kumins, L., and R. Bamberger (2005), ‘Oil and gas disruptions from hurricanes
Katrina and Rita’, Congressional Research Report for Congress.
MacKenzie, C.A., J.R. Santos, and K. Barker (2012), ‘Measuring changes in inter-
national production from a disruption: case study of the Japanese earthquake
and tsunami’, International Journal of Production Economics, 138, 293–302.
Martin, R., M. Muûls, and A. Ward (2011), ‘The sensitivity of UK manufacturing
firms to extreme weather events’, mimeo.
Puzzello, L. (2012), ‘A proportionality assumption and measurement biases in the
factor content of trade’, Journal of International Economics, 87, 105–111.
Reimer, J.J. (2006), ‘Global production sharing and trade in the services of
factors’, Journal of International Economics, 68, 384–408.
Sherin, B., and S. Bartoletti (2000), ‘Taiwan’s 921 quake and what it means to
the semiconductor industry’, available at http://www.semiconductorsafety.org/
proceedings00/sherinbrian.pdf.
Trefler, D., and S.C. Zhu (2010), ‘The structure of factor content predictions’,
Journal of International Economics, 82, 195–207.
Winkler, D., and W. Milberg (2009), ‘Errors from the “proportionality assump-
tion” in the measurement of offshoring: application to German labor demand’,
SCEPA Working Paper Series, No. 2009–12.
Global supply chains and natural disasters 145
APPENDIX 4A.1 REGIONAL AND SECTORAL
AGGREGATION
The concordance of BACI data with the GTAP sectoral and regional clas-
sifications leaves us with 82 regions and 44 sectors. We list them below.
Region Aggregation
Oceania
AUS (Australia, Cocos Islands, Christmas Island, Heard Island and
McDonald Island), NZL (New Zealand), XOC (Rest of Oceania: American
Samoa, Cook Islands, Fiji, Micronesia Federated States of, Guam,
Kiribati, Marshall Islands, Northern Mariana Islands, New Caledonia,
Niue, Nauru, Palau, Papua New Guinea, French Polynesia, Solomon
Islands, Tokelau, Tonga, Tuvalu, Vanuatu, Wallis and Futuna, Samoa,
and United States Minor Outlying Islands);
Asia
PRC (People’s Republic of China), HKG (Hong Kong, China), JPN
(Japan), KOR (Republic of Korea), XEA (Rest of East Asia: Mongolia,
Korea, Democratic People’s Republic of, Macao), TAP (Taipei,China),
XSE (Rest of Southeast Asia: Brunei Darussalam, Cambodia, Lao
People’s Democratic Republic, Myanmar, Timor- Leste), INO (Indonesia),
MAL (Malaysia), PHI (Philippines), SIN (Singapore), THA (Thailand),
VIE (Viet Nam), BAN (Bangladesh), IND (India), SRI (Sri Lanka), XSA
(Rest of South Asia: Afghanistan, Bhutan, Maldives, Nepal, Pakistan);
North America
CAN (Canada), USA (United States of America), MEX (Mexico),
XNA (Rest of North America: Bermuda, Greenland, Saint Pierre and
Miquelon);
Other Americas
COL (Colombia), PER (Peru), VEN (Venezuela), XAP (Rest of Andean
Pact: Bolivia, Ecuador), ARG (Argentina), BRA (Brazil), CHL (Chile),
URY (Uruguay), XSM (Rest of South America: Falkland Islands, French
Guiana, Guyana, Paraguay, Suriname), XCA (Central America: Belize,
Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Nicaragua, Panama),
XCB (Rest of Free Trade Area of the Americas and Rest of the Caribbean:
Antigua and Barbuda, Bahamas, Barbados, Dominica, Dominican
Republic, Grenada, Haiti, Jamaica, Puerto Rico, Saint Kitts and Nevis,
Saint Lucia, Saint Vincent and the Grenadines, Trinidad and Tobago,
146 Asia and global production networks
Virgin Islands US; Anguilla, Aruba, Cayman Islands, Cuba, Montserrat,
Netherlands Antilles, Turks and Caicos, Virgin Islands – British);
Europe
AUT (Austria), BLX (Belgium and Luxembourg), DEN (Denmark), FIN
(Finland), FRA (France), GER (Germany), UKG (United Kingdom),
GRC (Greece), IRE (Ireland), ITA (Italy), NET (Netherlands), POR
(Portugal), SPA (Spain), SWE (Sweden), SWI (Switzerland), XEF (Rest
of Efta: Iceland, Liechtenstein, Norway), XER (Rest of Europe: Andorra,
Bosnia and Herzegovina, Faroe Islands, Gibraltar, Macedonia, the former
Yugoslav Republic of, Monaco, San Marino, Serbia and Montenegro),
ALB (Albania), BGR (Bulgaria), HRV (Croatia), CYP (Cyprus), CZE
(Czech Republic), HUN (Hungary), MLT (Malta), POL (Poland), ROU
(Romania), SVK (Slovakia), SVN (Slovenia), EST (Estonia), LVA (Latvia),
LTU (Lithuania), RUS (Russian Federation), XSU (Rest of Former Soviet
Union: Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Georgia, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyz
Republic, Moldova, Republic of, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, Ukraine,
Uzbekistan), TUR (Turkey);
Africa and Middle East
XME (Rest of Middle East: Bahrain, Iran, Iraq, Israel, Jordan,
Kuwait, Lebanon, Oman, Palestinian Territory, Occupied, Qatar, Saudi
Arabia, Syrian Arab Republic, United Arab Emirates, Yemen), MAR
(Morocco), TUN (Tunisia), XNF (Rest of North Africa: Algeria, Egypt,
Libyan Arab Jamahiriya), ZAF (South Africa), MWI (Malawi), MOZ
(Mozambique), TZA (Tanzania), ZMB (Zambia), ZWE (Zimbabwe),
XSD (Rest of Southern African Development Community and Rest of
Sub- Saharan Africa: Angola, Congo, the Democratic Republic of the,
Mauritius, Seychelles; Benin, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, Cape
Verde, Central African Republic, Chad, Comoros, Congo, Cote d’Ivoire
Djibouti, Equatorial Guinea, Eritrea, Ethiopia, Gabon, Gambia, Ghana,
Guinea, Guinea- Bissau, Kenya, Liberia, Mali, Mauritania, Mayotte,
Niger, Nigeria, Rwanda, Saint Helena, Sao Tome and Principe, Senegal,
Sierra Leone, Somalia, Sudan, Togo), MDG (Madagascar), UGA
(Uganda), BWA (Botswana), XSC (Rest of South African Customs
Union: Lesotho, Namibia, Swaziland).
Sector Aggregation
Raw agriculture
PDR (Paddy rice), WHT (Wheat), GRO (Cereal grains not elsewhere clas-
sified (nec, henceforth)), V_F (Vegetables, fruit, nuts), OSD (Oil seeds),
Global supply chains and natural disasters 147
C_B (Sugar cane, sugar beet), PFB (Plant- based fibers), OCR (Crops
nec), CTL (Bovine cattle, sheep and goats, horses), OAP (Animal prod-
ucts nec), RMK (Raw milk), WOL (Wool, silk- worm cocoons), FOR
(Forestry), FSH (Fishing);
Food products
OMN (Minerals nec), CMT (Bovine meat products), OMT (Meat prod-
ucts nec), VOL (Vegetable oils and fats), MIL (Dairy products), PCR
(Processed rice), SGR (Sugar), OFD (Food products nec), B_T (Beverages
and tobacco products);
Manufacturing
TEX (Textiles), WAP (Wearing apparel), LEA (Leather products), LUM
(Wood products), PPP (Paper products, publishing), P_C (Petroleum,
coal products), CRP (Chemical, rubber, plastic products), NMM (Mineral
products nec), I_S (Ferrous metals), NFM (Metals nec), FMP (Metal
products), MVH (Motor vehicles and parts), OTN (Transport equipment
nec), ELE (Electronic equipment), OME (Machinery and equipment nec),
OMF (Manufactures nec);
Energy
COL (Coal), OIL (Oil), GAS (Gas), ELY (Electricity), GDT (Gas manu-
facture, distribution).
148
5. Vertical specialization, tariff
shirking and trade
Alyson C. Ma and Ari Van Assche
1. INTRODUCTION
The organization of production has changed in the past few decades.
Groundbreaking advances in transportation and communications tech-
nology have enabled firms to separate value chain tasks in space and time
(Grossman and Rossi- Hansberg, 2008). Recent studies have extensively
investigated how this added organizational flexibility allows firms to arbi-
trage factor cost and institutional differences across countries, leading to the
emergence of global value chains (see Van Assche, 2012 for an overview).
An additional benefit related to the slicing up of value chains, which
has received less attention, is that it allows firms to more easily circumvent
trade policy barriers. To avoid a country- specific trade barrier, a company
no longer has to relocate its entire value chain to another country, but
only a single value chain stage, often final assembly. Fung et al. (2007,
pp. 58–59), for example, describe how the trading company Li & Fung
scrambled to restructure its value chain in response to an unexpected trade
policy shock:
[O]n a Friday in early September 2006, the South African government
announced that it would be imposing strict quotas on Chinese imports in two
weeks. Li & Fung had orders already in production for South African retailers
that would be affected by these changes. Managers began to look at contin-
gency plans to move production to factories in different countries and even
to move the last stage of existing orders to different end countries to satisfy
non- China country- of- origin rules.
The trading company’s urge to restructure its value chain to circumvent
trade barriers implies that tariff shirking may be a powerful force affecting
trade patterns. A firm’s ability to circumvent trade policy, in turn, may
have important implications for the effectiveness of trade policy to protect
domestic firms and for the transmission of trade policy shocks along
different parts of the value chain.
Vertical specialization, tariff shirking and trade 149
In this chapter, we present an analytical framework that allows us to
investigate the effects of tariff shirking on trade. We build on the hetero-
geneous firm models by Melitz (2003) and by Chaney (2008), but allow
Northern firms to manufacture their goods either in their home country
(local value chain) or in the South (global value chain). We show that this
added organizational flexibility makes it profitable for some Northern
firms (at the margin) to circumvent country- specific tariff hikes by relo-
cating their manufacturing. For example, if tariffs increase on Southern
exports, some Northern firms will reshore their manufacturing to their
home country, leading to an extensive margin effect. Several strong results
emerge from the model. First, tariff shirking reduces the effectiveness
of trade policy to protect a domestic industry since it provides foreign
companies with an extra tool to circumvent country- specific tariffs.
Second, vertical specialization increases the elasticity of bilateral exports
to country- specific tariff hikes. Third, Southern exports that are part of
global value chains are more sensitive to a country- specific tariff hike than
Southern exports that are part of local value chains. Fourth, the effect
of trade policy is distributed unevenly along the value chain. While tariff
shirking dampens the vulnerability of headquarters services to trade policy
shocks, it amplifies the vulnerability of manufacturing to trade policy
shocks.
Guided by the theory, we empirically investigate the prediction that
Southern exports that are part of global value chains are more sensitive to
a country- specific tariff hike than Southern exports that are part of local
value chains. For this purpose, we draw on both firm- level and provincial
level data from the customs statistics of the People’s Republic of China
(PRC). We do so by making a distinction between Chinese exports under
two separate customs regimes: processing trade and ordinary trade. As
both Kee and Tang (2013) and Koopman et al. (2012) have illustrated,
processing exports are predominantly part of global value chains, while
ordinary exports more extensively use domestic value chains. In line
with our theoretical predictions, we find strong evidence that processing
exports are more sensitive to the imposition of antidumping measures
than ordinary exports. This is mostly due to the extensive margin effect
identified in the theoretical model.
The rest of the chapter is organized as follows. In Section 2, we survey
the related literature on trade policy and global value chains. In Section
3, we present the theoretical model and discuss our central predictions.
Section 4 then presents the data and methods used for our empirical analy-
sis, and the results. Section 5 talks about the implications for policy and
we finally conclude.
150 Asia and global production networks
2. VERTICAL SPECIALIZATION AND TRADE
POLICY
The growing ability of companies to separate value chain tasks in space
and time is intrinsically related to the modularization of product archi-
tectures. Ulrich (1995) defines a product as a combination of components
or modules that interact with one another according to the design
rules of its product architecture. Products’ architectures can vary on a
continuum from integral to modular depending on the number of inter-
dependencies between modules (Schilling, 2000). If the product architec-
ture is integral, modules are highly interdependent and require constant
monitoring and tacit interactions. In that case, geographically separating
value chain activities is hard to do since it requires significant coordi-
nation efforts (Fort, 2011). In contrast, if the product architecture is
modular, then the modules interact through codified (and often digitized)
interfaces, which make them relatively independent from one another.
In that case, modules can be geographically separated at a relatively low
coordination cost.
The emergence of e- mail, the Internet and common communications
protocols, as well as the increased availability of high- capacity computing
power, has made it easier for firms to modularize their product architec-
ture. Currently, many companies rely on sophisticated computer- aided
design (CAD) technologies and business- to- business (B2B) systems to
share codified information between geographically separated locations.
These technologies allow them to perform tasks in geographically dis-
persed locations with limited risk of miscommunication and with a
relatively modest cost of monitoring (Blinder, 2006; Leamer and Storper,
2001; Levy and Murnane, 2003). Indeed, Fort (2011) estimates that US
companies that use CAD technology to coordinate shipments have frag-
mented their international production processes more extensively than
have companies without CAD technology.
A now vast literature in international trade has investigated how the
added organizational flexibility related to the modularization of product
architectures allows firms to arbitrage cost differences across countries.
Beyond the traditional sources of comparative advantage such as tech-
nological differences and relative endowments, scholars have pinpointed
new sources of comparative advantage for task trade. Focusing on the fact
that global value chains often involve multiple companies that sign con-
tracts with each other, one stream of literature has identified the quality
of a country’s judiciary system as a source of comparative advantage
(Acemoglu et al., 2007; Costinot, 2009; Levchenko, 2007; Nunn, 2007).
Other studies have focused on the quality of a country’s transportation
Vertical specialization, tariff shirking and trade 151
infrastructure (Gamberoni et al., 2010) and labor markets (Helpman and
Itskhoki, 2010) as a source of comparative advantage.
Less attention has been paid to trade policy barriers as a cost factor that
can be arbitraged through the restructuring of the value chain.
1
The litera-
ture has largely considered trade policy barriers as a factor that reduces a
firm’s incentive to slice up its value chains. Focusing on worldwide tariffs,
Yi (2003) shows that they have a higher impact on the cost of trade within
global value chains as compared with regular trade (i.e. trade of final
goods fully produced in a single country), since the same component needs
to cross borders multiple times. As a result, he predicts that a relatively
small rise in worldwide tariffs or other trade barriers will deter many firms
from fragmenting production internationally, therefore leading to a large
drop in trade.
2
In Yi’s (2003) model, the ability to fragment production internationally
does not provide firms with added flexibility to circumvent tariffs, since
tariffs world- wide are assumed to uniformly move up or down. The litera-
ture on tariff jumping, then again, provides insights into the effect of tariff
changes on the spatial structure of production. Belderbos and Sleuwaegen
(1998) and Blonigen (2002) provide evidence that many firms react to a
country- specific tariff increase or antidumping measure by moving their
production to the destination country, thereby avoiding the trade barrier.
Blonigen et al. (2004) show that such tariff jumping foreign direct invest-
ment (FDI) reduces the effectiveness of trade policy to protect domestic
firms.
Surprisingly, the international trade literature has paid limited attention
to tariff shirking as a strategy to avoid country- specific changes in trade
policy. Distinct from tariff jumping, where the firm moves production to
the destination country or region, a firm under tariff shirking would try
to circumvent the trade policy barrier by moving manufacturing to a third
country that does not face the trade policy barrier.
3
Arguably, vertical
specialization has made tariff shirking easier since firms only need to move
a part of their value chain instead of their entire value chain. In the next
section we move to set up a theoretical model that allows us to analyze the
mechanism of tariff shirking and the effect on trade.
3. MODEL
Our model builds on the firm heterogeneity models of Melitz (2003) and
Chaney (2008), but allows firms to manufacture their final goods either in
their home country (local value chain) or in a Southern country (global
value chain). Consider a world with many small Northern countries and
152 Asia and global production networks
a small Southern country. In each country j, households spend the fixed
amount
Y
j
. 0
on a specific differentiated goods sector. The demand
function for a variety
v
in this sector produced in country i and sold in
country j equals:
y
ij
(
v
)
5
A
j
p
ij
(
v
)
2e
,
(5.1)
where e 5
1
1 2 a
.
1
is the elasticity of substitution between any pair of
differentiated goods and the demand level A
j
is exogenous from the point
of view of the individual firm and the individual country (due to the small
country assumption).
4
Exports from country i to country j are subject to an ad valorem tariff
t
ij
,
where
t
ij
5 1 1 t
ij
.
Tariffs are country- specific and vary across countries.
The tariff implies that the consumer price in country j is higher than the
domestically charged price (i.e. in country i):
p
ij
(
v
)
5
p
i
(
v
) (
1
1
t
ij
)
5
p
i
(
v
)
t
ij
,
(5.2)
where
p
i
(
v
)
is the domestic price.
In each country, a continuum of firms has the know- how to produce
a single variety. We assume that each firm draws a productivity
f
from
a cumulative Pareto distribution
G
(
f
)
with shape parameter
z . e 2 1
(Helpman et al., 2004):
G
(
f
)
5
1
2 f
2
z
.
(5.3)
An inverse measure of the heterogeneity in a sector is given by z. If z is
high, firms are more homogeneous, in the sense that more output is con-
centrated among the smallest and least productive firms. We assume that
all countries face an identical Pareto distribution function.
The value chain of a product consists of three stages: knowledge-
intensive headquarters service production, labor- intensive manufacturing
and final sale. A firm is required to produce its headquarters services in
its home country. Manufacturing, in contrast, is footloose and can be
conducted either in a Northern country at a fixed unit labor cost of
w
N
or in the South at a fixed unit labor cost of
w
S
. If manufacturing is not
co- located with headquarters services, the firm faces a fixed cost g of coor-
dinating its global value chain activities across borders. Finally, to sell its
product variety to consumers in the destination country j, a firm faces a
fixed cost f.
In our model, we assume that wages are fixed and are lower in the South
Vertical specialization, tariff shirking and trade 153
than in the Northern countries,
w
S
, w
N
.
Furthermore, we assume that
the following condition holds:
5
a
w
N
w
S
b
e2
1
a
t
N
t
S
b
e
. 1. (5.4)
Under this condition, any firm has a marginal cost advantage of manufac-
turing its products in the South compared to the North. In other words,
the wage advantage of manufacturing in the South is sufficiently large to
outweigh a potential tariff advantage of exporting the final good from the
North.
Without loss of generality, we will focus on the strategies of firms from
a single Northern country l 5 N and from the South l 5 S that sell their
products to a specific Northern destination country j. For notational
clarity, we will drop the subscript j that identifies the destination country.
We solve the model in two steps. In Section 3.1, we analyze the
benchmark scenario of “no vertical specialization” where Northern and
Southern firms are required to spatially co- locate headquarters services
and manufacturing. In Section 3.2, we then study the scenario of “verti-
cal specialization” where it becomes optimal for some Northern firms to
slice up their value chain and offshore their manufacturing to a Southern
country. By comparing the equilibrium outcomes of both scenarios we
can investigate how the extra organizational ability of slicing up the value
chain affects the elasticity of exports to country- specific tariff changes.
3.1 No Vertical Specialization
Consider the benchmark case where g approaches infinity so that all firms
are better off co- locating manufacturing with headquarters services.
6
This is in line with the scenario where the product architecture is integral
so that it is difficult to spatially disperse value chain activities. From
equations (5.1) and (5.2), firms from l[{N, S} choose y to maximize
p
l
5
(
p
l
2
w
l
f
)
y
l
2 f. It is straightforward to check that this program yields
the optimal price, p
l
5
w
l
af
, the optimal firm- specific exports:
x
l
5
B
1
2 a
a
f
w
l
b
e2
1
t
l
2e
, (5.5)
and the optimal firm- specific profit:
p
l
5
a
f
w
l
b
e2
1
t
l
2e
B 2 f, (5.6)
154 Asia and global production networks
where
B
5
(
1
2 a
)
A
a
e2
1
.
Intuitively, equations (5.5) and (5.6) suggest
that a firm’s exports and profits decline with the rise of its home country
l’s wages
w
l
and the country- specific tariffs it faces
t
l
.
Not all firms are able to generate enough profits to cover the fixed cost
f of exporting to the destination country. Define
f
l
as the threshold pro-
ductivity at which
p
l
5 0.
Using equation (5.6), the cut- off productivity
coefficient for firms in country l equals:
f
l
5 w
l
a
f
B
b
1
e2 1
t
l
e
e2 1
.
(5.7)
From equation (5.6), it is clear that less productive firms with
f , f
l
do
not export to the destination country, while firms with
f . f
l
become
exporters.
Country l’s aggregate exports to the destination country equal the sum
of exports by firms with
f . f
l
.
Using the firm- level export equation (5.5),
the aggregate export equation equals:
X
l
5
3
`
f
l
x
l
(
f
)
dG
(
f
)
5
B
1 2 a
t
l
2 e
3
`
f
l
a
f
w
l
b
e2 1
dG
(
f
)
. (5.8)
We can use equation (5.8) to investigate the elasticity of aggregate exports
X
l
with respect to a country- specific tariff change
t
l
.
As illustrated by
Chaney (2008) the effect can be decomposed into two different margins:
2
dX
l
/
dt
l
X
l
/t
l
5 2
t
l
X
l
a
3
`
f
l
0x
l
(
f
)
0t
l
dG
(
f
)
b
1
t
l
X
l
a
x
l
(
f
l
)
G
r
(
f
l
)
0
f
l
0t
l
b
, (5.9)
where the first term is the intensive margin and the second is the exten-
sive margin. The intensive margin determines by which amount existing
exporters (or incumbents) change the size of their exports. The extensive
margin defines the amount that aggregate exports change due to firm
entry and exit. In Appendix 5A.1, we solve equation (5.9) to obtain the
elasticity of a country’s exports to a country- specific tariff change:
2
dX
l
X
t
l
dt
l
5 e 1
(
z 2
(
e 2 1
))
e
e 2 1
. (5.10)
There are two important aspects to note about this elasticity. First, the
elasticity differs from Chaney (2008) because we model trade barriers as ad
valorem tariffs and not as iceberg transport costs. As Cole and Davies (2011)
show, the use of ad valorem tariffs implies that, unlike in Chaney (2008), the
Vertical specialization, tariff shirking and trade 155
elasticity of trade with respect to trade barriers is a function of the elastic-
ity of substitution between product varieties. It is important to emphasize,
however, that the central predictions of our model would be unaffected if
we had used iceberg transport costs. Second, due to our assumption that the
productivity dispersion is identical across countries, the elasticity of aggre-
gate exports with respect to a country- specific tariff change is the same for
both Northern countries and South. In the remainder of the chapter, we will
use equation (5.10) as a benchmark to investigate how vertical specializa-
tion alters the impact of country- specific trade policy shocks on trade.
3.2 Vertical Specialization
Consider next the scenario where the fixed coordination costs g are within
the parameter range.
f
[ (
t
N
t
S
)
e
(
w
N
w
S
)
e2 1
2
1
]
,
g
,1`
.
In that case, it is only
optimal for the most productive Northern firms to locate their manufac-
turing in the South.
7
As Figure 5.1 illustrates, three organizational forms
coexist in the industry under this condition: (1) Southern firms with local
Northern firm with
global value chain
Headquarter
service
Manufacturing
Sales
Headquarter
service
Manufacturing
Sales
Southern firm with
local value chain
DESTINATION
SOUTH
NORTH
Northern firm with
local value chain
Sales
Manufacturing
Headquarter
service
Source: Authors’ depiction.
Figure 5.1 Types of organizational forms exporting to the destination
country
156 Asia and global production networks
value chains, (2) Northern firms with local value chains, and (3) Northern
firms with global value chains. In the remainder of this section, we esti-
mate the elasticity of exports with respect to country- specific tariffs for
these three organizational forms.
3.2.1 Southern firms
Due to the marginal cost advantage of manufacturing in the South, there
is no benefit for Southern firms to manufacture their goods in the North.
As a result, all Southern firms co- locate manufacturing with headquarters
services in the South and the analysis is identical to Section 3.1. The elas-
ticity of Southern firms’ exports with respect to a country- specific tariff
change thus equals:
2
dX
S
X
S
t
S
dt
S
5 e 1
(
z 2
(
e 2 1
))
e
e 2 1
. (5.11)
3.2.2 Northern firms
As is illustrated in Figures 5.1 and 5.2, two types of Northern firms
sell their products to the destination country: less productive firms
(
f
N
, f , f
NO
) which manufacture in the North, and more productive
Non-exporters Northern firms with
domestic value
chain
Northern firms with
global value
chain
–(f + g)
f
0
(
N
)
–1
(
NO
)
–1
N
k
NO
(
k
)
–1
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure 5.2 Productivity and Northern firms’ organizational form
Vertical specialization, tariff shirking and trade 157
firms (
f . f
NO
) which manufacture in the South. We consider their
optimization problems in turn.
For Northern firms with a domestic value chain (
f
N
, f , f
NO
), the
profit maximization problem is identical to section 3.1. Firm- specific
profits amount to p
N
5
(
f
w
N
)
e2
1
t
N
2e
B
2
f,
which imply that firms with a
productivity below f
N
5 w
N
(
f
B
)
1
e 2 1
t
N
e
e 2 1
do not export to the destination
country. Firm- specific exports amount to
x
N
5
B
1 2 a
(
f
w
N
)
e2 1
t
N
2e
.
Northern firms with a global value chain (
f . f
NO
) perform their manu-
facturing in the South and choose y to maximize p
NO
5
(
p 2
w
S
f
)
y 2 f 2 g
.
For these firms, their optimal price equals p
NO
5
w
S
af
, their firm- specific
exports equal:
x
NO
5
B
1
2 a
a
f
w
S
b
e2
1
t
S
2e
, (5.12)
and their firm- specific profits equal:
p
NO
5
a
f
w
S
b
e2
1
t
S
2e
B 2 f 2 g. (5.13)
Using equations (5.5) and (5.13), the threshold at which p
N
(
f
NO
)
5p
NO
(
f
NO
)
equals:
f
NO
5
a
g
B
(
w
S
1 2 e
t
S
2e
2 w
N
1 2 e
t
N
2e
)
b
1
e2 1
. (5.14)
The Northern firms with a productivity
f . f
NO
manufacture in the
South, while firms with a productivity
f
N
, f , f
NO
manufacture in the
North.
3.3 Aggregate Exports by Firm Type
Aggregate exports from the North by firms with domestic value chains,
X
N
,
equals the integral of firm- level exports
x
N
for firms with a productiv-
ity
f
N
, f , f
NO
.
Using equation (5.5):
X
N
5
3
f
NO
f
N
x
N
(
f
)
dG
(
f
)
. (5.15)
Aggregate exports from the South by Northern firms with global value
chains,
X
NO
,
equals the integral of firm- level exports
x
NO
for Northern
firms with a productivity
f . f
NO
.
Using equation (5.12):
158 Asia and global production networks
X
NO
5
3
`
f
O
x
NO
(
f
)
dG
(
f
)
. (5.16)
We can use these aggregate export equations to investigate if vertical spe-
cialization affects the elasticity of exports with respect to country- specific
tariffs.
3.3.1 Impact of an increase in t
S
on
X
NO
We first investigate the impact of an ad valorem bilateral tariff increase
t
S
on
X
NO
.
In Appendix 5A.2, we use equation (5.16) to calculate that the
elasticity of
X
NO
with respect to
t
S
equals:
2
dX
NO
/dt
S
X
NO
/t
S
5 e 1
(
z 2
(
e 2 1
))
e
e 2 1
c, (5.17)
where
c 5
a
w
N
w
S
b
e2 1
a
t
N
t
S
b
e
a
w
N
w
S
b
e2 1
a
t
N
t
S
b
e
2 1
. 1.
Due to our assumption in equation (5.4) that there is a marginal cost
advantage of manufacturing in the South compared to the North, the fol-
lowing inequality holds:
c . 1.
As a result, if we compare to the equation
(5.10), Northern firms’ exports from South,
X
NO
,
are more elastic with
respect to an increase in
t
S
than their exports were under no vertical spe-
cialization. This result is driven by an extra extensive margin effect related
to tariff shirking. If
t
S
increases, it induces an extra number of firms to
stop exporting from country S since they move assembly back to N to cir-
cumvent the tariff hike. Note that the extra elasticity denoted by
c
is larger
if the marginal cost advantage of manufacturing in the South is smaller. In
other words, the smaller is the marginal cost advantage of manufacturing
in the South, the more
X
NO
would be affected by tariff shirking.
Compared to equation (5.11), Northern firms’ exports from South,
X
NO
,
are also more elastic than Southern firms’ exports from South,
X
S
,
with
respect to an increase in
t
S
.
This is once again because some Northern
firms (at the margin) have the extra flexibility to circumvent the tariff
increase by reshoring manufacturing back to the North. An implication
of the difference in elasticities between Southern exports conducted by
Northern and Southern firms is that an increase in
t
S
will reduce the share
Vertical specialization, tariff shirking and trade 159
of Southern exports conducted by Northern firms. Define
s
NO
as the share
of Southern exports conducted by Northern firms:
s
NO
5
X
NO
X
NO
1 X
S
. (5.18)
By taking the derivate of equation (5.18) and using the elasticities in equa-
tions (5.11) and (5.17), it is straightforward to show that the share
s
NO
is
negatively affected by a rise in
t
S
:
0s
NO
0t
S
5 2
1
t
S
s
NO
(
1 2 s
NO
) (
z 2
(
e 2 1
))
e
e 2 1
(
c 2 1
)
, 0
.
(5.19)
In our empirical analysis, we will further investigate this specific predic-
tion of the model.
3.3.2 Impact of an increase in
t
N
on
X
N
We next investigate the effect of an ad valorem bilateral tariff increase
t
N
on
X
N
.
In Appendix 5A.2, we use equation (5.15) to calculate that the
elasticity equals:
2
dX
N
/dt
N
X
N
/t
N
5 e1
(
z2
(
e 21
))
e
e21
°
11
X
NO
X
N
*
1
a
w
N
w
S
b
e2 1
a
t
N
t
S
b
e
21
¢
. (5.20)
If we compare with the scenario of no vertical specialization in equation
(5.10), it is clear that
X
N
is more elastic with respect to
t
N
under vertical
specialization than under no vertical specialization since
X
NO
X
N
*
1
a
w
N
w
S
b
e2 1
a
t
N
t
S
b
e
2 1
. 0.
This result is once again due to an extra extensive margin effect. The logic
is the following. Compared to no vertical specialization, a tariff hike not
only induces a number of Northern firms to become non- exporters, but
also causes a number of firms to divert their exports through the South in
order to circumvent the tariff increase. This extra tariff shirking effect at
the extensive margin, which is driven by the ability to fragment assembly
from input production, increases the elasticity of
X
N
with respect to
t
N
.
The extra elasticity once again depends on the size of the marginal cost
160 Asia and global production networks
advantage of manufacturing in the South. The smaller this marginal cost
advantage is, the more sensitive is
X
N
to a country- specific tariff hike.
3.3.3 Sensitivity of production stages to trade policy shocks
Finally, we investigate whether vertical specialization affects the impact
of a tariff increase differentially along the two vertical stages of the
value chain: (non- footloose) headquarters services and (footloose)
manufacturing.
It is straightforward to show that vertical specialization reduces the
vulnerability of sector- wide headquarters services in the North to a
country- specific tariff increase
t
N
or
t
S
.
The intuition is the following.
Since a number of companies (at the margin) are able to dampen the
effect of the tariff hike by relocating their manufacturing, the demand
for products sold by firms from N is less affected by the tariff hike than
under the no- vertical- specialization scenario. As a result, non- footloose
headquarters service production in country N is also less vulnerable to
the tariff hike.
In contrast, vertical specialization increases the vulnerability of manu-
facturing activities in both country
N
and S to a country- specific tariff
increase
t
N
or
t
S
.
As Northern companies (at the margin) relocate their
manufacturing to circumvent tariffs, footloose manufacturing activities
become particularly vulnerable to trade policy shocks. Manufacturing in
country N, for example, is extra vulnerable to an increase in
t
N
since it
induces a number of firms to cease manufacturing in N and offshore it to
S. Similarly, manufacturing in country S is extra vulnerable to an increase
in
t
S
since it induces a number of Northern firms to cease production in
S
and reshore it to country N.
4. EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS
A key prediction from the model is that Southern exports that are part
of global value chains are more elastic with respect to a country- specific
tariff hike than Southern exports that are part of local value chains. As a
result, a country- specific tariff hike should reduce the share of exports that
are part of global value chains. In this section, we draw on both province-
level (1997–2009) and firm- level (2000–2006) data from Chinese customs
statistics to investigate this claim.
To classify Chinese exports that are part of global versus local value
chains, we distinguish between two customs regimes: processing trade and
ordinary trade. These two trade forms differ in terms of tariff treatment
and the ability of firms to sell on the domestic market:
Vertical specialization, tariff shirking and trade 161
Under the processing trade regime, firms enjoy the right of duty- free
imports of intermediate goods and capital equipment that are used
in their export processing activity, but face restrictions in selling to
the domestic market.
Under the ordinary trade regime, firms pay import duties on
imported inputs but can sell their output locally.
Due to these distinct characteristics the processing trade regime is used
primarily by exporting firms that are part of a global value chain, while
the ordinary trade regime is used by exporting firms that have more
extensive domestic value chains. Two stylized facts back this up. First,
recent estimates suggest that processing exports embody less than half as
much domestic value added than ordinary exports (Kee and Tang, 2013;
Koopman et al., 2012). Second, as is shown in Figure 5.3, foreign- owned
firms play a much more dominant role in the processing trade regime than
in the ordinary trade regime. Between 1997 and 2009, the share of process-
ing exports conducted by foreign- owned enterprises increased from 64
percent to 85 percent. In comparison, this share throughout the sample
period remained under 30 percent in the ordinary trade regime. We use
0
20
40
60
80
100
1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
%
Ordinary trade Processing trade
Source: Authors’ calculations using data from the People’s Republic of China’s Customs
Statistics.
Figure 5.3 Share of the People’s Republic of China’s exports conducted
by foreign- owned enterprises, by customs regime, 1997–2009
(%)
162 Asia and global production networks
this distinction to evaluate the theoretical prediction that exports are more
sensitive to country- specific trade policy shocks under the processing trade
regime than under the ordinary trade regime.
As our measure of country- specific trade policy shocks, we use anti-
dumping cases against the PRC as identified in the Global Antidumping
Database (GAD) published by the World Bank (Bown, 2009). The benefit
of using antidumping as a measure for a country- specific trade policy
shock is that it is generally imposed by a country on firms of a specific
country, and not across the board. The GAD has detailed information on
each antidumping case, such as product information (6- digit HS codes),
the investigating country, the target country, the preliminary determi-
nation date and the year it was revoked. For our analysis, we collect
information on all antidumping cases against the PRC during the period
1997–2009. We match the GAD data with the Chinese customs data at the
HS6 digit level, the most disaggregated level at which the two datasets are
comparable.
From 1997 to 2009 there were a total of 1042 cases of which 1011 were
in the manufacturing sector. We focus our study on the manufacturing
sector, which is more in line with the theory presented on vertical spe-
cialization. Over the 12- year period in the data set, the average number of
cases was 78 per year with a median of 61 cases. The antidumping charges
were imposed on $131 billion of Chinese exports, which represented 1.75
percent of total Chinese exports in manufacturing. Table 5.1 shows that
the number of cases increased by 162 percent from 55 to 144 between 2000
and 2001. The number of cases also spiked in 2006 with 127 cases (up by 22
percent) and again in 2008 and 2009 with 110 and 158 cases, respectively.
The table also shows that the United States (US) held the most antidump-
ing charges against the PRC with about a quarter of the total number of
cases. The next three largest initiators are India, the European Union, and
Canada with 15 percent, 12 percent, and 10 percent, respectively.
4.1 Province- level Analysis
In a first step, we use aggregate province- level data for the time period
1997–2009 to investigate if antidumping disproportionately affects
processing exports compared to ordinary exports. In our analysis, our
dependent variable is the share in value of bilateral exports that is organ-
ized through processing trade in a specific HS 6- digit industry and year:
Share
ijkt
5
PX
ijkt
PX
ijkt
1 OX
ijkt
, (5.21)
163
Table 5.1 Summary statistics of preliminary antidumping decisions imposed against the People’s Republic of China, by
year and country
Year of preliminary antidumping decision
1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 Total
India 1 8 3 9 21 8 24 2 9 11 6 11 36 149
Indonesia 8 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 11
Israel 0 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 1 3 4 0 0 10
Malaysia 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1
Pakistan 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 4 0 0 4 9
Philippines 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1
Republic of Korea 3 2 0 1 0 0 9 2 2 3 4 7 0 33
Turkey 0 0 0 0 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 2
Taipei,China 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 14 0 0 0 14
South Africa 13 4 0 1 2 1 0 1 3 4 2 3 1 35
European Union 11 20 2 6 3 1 3 2 20 20 5 7 21 121
Argentina 8 0 2 0 11 6 1 4 1 5 2 17 38 95
Brazil 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 5 3 2 16 28
Colombia 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 2 1 47 2 7 3 62
Mexico 1 1 1 0 5 1 3 1 2 2 2 3 0 22
Peru 0 1 6 0 11 4 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 24
Trinidad and
Tobago
0 0 0 1 0 0 0 6 0 0 0 0 0 7
Venezuela 0 0 13 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 13
Canada 2 0 0 11 43 2 3 8 1 2 1 10 17 100
United States 13 0 2 25 46 50 5 42 3 5 5 42 15 253
Australia 1 0 0 0 2 3 0 3 1 2 0 1 7 20
New Zealand 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 1
Total 61 41 31 55 144 79 49 75 45 127 36 110 158 1011
Source: Authors’ calculations using the Global Antidumping Database.
164 Asia and global production networks
where
PX
ijkt
is the value of Chinese processing exports from province i
to country j in industry k and year t, and
OX
ijkt
is the value of Chinese
ordinary exports from province i to country j in industry k and year t.
To test the prediction of the theoretical model, we estimate the following
regression equation:
Share
ijkt
5 a
i
1 a
k
1 a
t
1 b
*
AD
jkt
1 e
ijkt
,
(5.22)
where
a
i
,
a
k
and
a
t
are province, industry and year fixed effects;
AD
jkt
is
a dummy variable that takes on a value of 1 when a HS 6- digit export
industry k faces an antidumping measure imposed by country j in a year
t and 0 otherwise; and
e
ijkt
is an error term. There will be evidence that an
antidumping measure disproportionately affects processing trade if the
OLS estimate b
^
is negative and significant.
The results of the benchmark analysis are presented in Column 1 of
Table 5.2. The negative and significant coefficient on the antidumping
indicator suggests that the share of processing exports declines after the
imposition of antidumping duties. Specifically, an antidumping imposi-
tion reduces the share of processing exports by 7.6 percent. We can infer
Table 5.2 Province- level estimation results
Dependent variable: Share
ijkt
Benchmark Foreign PT/
Domestic OT
Foreign PT/Domestic
OT/only AD sectors
(1) (2) (3)
AD −7.590***
(0.606)
−8.371***
(0.720)
−11.118***
(0.736)
Year FE Yes Yes Yes
Sector FE Yes Yes Yes
Province FE Yes Yes Yes
Observations 931 293 713 761 410 630
R
2
0.16 0.19 0.18
Notes:
AD 5 antidumping; FE 5 fixed effects; OT 5ordinary trade regime; PT 5 processing trade
regime.
Coefficients are reported with robust standard errors that are clustered at the province
level. Standard errors are given in parentheses. The individual coefficient is statistically
significant at the *10%, **5% or ***1% level.
Source: Authors’ calculations using the Global Antidumping Database and data from the
People’s Republic of China’s Customs Statistics.
Vertical specialization, tariff shirking and trade 165
from this that processing exports are considerably more sensitive to the
imposition of antidumping duties than ordinary exports.
In Column 2 of Table 5.2, we test whether the results are sensitive to
excluding Chinese firms that conduct processing exports and foreign firms
that conduct ordinary exports. This restriction aligns the empirical estima-
tion better to the theory that Southern exports within global value chains
are conducted by Northern firms, while Southern exports within local
value chains are conducted by Southern firms. The results are similar to
the benchmark analysis, with a slightly larger reduction of 8.4 percent in
the share of processing exports.
In Column 3 of Table 5.2, as an additional robustness test, we exclude
all industries from our data sample in which no antidumping was imposed
during the entire sample period (1997–2009). The results are once again
similar to the benchmark analysis, with a larger reduction of 11.1 percent.
4.2 Firm- level Analysis
The province- level data do not allow us to examine the impact of anti-
dumping impositions on the intensive and extensive margin separately.
To distinguish these two effects, we therefore utilize more disaggregated
firm-level data from Chinese customs statistics that are only available for
the subsample 2000 to 2006.
We define intensive margin as exports by incumbent firms. To be con-
sidered as an incumbent, a firm must have at least one year of positive
exports in an industry affected by antidumping prior to the imposition
of the antidumping charges and at least one year of positive exports
after the imposition. For example, a firm exporting a girl’s 16- inch bike
to the US in years 2001 to 2004 would be considered an incumbent if
the US imposed an antidumping charge on the PRC for the item in year
2002.
8
We define extensive margin as exports by non- incumbent firms (Morrow
and Brandt, 2013). In other words, the extensive margin captures exports
by firms that did not export in a year prior to the imposition of antidump-
ing charges or did not export in a year after the imposition of antidumping
charges.
To investigate if antidumping disproportionately affects processing
exports compared to ordinary exports at the intensive margin, we use the
following dependent variable:
Share_Int
jkt
5
PX_Int
jkt
PX_Int
jkt
1 OX_Int
jkt
, (5.23)
166 Asia and global production networks
where
PX_Int
jkt
is the value of processing exports to country j by incum-
bents in industry k and year t, and
OX_Int
jkt
is the value of ordinary exports
to country j by incumbents in industry k and year t. Similar to above, we
test our central prediction by estimating the following regression equation:
Share_Int
jkt
5 a
k
1 a
t
1 b
*
AD
jkt
1 e
jkt
,
(5.24)
where
a
k
and
a
t
are industry and year fixed effects;
AD
jkt
is a dummy varia-
ble that takes on a value of 1 when an HS 6- digit export industry k faces an
antidumping measure imposed by country j in a year t and 0 otherwise; and
e
jkt
is an error term. There will be evidence that an anti- dumping measure
disproportionately affects processing trade at the intensive margin if the
OLS estimate b
^
is negative and significant.
To investigate if antidumping disproportionately affects processing
trade compared to ordinary trade at the extensive margin, we use the
following dependent variable:
Share_Ext
jkt
5
PX_Ext
jkt
PX_Ext
jkt
1 OX_Ext
jkt
, (5.25)
where
PX_Ext
jkt
is the value of processing exports to country j by non-
incumbents in industry k and year t, and
OX_Ext
jkt
is the value of ordinary
exports to country j by non- incumbents in industry k and year t. Similar to
above, we estimate the following regression equation:
Share_Ext
jkt
5 a
k
1 a
t
1 b
*
AD
jkt
1 e
jkt
.
(5.26)
There will be evidence that an antidumping measure disproportionately
affects processing exports at the extensive margin if the OLS estimate
b
^
is
negative and significant.
In Columns 1–3 of Table 5.3, we present the benchmark results for the
share of processing exports in total Chinese exports. The results for the
pooled estimation, intensive margin, and extensive margin are provided
in Columns 1, 2, and 3, respectively. All three specifications include year
and sector fixed effects. We find that antidumping has a negative impact
on the share of processing exports across all three specifications, although
it is only significant at the 10 percent level for the intensive margin. When
incumbent and non- incumbent firms are pooled together, antidumping
reduces the share of processing exports by 3.1 percent. When only incum-
bents are considered (intensive margin), antidumping reduces the share of
processing exports by 2.1 percent. For non- incumbents (extensive margin),
antidumping reduces the share of processing exports by 2.4 percent.
167
Table 5.3 Firm- level estimation results and decomposition using value of exports
Dependent: Share of processing exports in total value of export
Benchmark Domestic OT/
Foreign PT
Domestic OT/Foreign
PT/Import Cut off
Domestic OT/Foreign
PT/Import Cut off/AD
Pooled Intensive Extensive Intensive Extensive Intensive Extensive Intensive Extensive
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
AD −3.13***
(0.834)
−2.07*
(1.147)
−2.41**
(1.176)
−3.247**
(1.402)
−3.271**
(1.361)
−4.021**
(1.420)
−3.569**
(1.373)
−2.451*
(1.468)
−4.449***
(1.401)
Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Sector FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 370 871 91 692 279 179 76 637 217 223 76 250 216 889 28 029 124 457
R
2
0.28 0.44 0.32 0.44 0.33 0.44 0.33 0.46 0.34
Notes:
AD 5 antidumping; FE 5 fixed effects; OT 5ordinary trade regime; PT 5 processing trade regime.
Coefficients are reported with robust standard errors that are clustered at the firm level. Standard errors are given in parentheses. The individual
coefficient is statistically significant at the *10%, **5% or ***1% level.
Source: Authors’ calculations using the Global Antidumping Database and data from the People’s Republic of China’s Customs Statistics.
168 Asia and global production networks
Similar to the provincial- level estimation, we also conducted a number
of robustness tests of our firm- level results. First, in Columns 4–5
of Table 5.3, we solely considered processing exports conducted by
foreign- owned firms and ordinary exports by Chinese- owned firms. The
results are similar to the benchmark findings, but with larger negative
magnitudes of 3.2 percent and 3.3 percent at the intensive and extensive
margin, respectively.
The decision to impose antidumping could be considered endogenous
since the foreign firms that originate from the imposing country may
actively lobby for or against their imposition. To address this possible
endogeneity, we have therefore as a robustness test eliminated from our
data sample any firm that imports more than 5 percent of its imports from
a country that imposes antidumping.
9
The findings in Columns 6–7 of
Table 5.3 suggest that it leads to slightly larger decreases in exports.
Finally, in Columns 8–9, we exclude all industries from our data sample
in which no antidumping was imposed during the entire sample period. In
this case, we find that the coefficient on the antidumping indicator for the
intensive margin is negative as in the benchmark but at only the 10 percent
significance level. The result predicts that the share of processing exports
in total exports by incumbents decreases by 2.5 percent in the presence of
an antidumping measure. The coefficient on the antidumping indicator
for the extensive margin is highly significant and with a larger magnitude
than the benchmark. Specifically, the share of processing exports at the
extensive margin is reduced by 4.5 percent in reaction to antidumping.
In Table 5.4, we estimate our empirical specification using quantities
instead of values. In other words, we use as our dependent variable the
share of processing exports in the total quantity exported for years 2001
to 2005. The results confirm the previous results that antidumping charges
negatively affect the share of processing exports in total exports, at both
the intensive and the extensive margin.
5. CONCLUDING REMARKS
The core idea behind the chapter is that trade policy matters for the organ-
ization of global value chains, a notion that seems to have been neglected
by trade economists, but has major implications for our understanding of
trade and the international transmission of trade policy shocks. To gain
new insights into this research area, we have developed a theoretical model
in which a firm’s ability to spatially separate manufacturing from head-
quarters services gives it the flexibility to circumvent a country- specific
tariff increase by relocating its manufacturing elsewhere, a phenomenon
169
Table 5.4 Firm- level estimation results and decomposition using quantity of export
Dependent: Share of processing exports in total quantity of exports
Benchmark Domestic OT/
Foreign PT
Domestic OT/Foreign
PT/Import Cut off
Domestic OT/Foreign
PT/Import Cut off/AD
Pooled Intensive Extensive Intensive Extensive Intensive Extensive Intensive Extensive
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
AD −2.83***
(0.819)
−2.00*
(1.146)
−2.36**
(1.186)
−3.072**
(1.393)
−2.746**
(1.365)
−3.651**
(1.415)
−2.459*
(1.366)
−3.217**
(1.484)
−3.724**
(1.391)
Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Sector FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 370 224 91 571 278 653 76 537 216 691 76 156 216 358 27 994 124 167
R
2
0.28 0.45 0.32 0.45 0.33 0.45 0.33 0.47 0.34
Notes:
AD 5 antidumping; FE 5 fixed effects; OT 5ordinary trade regime; PT 5 processing trade regime.
Coefficients are reported with robust standard errors that are clustered at the firm level. Standard errors are given in parentheses. The individual
coefficient is statistically significant at the *10%, **5% or ***1% level.
Source: Authors’ calculations using the Global Antidumping Database and data from the People’s Republic of China’s Customs Statistics.
170 Asia and global production networks
that we have termed tariff shirking. We have illustrated a number of
general equilibrium implications of tariff shirking. First, we have shown
that it increases the elasticity of exports within global value chains
to country- specific trade policy shocks by creating an extra extensive
margin effect. Second, we have illustrated that tariff shirking differentially
affects the vulnerability of headquarters services and manufacturing to
country- specific trade policy shocks. Whereas tariff shirking dampens the
vulnerability of headquarters services to trade policy shocks, it amplifies
the vulnerability of manufacturing to trade policy shocks. This last result
is complementary to Bergin et al.’s (2011) finding that offshored assembly
activities in Mexico are more vulnerable to US business cycle shocks than
corresponding US industries.
We used firm- level and province- level export data from the PRC to see
if there is evidence that Chinese exports that are part of global value chains
are more sensitive to antidumping measures than Chinese exports that rely
on domestic value chains. The answer is yes: processing exports that rely
heavily on imported inputs are consistently more sensitive to antidumping
duties than ordinary exports. This result is found to be primarily driven by
an extensive margin effect.
While our empirical results apply only to the PRC, the economic logic is
broader and suggests that tariff shirking may be an important driver of trade
and the international organization of production, and an important deter-
minant of the effectiveness of trade policy. The policy implications of our
analysis are complex. Policymakers may be inclined to try to prevent tariff
shirking and restore the effectiveness of country- specific trade policy barri-
ers by linking them to rules of origin. Such a move, however, would further
increase the administrative complexity of trade and may even end up being
detrimental for a country. As Deardorff (2013) shows, rules of origin can
reduce or even eliminate completely the gains from trade. A policy reaction
that would be more in line with the spirit of the World Trade Organization
would be to step away from discriminatory trade policy barriers, which
are less effective due to tariff shirking, and to focus on non- discriminatory
trade policy barriers that limit the potential of tariff shirking.
NOTES
1. Konings and Vandenbussche (2013) provide evidence that antidumping measures on
imported inputs negatively affect firms’ exports. However, they do not analyze whether
firms react to this through tariff shirking.
2. Escaith and Diakantoni (2012) and Miroudot and Rouzet (2013) use international
input–output matrices to estimate the effective protection rates when components cross
borders multiple times.
Vertical specialization, tariff shirking and trade 171
3. There is a recent literature on export platform FDI that investigates the drivers of a
firm’s decision to conduct FDI in a third country (Ekholm et al., 2007; Grossman et
al., 2006; Ito, 2013; Mrázová and Neary, 2013). However, these studies have mainly
focused on the effect of uniform changes in trade costs across countries, and not on
the effect of country- specific changes in trade costs, therefore ruling out tariff shirking.
Furthermore, they have not considered the implications for the effectiveness of trade
policy.
4. As is well known from previous studies, A
i
5 Y
i
/
[
e
n
i
0
p
i
(
v
)
12 e
dv
]
, where n
i
is the measure
of varieties available in country i and p
i
(v) is the price of variety v in country i. Firms
treat A
i
as fixed since they are too small to individually affect A
i
.
5. Under this condition, the marginal profit of manufacturing a unit in the South exceeds
the marginal profit of manufacturing a unit in the North. One can obtain this condition
by using equation (5.6).
6. Alternatively, we could cut off the productivity at a maximum value.
7. If,
g
,
f
[ (
t
N
t
S
)
e
(
w
N
w
S
)
e2 1
2
1
]
,
it is optimal for all Northern firms to manufacture in the
South. In this unrealistic case, there will be no extra extensive margin effect and the elas-
ticity of bilateral exports with respect to a country- specific tariff change reverts to that of
the case of no vertical specialization.
8. Given our definition of an incumbent, firms would not be considered in this category for
years 2000 and 2006. As such, we dropped these years in our estimation.
9. We would like to thank Laura Puzzello for suggesting this robustness test. The results are
similar for other cut off levels.
REFERENCES
Acemoglu, D., P. Antràs, and E. Helpman (2007), ‘Contracts and technology
adoption’, The American Economic Review, 97, 916–943.
Belderbos, R. and L. Sleuwaegen (1998), ‘Tariff jumping DFI and export substitu-
tion: Japanese electronics firms in Europe’, International Journal of Industrial
Organization, 16, 601–638.
Bergin, P.R., R.C. Feenstra, and G.H. Hanson (2011), ‘Volatility due to offshor-
ing: theory and evidence’, Journal of International Economics, 85, 163–173.
Blinder, Alan S. (2006), ‘Offshoring: the next industrial revolution’, Foreign
Affairs, 85, 113.
Blonigen, Bruce A. (2002), ‘Tariff- jumping antidumping duties’, Journal of Inter-
national Economics, 57, 31–49.
Blonigen, B.A., K. Tomlin, and W.W. Wilson (2004), ‘Tariff- jumping FDI and
domestic firms’ profits’, Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne
d’Économique, 37, 656–677.
Bown, C.P. (2009), ‘Global antidumping database (Current Version 5.0)’, Brandeis
University working paper, available online at www.brandeis.edu/~cbown/
global_ad.
Chaney, T. (2008), ‘Distorted gravity: the intensive and extensive margins of
international trade’, The American Economic Review, 98, 1707–1721.
Cole, M.T. and R.B. Davies (2011), ‘Strategic tariffs, tariff jumping, and heteroge-
neous firms’, European Economic Review, 55, 480–496.
Costinot, A. (2009), ‘On the origins of comparative advantage’, Journal of
Inter national Economics, 77, 255–264.
Deardorff, A.V. (2013), ‘Rue the ROOs: Rules of Origin and the gains (or losses)
from trade agreements’, University of Michigan mimeo.
172 Asia and global production networks
Ekholm, K., R. Forslid, and J.R. Markusen (2007), ‘Export- platform foreign
direct investment’, Journal of the European Economic Association, 5, 776–795.
Escaith, Hubert, and A. Diakantoni (2012), ‘Reassessing effective protection rates
in a trade in tasks perspective: evolution of trade policy in ‘Factory Asia’, World
Trade Organization Economic Research and Statistics Division, Staff Working
Paper ERSD- 2012–13.
Fort, T. (2011), ‘Breaking up is hard to do: Why firms fragment production across
locations’, University of Maryland mimeo.
Fung, V.K., W.K. Fung, and Y.R. Wind (2007), Competing in a Flat World:
Building Enterprises for a Borderless World, Pearson Prentice Hall.
Gamberoni, E., R. Lanz, and R. Piermartini (2010), ‘Timeliness and contract
enforceability in intermediate goods trade’, World Bank Policy Research
Working Paper Series 5482.
Grossman, G.M., E. Helpman, and A. Szeidl (2006), Optimal integration
strategies for the multinational firm’, Journal of International Economics, 70,
216–238.
Grossman, G.M., and E. Rossi- Hansberg (2008), ‘Trading tasks: A simple theory
of offshoring’, American Economic Review, 98, 1978.
Helpman, E., and O. Itskhoki (2010), ‘Labour market rigidities, trade and unem-
ployment’, The Review of Economic Studies, 77, 1100–1137.
Helpman, E., M.J. Melitz, and S.R. Yeaple (2004), ‘Export versus FDI with het-
erogeneous firms’, The American Economic Review, 94, 300–316.
Ito, T. (2013), ‘Export- platform foreign direct investment: theory and evidence’,
The World Economy, 36, 563–581.
Kee, H.L., and H. Tang (2013), ‘Domestic value added in Chinese exports: firm-
level evidence’, mimeo, Johns Hopkins University.
Konings, J. and H. Vandenbussche (2013), ‘Anti- dumping protection hurts export-
ers: firm- level evidence’, Review of World Economics, 149, 295–320.
Koopman, R., Z. Wang, and S.- J. Wei (2012), ‘Estimating domestic content in
exports when processing trade is pervasive’, Journal of Development Economics,
99, 178–189.
Leamer, E.E., and M. Storper (2001), ‘The economic geography of the internet
age’, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 8450.
Levchenko, A.A. (2007), ‘Institutional quality and international trade’, The Review
of Economic Studies, 74, 791–819.
Levy, F., and R.J. Murnane (2003), ‘The skill content of recent technological
change: an empirical exploration’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118,
1279–1333.
Melitz, M.J. (2003), ‘The impact of trade on intra- industry reallocations and
aggregate industry productivity’, Econometrica, 71, 1695–1725.
Miroudot, S., and D. Rouzet (2013), ‘The cumulative impact of trade barriers
along the value chain: an empirical assessment using the OECD inter- country
input–output model’, mimeo, OECD.
Morrow, P., and L. Brandt (2013), ‘Tariffs and the organization of trade in China’,
mimeo, University of Toronto.
Mrázová, M., and J. Neary (2013), ‘Selection effects with heterogeneous firms’,
mimeo, University of Oxford.
Nunn, N. (2007), ‘Relationship- specificity, incomplete contracts, and the pattern
of trade’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122, 569–600.
Schilling, M.A. (2000), ‘Toward a general modular systems theory and its
Vertical specialization, tariff shirking and trade 173
application to interfirm product modularity’, Academy of Management Review,
25, 312–334.
Ulrich, K. (1995), ‘The role of product architecture in the manufacturing firm’,
Research Policy, 24, 419–440.
Van Assche, A. (2012), ‘The rise of global value chains: implications for Canadian
trade and competition policies’, Institute for Research on Public Policy No. 31.
Yi, K.- M. (2003), ‘Can vertical specialization explain the growth of world trade?’,
Journal of Political Economy, 111, 52–102.
174 Asia and global production networks
APPENDIX 5A.1 NO VERTICAL SPECIALIZATION
The elasticity of aggregate exports
X
l
with respect to country- specific tariff
t
l
under no vertical specialization can be separated into an intensive and
an extensive margin effect:
2
dX
l
/
dt
l
X
l
/t
l
5 2
t
l
X
l
a
3
`
f
l
0x
l
(
f
)
0t
l
dG
(
f
)
b
1
t
l
X
l
a
x
l
(
f
l
)
Gr
(
f
l
)
0
f
l
0t
l
b
. (5A.1.1)
Using the definition of equilibrium individual exports from equation (5.5)
and using the assumption that country l is small enough so that a change
in
t
l
does not affect B, we get:
dx
l
(
f
)
dt
l
5 2 e
x
l
t
l
.
Inserting this into (5A.1.1) and rearranging, we obtain:
2
dX
l
/d
t
l
X
l
/
t
l
5 e 1
x
l
(
f
l
)
Gr
(
f
l
)
f
l
X
l
*
t
l
f
l
0f
l
0
t
l
(5A.1.2)
Using the definition of the distribution of productivity shocks
Gr
(
f
)
5
z
f
2
z
2
1
from equation (5.3) and the definition of firm- level exports
from equation (5.5), we can rewrite aggregate exports in the following
way:
X
l
5
3
`
f
l
x
l
(
f
)
dG
(
f
)
5
5
3
`
f
l
B
1 2 a
a
f
w
l
b
e2 1
t
l
2 e
zf
2 z2 1
df
5
1
z
2
(
e 2
1
)
*x
l
(
f
l
)
Gr
(
f
l
)
f
l
.
Inserting this into (5A.1.2), we obtain:
2
dX
l
/d
t
l
X
l
/
t
l
5 e 1
(
z 2
(
e 2 1
))
*
t
l
f
l
0f
l
0
t
l
. (5A.1.3)
From equation (5.7), we can derive that
t
l
f
l
0
f
l
0
t
l
5
e
e 2
1
so that:
Vertical specialization, tariff shirking and trade 175
2
dX
l
X
l
t
l
dt
l
5 e 1
(
z 2
(
e 2 1
))
e
e 2 1
5
ze
e 2 1
. (5A.1.4)
APPENDIX 5A.2 VERTICAL SPECIALIZATION
Elasticity of Aggregate Exports
X
NO
with Respect to Tariff
t
S
We first calculate the elasticity of aggregate exports by Northern firms
that manufacture in the South,
X
NO
,
with respect to tariff
t
S
. The elastic-
ity can once again be separated into an intensive and an extensive margin
effect:
2
dX
NO
/d
t
S
X
NO
/
t
S
5 2
t
S
X
NO
a
3
`
f
NO
0x
NO
(
f
)
0t
S
dG
(
f
)
b
1
t
S
X
NO
a
x
NO
(
f
NO
)
Gr
(
f
NO
)
0f
NO
0t
S
b
.
(5A.2.1)
Using equation (5.12) and using the assumption that country l is small
enough so that a change in
t
S
does not affect B, we get:
dx
NO
(
f
)
dt
S
5 2 e
x
NO
t
S
Inserting this into (5A.2.1) and rearranging, we obtain:
2
dX
NO
/d
t
S
X
NO
/
t
S
5 e 1
x
NO
(
f
NO
)
Gr
(
f
NO
)
f
NO
X
NO
*
df
NO
f
NO
t
S
d
t
S
(5A.2.2)
We can use the definition of firm- level exports from equation (5.12) and
the definition of the distribution of productivity shocks in equation (5.3)
to rewrite aggregate exports in the following way:
X
NO
5
3
`
f
NO
x
NO
(
f
)
dG
(
f
)
5
1
z2
(
e21
)
*x
NO
(
f
NO
)
Gr
(
f
NO
)
f
NO
. (5A.2.3)
Inserting (5A.2.3) into (5A.2.2), we obtain:
2
dX
NO
/d
t
S
X
NO
/
t
S
5 e 1
(
z 2
(
e 2 1
))
*
a
t
S
f
NO
0f
NO
0
t
S
b
(5A.2.4)
176 Asia and global production networks
We can use equation (5.14) to derive the elasticity of the cut-off condition
f
NO
with respect to tariffs:
df
NO
f
NO
t
S
d
t
S
5
e
e 2
1
c
where
c 5
a
w
N
w
S
b
e
2
1
a
t
N
t
S
b
e
a
w
N
w
S
b
e2 1
a
t
N
t
S
b
e
2 1
.
Inserting this elasticity into (5A.2.4) gives:
2
dX
NO
/dt
S
X
NO
/t
S
5 e 1
(
z 2
(
e 2 1
))
e
e 2 1
c. (5A.2.5)
Elasticity of Aggregate Exports
X
N
with Respect to Tariff
t
N
We can next calculate the elasticity of aggregate exports
X
N
with respect
to tariff
t
N
under vertical specialization. The elasticity can once again be
separated into an intensive and an extensive margin effect:
2
dX
N
/
dt
N
X
N
/t
N
5 2
t
N
X
N
a
3
f
NO
f
N
0x
N
(
f
)
0t
N
dG
(
f
)
b
1
t
N
X
N
c
x
N
(
f
N
)
Gr
(
f
N
)
0f
N
0t
N
2 x
N
(
f
NO
)
Gr
(
f
NO
)
0f
NO
0
t
N
d
Using the definition of equilibrium individual exports from equation (5.4)
and using the assumption that country l is small enough so that a change
in
t
N
does not affect B, we get:
dx
N
(
f
)
dt
N
5 2 e
x
N
t
N
.
Inserting this into the above equation and rearranging, we obtain:
2
dX
N
/
dt
N
X
N
/
t
N
5 e1
a
x
N
(
f
N
)
Gr
(
f
N
)
f
N
X
N
*
0
f
N
0
t
N
t
N
f
N
2
x
N
(
f
NO
)
Gr
(
f
NO
)
f
NO
X
N
*
0
f
NO
0
t
N
t
N
f
NO
b
.
(5A.2.6)
Vertical specialization, tariff shirking and trade 177
We have shown above that
0f
N
0
t
N
t
N
f
N
5
e
e 2
1
.
Furthermore, it is straight-
forward to derive from equation (5.14) that:
df
NO
f
NO
t
N
d
t
N
5 2
e
e 2
1
(
c 2 1
)
, 0,
where
c 5
a
w
N
w
S
b
e
2
1
a
t
N
t
S
b
e
a
w
N
w
S
b
e2 1
a
t
N
t
S
b
e
2 1
. 1.
Inserting these cut- off elasticities into (5A.2.6) and rearranging:
2
dX
N
/d
t
N
X
N
/
t
N
5 e 1
e
e 2
1
a
x
N
(
f
N
)
Gr
(
f
N
)
f
N
2
x
N
(
f
NO
)
Gr
(
f
NO
)
f
NO
X
N
b
a
x
N
(
f
N
)
Gr
(
f
N
)
f
N
2
x
N
(
f
NO
)
Gr
(
f
NO
)
f
NO
X
N
1 c*
x
N
(
f
NO
)
Gr
(
f
NO
)
f
NO
X
N
b
(5A.2.7)
Using the definition of firm- level exports from equation (5.5) and the defi-
nition of the distribution of productivity shocks in equation (5.3), we can
rewrite aggregate exports in the following way:
X
N
5
3
f
NO
f
N
x
N
(
f
)
dG
(
f
)
5
1
z2
(
e21
)
*
[
x
N
(
f
N
)
Gr
(
f
N
)
f
N
2x
N
(
f
NO
)
Gr
(
f
NO
)
f
NO
]
.
Inserting this equation into (5A.2.7) and rearranging, we obtain:
2
dX
N
/dt
N
X
N
/t
N
5 e 1
(
z 2
(
e 2 1
))
e
e 2 1
a
1 1 c*
x
N
(
f
NO
)
x
NO
(
f
NO
)
*
x
NO
(
f
NO
)
Gr
(
f
NO
)
f
NO
x
N
(
f
N
)
Gr
(
f
N
)
f
N
2
x
NO
(
f
NO
)
Gr
(
f
NO
)
f
NO
b
. (5A.2.8)
178 Asia and global production networks
Inserting equations (5.5), (5.12), (5A.2.3) and the definition of
c
into
(5A.2.8), we can rearrange the equation to:
2
dX
N
/dt
N
X
N
/t
N
5 e1
(
z2
(
e21
))
e
e21
°
11
X
NO
X
N
*
1
a
w
N
w
S
b
e2 1
a
t
N
t
S
b
e
21
¢
. (5A.2.9)
179
6. Changes in the production stage
position of People’s Republic of
China trade
Deborah Swenson
1. INTRODUCTION
In the discussion of developments in global value chains, the People’s
Republic of China (PRC) has featured front and center due to the effects
of its market reforms, and the country’s 2001 World Trade Organization
(WTO) entry. The PRC’s participation in global value chains has also
attracted note due to the sheer scale of its involvement in international
trade. This attention is certainly warranted due to the heavy involvement
of the country’s imports and exports in the relocation and reorganization
of production through global value chains. However, while the nature of
the PRC’s contributions and connections has been recorded in great detail
in a small number of cases, such as for the Apple iPod, detailed knowledge
of its production structures and the related trade connections for most
products at the same level is rarely available.
In the absence of detailed data on the production of all products, econo-
mists have managed to use other methods for drawing inferences about
shifts in global production by tracking trade in parts and components, or
through the use of input–output tables.
1
Due to the operation of special
processing export policies, PRC trade has yielded further insights into the
developments of global value chains.
2
However, an ongoing assessment
of changes in its production activity is warranted due to major changes in
the country’s economic environment, which include increases in the cost
of labor and changes in technology, as well as changes in production chain
opportunities following its 2001 WTO entry.
3
Further, since Johnson and
Noguera (2012b) and Baldwin and Lopez- Gonzalez (2013) document
large declines in the value added content of trade in recent years, it is
important to evaluate how the trends have been manifested in the PRC’s
engagement in production.
To provide complementary insights about shifts in the trade
180 Asia and global production networks
connections between the PRC and Asia, as well as the rest of the world,
this chapter applies new product- level measures describing the position
of products in the production process to PRC trade. The idea that pro-
duction is conducted through a sequence of steps is easy to visualize,
and has long been embedded as a feature in economic models of interna-
tional production.
4
More recently, the idea of sequential production has
been taken to the data, in the work of Antras and Chor (forthcoming),
Fally (2012a), and Antras et al. (2012). In this work, data on United
States (US) production is used to develop measures that characterize an
industry or product’s place in the production sequence. With this data in
hand, I am able to use this production metric to observe how the char-
acteristics of PRC trade, and trade in intermediates in particular, have
changed in recent years.
5
Analysis of PRC trade growth at the product level between 2001 and
2011 indicates that the stages (number of plant- level steps) embedded in
imports have increased, while the number of stages implicitly contained
in exports have declined. However, this aggregate change reflects both
changes in the composition of trade, as well as changes in sourcing within
industries or within trade- partner relationships. In general, the overall
shift appears to relate tightly to shifts in the industry composition of
Chinese trade.
Naturally, while product level trade grew in the majority of cases, not
all of the country’s trade relationships observed at the product- province-
country- ownership level survived over the decade of observation. For
this reason, I also analyze how the probability of transaction exit was
related to the stages implicitly contained in PRC imports of intermedi-
ates. Here, I find the probability that an import transaction exit is related
to slower levels of export growth. Further, as with expansion of existing
transactions, industry plays a large role in the change in stages. Between
2001 and 2011, the exit of trade transactions was heavily concentrated in
high- stage products for some industries. Similarly, the degree of exit was
heavily concentrated in low- stage products for other industries. Thus,
while we have notions of how technology, income, distance and other
factors contribute to the relocation of production chains, this suggests
that the influences of these factors on sequential stage characteristics or
PRC participation in production chains are anything but uniform across
industries.
The remainder of the chapter is organized as follows. First, to provide
some background the next section introduces the data set and discusses
recent developments in PRC trade. Next, I describe recent measures of
production position – Upstreamness and Stages – and provide a summary
of changes in these measures for PRC trade. The fourth section describes
Changes in the production stage position of PRC trade 181
product trade variety, across countries and industries. The analysis in
sections 5 and 6 is in two parts: the first analysis tests how trade growth
was related to measures of production position, while the second set of
regressions tests how the measures of production position were related to
transaction exit.
2. DEVELOPMENTS IN PRC TRADE
The core data in this project are Chinese import and export transac-
tions for the years 1997 to 2011, which are collected by the General
Administration of Customs. A key strength of these data is the fact that
they include a number of identifiers that enable researchers to observe the
agents, and forms of activity that underpin the trade activities conducted
by firms in the PRC. Further, since the government offers trade policies
that facilitate processing trade, each trade transaction reports the customs
regime under which products enter or exit. While there are a handful of
custom regimes reported in the data, the two forms of organization that
account for the majority of Chinese trade activity are ordinary trade and
processing trade. The latter is especially interesting, since firms engaged in
processing trade by definition procure some of their inputs from abroad
and export all of their output. While the activities of global value chains
are not limited to the use of the processing trade regime, rules governing
the use of the processing trade benefit firms through a number of chan-
nels, including the exemption from tariffs on imported inputs used in
the production of export goods. The operation of the processing trade
regime provides a data trail for research, since the administration of
processing trade requires processing firms to provide separate reports on
their imports of inputs and subsequent export. Thus data from process-
ing firms shed light on the operation of global value chains.
6
Firms that
are not exclusively engaged in export may nonetheless provide or use
inputs or assembly services that are integrated with global value chains.
However, this activity does not qualify firms for tariff reductions on
imported inputs, and at least in the earliest years of this analysis, may
have left firms with less autonomy in their choice and use of imported
inputs.
A second important identifier in the Chinese trade data is the marker
for ownership, which allows researchers to distinguish whether the trade
was conducted by foreign owned enterprises, state owned enterprises, or
private firms. As has been shown by Koopman et al. (2008), as well as by
others, throughout the 2000s the overwhelming majority of processing
trade volume was handled by foreign owned firms, while private firms
182 Asia and global production networks
and state owned enterprises (SOEs) were responsible for the majority of
ordinary trade.
The last noteworthy identifier in the trade data is the information on
the location of the entity that produces the export, or the location that
was responsible for import purchases. While these data are recorded
at a fine geographic level not just city, but zone within the city this
chapter aggregates the data and studies geographic differences in import
or export at the provincial level. As with many national customs collection
systems, the PRC chooses to report transactions at a level of detail that
goes beyond the 6- digit harmonized system (HS) set of codes. However,
since the PRC modified its 8- digit identifiers over the sample period, the
product level component of this project aggregates the transactions data
to the 6- digit level for analysis.
Changes in the Composition of PRC Exports
One notable development has been the shift in industry composition of
exports since the late 1990s. To illustrate the changing industrial compo-
sition, the HS6 product transactions in the data set were assigned to 13
industries based on their 2- digit HS code, and the data were aggregated
to the industry- year level.
7
As the upper panel of Table 6.1 shows, in
both 1997 and 2011 the textile and electronic machinery sectors were the
two sectors that were responsible for the highest shares in total exports.
However, their relative representation flipped during the time interval:
while textiles exports in 1997 were substantially larger than electronics
exports in 1997, the relative importance of the two industries reversed,
with electronics taking a substantial and ongoing lead for the latter years
of the sample period. Since processing exports are known participants
in global value chains, the lower panel of Table 6.1 displays the industry
sector export shares only for processing exports. Similar to the upper
panel for all exports, processing exports also recorded a dramatic reversal
in the relative importance of textiles and electronics. While the textile and
electronics industries were almost at parity, each responsible for roughly
20 percent of processing exports in 1997, by 2011 the share of textiles in
processing exports declined below 5 percent, while the share of process-
ing exports comprised of electrical machinery products rose to almost 35
percent.
The contrast between the importance of textiles and electronics in
overall export as compared with processing export raises an important
issue in the use of processing trade as a lens for observing Chinese
participation in global value chains. The fact that the PRC still had
substantial textile exports while processing exports of textiles declined
Changes in the production stage position of PRC trade 183
precipitously may be attributed to at least two factors. First, since later
in the period textile exports were increasingly provided by the new entry
of private firms in the textile industry, the decline in processing exports
of textiles can be partially explained by the fact that private firms are less
frequently engaged in processing trade than were foreign invested firms.
The other factor that explains the trends in processing trade participa-
tion is the general decline in usage of processing trade. When studying
Table 6.1 Industry shares of Chinese exports and processing exports
1997 2001 2007 2011
Export shares (%)
Textiles 23.7 18.8 13.6 12.7
Electrical machinery 13.5 19.3 24.7 23.5
Non- manufacturing 12.6 9.5 4.9 5.0
Miscellaneous manufacturing 10.5 10.1 9.0 9.0
Non- electrical machinery 7.5 12.6 18.8 9.0
Metals 7.4 6.1 9.5 7.6
Footwear and headgear 5.6 4.6 2.5 2.8
Chemicals and allied industries 5.2 4.8 4.2 5.1
Raw hides, leather and fur 3.4 3.2 1.3 1.6
Plastics and rubber 3.2 3.1 3.0 1.8
Transportation 2.8 3.6 4.5 5.8
Stone, clay and glass 2.8 2.5 2.2 3.2
Wood and wood products 1.9 1.8 1.7 1.6
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Processing export shares (%)
Electrical machinery 21.2 29.0 37.5 34.6
Textiles 20.0 13.7 5.9 4.8
Miscellaneous manufacturing 13.7 12.1 9.6 8.9
Non- electrical machinery 10.3 17.6 27.3 27.6
Footwear and headgear 7.2 4.8 1.8 1.6
Metals 6.8 3.9 2.8 2.3
Plastics and rubber 4.2 4.0 3.6 4.0
Raw hides, leather and fur 4.1 3.1 0.9 0.6
Transportation 3.9 4.0 4.5 7.6
Non- manufacturing 3.7 2.5 2.2 2.1
Stone, clay and glass 2.0 2.0 1.2 3.1
Chemicals and allied industries 1.5 1.8 1.5 1.5
Wood and wood products 1.4 1.3 1.1 1.1
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Source: Author’s calculation.
184 Asia and global production networks
the decline in the share of processing trade in PRC exports, Brandt
and Morrow (2013) document the role of input tariff reductions that
reduced a cost advantage that differentially benefited processing export-
ers relative to ordinary exporters, and the growth in domestic markets.
8
Alternatively, as the variety of domestic inputs increased, and as local
demand expanded, processing trade could have shrunk in importance as
local demand was met by local firm entry rather than processing trade
expansion by foreign owned firms. Thus, while earlier processing trade
data may have provided a relatively comprehensive view of PRC par-
ticipation in global value chains, it is likely that an increasing share of
production sharing activities was moving outside of the processing trade
regime in the later years.
More generally, Table 6.1 shows that the majority of manufacturing
industries had fairly stable export shares over the sample period. However,
the one industry that draws attention for its buoyancy is the transpor-
tation sector, which moved from 2.8 percent to 5.8 percent of overall
exports, and from 3.9 percent to 7.6 percent of processing exports between
1997 and 2011.
For another view of changes in trade composition, the data can be
aggregated by product type, rather than industry composition. Thus to
gain insight into developments in the PRC’s activities within global value
chains, UN Broad Economic Classification (BEC) codes that provide a
mapping between HS6 product codes and good type were used to distin-
guish trade in final goods from trade in intermediate inputs and primary
goods. Further, while parts of the analysis track changes in trade in
intermediate goods, the UN BEC codes can be used further to distinguish
between product trade in parts and components and product trades in
semi- finished goods.
By aggregating processing trade imports and exports by product
type, we can examine the types of products flow into and out of Chinese
processing trade operations to describe how the composition of processing
trade has changed over time. Figure 6.1a, which shows the developments
in processing imports and exports for the five goods categories (capital
goods, consumer goods, parts and components, semi- finished goods and
primary goods), reveals that aside from the downturn during the global
recession, the PRC has managed a sustained growth in its exports of
final goods – growth that is particularly pronounced in the case of capital
goods as compared with the growth in the export of consumer final goods.
Through the entire period, the country was both an importer and an
exporter of intermediate goods; however it was a net importer of both
parts and components and semi- finished goods.
For comparison Figure 6.1b displays the developments in the PRC’s
Changes in the production stage position of PRC trade 185
overall imports and exports of the five goods groups. On the export side,
the growth in overall consumer products exports is more pronounced
than was the growth in consumer products exports by processing trade
firms. One factor for this change, noted by Brandt and Morrow (2013),
was a decline in importance of the processing trade in industry sectors
where input tariffs declined. More important, the data show that the PRC
involvement with intermediate inputs trade extended outside of processing
trade. As with processing trade, import and export of parts and compo-
nents and of semi- finished goods all increased, though the country transi-
tioned from a net importer to a modest net exporter in the semi- finished
goods category, while it retained its status as a net importer in the parts
and components sector. Thus, because the activities of global value chain
type production were not limited to the activities of firms engaged in
processing trade, it appears important when describing the developments
in the country’s participation in global value chains to analyze changes in
both processing and ordinary trade.
9
0
50
100
150
200
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
2011
US$
billion
Consumer goods
0
50
100
150
200
250
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
2011
US$
billion
Parts and components
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
2011
US$
billion
Primary goods
Processing exports
Processing imports
1999
1997
0
100
200
300
400
500
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
2011
Capital goods
US$
billion
Source: Author’s calculation.
Figure 6.1a People’s Republic of China processing trade, 1997–2011
186 Asia and global production networks
3. PRODUCTION STAGES – UPSTREAMNESS AND
STAGES
To search for evidence of shifts in the country’s position in global supply
chains, I turn to new measures of product position developed by Fally
(2012a, 2012b). Conceptually, we can visualize production as involving a
number of steps, as final goods are created through the completion of a
number of tasks. Within this sequential process, a good can be character-
ized by the number of stages or steps that precede or follow the handling
of a particular product. Based on this idea, Fally generates measures of
Upstreamness and Stages. For example, each input handled in a pro-
duction chain will ultimately be handled in a number of steps prior to
completion and sale as a final good. The count of future stages is deemed
upstreamness. Similarly, the creation of each input implies that the input
has already passed through a number of prior steps. When weighted by
the value- added of each step, Fally terms the count of prior steps, stages.
10
Through the use of the US Bureau of Economic Analysis concordances,
Fally links his measures of upstreamness and stages to HS6 products.
In this project, I use HS6 product identifiers to match Fally’s measures
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
2011
US$
billion
Capital goods
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
2011
US$
billion
Consumer goods
0
100
200
300
400
500
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
2011
US$
billion
Parts and components
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
2011
US$
billion
Primary goods
Overall exports
Overall imports
Source: Author’s calculation.
Figure 6.1b People’s Republic of China overall trade, 1997–2011
Changes in the production stage position of PRC trade 187
of stages and upstreamness with Chinese customs data on imports and
exports. While production techniques may not be identical in the US and
the PRC, the connection is used to answer two questions. First, how does
the production chain position of the products traded by the PRC – traded
intermediate products in particular compare with the production chain
position of US- based activities? Second, when the measures are applied to
Chinese trade across the 2000s, is there evidence that the production chain
position of the country’s trade has shifted over time overall, by indus-
try or across countries? Both of these questions are descriptive empiri-
cal inquiries. In particular, while Antras and Chor (forthcoming) test a
property rights model of the firm by examining the connection between
their related measure of downstreamness to ownership and the elasticity of
demand, the connection between product position and trade outcomes is
still a new research endeavor. Further, since Nunn (2007) has shown how
lock- in due to relationship specific investments is especially important in
intermediate inputs, it is not clear whether one would expect to see notice-
able changes in the production position of PRC trade.
11
Thus, this work
will provide some initial evidence on this question.
In contrast with Fally’s observation that US production data in recent
decades has been characterized by a decline in the number of stages, the
PRC’s intermediate imports are characterized by increases in both stages
and upstreamness between 2001 and 2011. For example, if I calculate PRC
stage measures by weighting each HS6 intermediate input import transac-
tion by its dutiable value, the PRC’s measure of stages rose from 2.49 to
2.61 in the decade running from 2001 and 2011. This trend is interesting,
since it suggests that the PRC, in contrast with the US, is participating
in industries that are increasing in stages, rather than declining in stages.
This change could arise from one of two sources. First, changes in relative
production capability could cause Chinese firms to move away from the
processing of low stage items to the processing of higher stage items that
are characterized by handling by a larger number of prior plants. This
would imply that the upstreamness measure should have declined over
the period, since the later receipt of the inputs along the production chain
implies that the completion of the production will require fewer subse-
quent steps to arrive at the end of the production sequence. However, if I
take the same approach, and calculate the weighted average of upstream-
ness for PRC intermediate imports using transaction dutiable values as
weights, these too rose, beginning at a value of 2.84 and ending at 3.18
during the period. Taken together, this evidence suggests that the PRC
was moving into production processes that involved production chains of
increasing length.
12
Next, to better understand the trends in PRC values of the stages and
188 Asia and global production networks
upstreamness measures, I provide more systematic disaggregation of
Chinese imports, noting differential trends across different groups of
trade. I apply Fally’s measures to import data, and examine how they
differ by type of importer (processing firms versus ordinary firms), and
by industry. In Table 6.2, I begin by presenting information on aggregate
shifts in the measures for processing and ordinary imports between 1997
and 2011. As the first two rows show, the average stages of all processing
imports declined between 1997 and 2011, whether the average is computed
as the average across all transactions, or the average across all transac-
tions weighted by the dutiable values of import. In a similar evaluation of
average upstreamness, the evidence is mixed. However, when the process-
ing trade observations are weighted by dutiable transaction value, the data
show that the number of stages subsequent to the receipt of the import
declined between 1997 and 2011.
However, one problem with upstreamness or stages measures based on
the universe of imports is the fact that they combine both intermediate
inputs and raw materials. Alternatively, the measures may also change
over time due to the inclusion of capital goods imports. Thus, to isolate
changes related to the use of intermediates, the bottom rows of Table 6.2
recalculate average upstreamness and stages, using data only on imported
intermediates. Under this new metric, the data now suggest that imported
Table 6.2 Import upstreamness and stages by trade type
Upstreamness Stages
1997 2001 2007 2011 1997 2001 2007 2011
All Imports
Processing trade 2.52 2.58 2.55 2.53 2.45 2.45 2.42 2.39
Processing trade (weighted) 2.69 2.73 2.55 2.52 2.48 2.41 2.35 2.31
Ordinary trade 2.26 2.42 2.42 2.39 2.37 2.32 2.30 2.29
Ordinary trade (weighted) 2.69 2.79 3.11 3.21 2.39 2.34 2.26 2.42
Intermediate input imports
Processing trade 2.66 2.59 2.78 2.58 2.47 2.34 2.44 2.42
Processing trade (weighted) 2.81 2.84 3.12 2.83 2.51 2.35 2.45 2.41
Ordinary trade 2.59 2.59 3.09 2.57 2.34 2.47 2.31 2.31
Ordinary trade (weighted) 2.78 3.30 3.44 3.42 2.41 2.35 2.26 2.23
Note: For each product group, the first row represented the unweighted average, while
the second row denoted (weighted) is the mean value for Upstreamness or Stages, when
dutiable import transaction values are used as weights.
Source: Author’s calculation.
Changes in the production stage position of PRC trade 189
intermediates have gone through more stages prior to their import for
Chinese processing. It also suggests that the products imported by PRC
processors are closer to final demand than before, since the number of
stages characterizing processing trade imported inputs declined between
1997 and 2011.
For a different view on upstreamness and stages, Table 6.3 presents
measures based on imported intermediate inputs that were sourced from
different regions. In the case of processing imports of intermediates,
Table 6.3 Upstreamness and stages for intermediates trade by source
region
All intermediate imports
Upstreamness Stages
2000 2011 2000 2011
Japan 2.73 2.74 2.45 2.42
ASEAN 5 2.95 3.10 2.51 2.68
Republic of Korea and Taipei,China 2.96 3.00 2.62 2.59
NAFTA 2.87 2.89 2.48 2.50
European Union 28 2.47 2.61 2.36 2.39
Australia and New Zealand 2.94 3.20 2.41 2.46
Processing intermediate imports
Japan 2.59 2.66 2.41 2.37
ASEAN 5 2.81 2.82 2.38 2.54
Republic of Korea and Taipei,China 2.74 2.77 2.56 2.49
NAFTA 2.77 2.92 2.31 2.49
EU28 2.53 2.74 2.36 2.47
Australia and New Zealand 3.05 3.23 2.46 2.44
Ordinary intermediate imports
Japan 2.97 2.80 2.55 2.42
ASEAN 5 3.08 3.27 2.67 2.78
Republic of Korea and Taipei,China 3.33 3.00 2.75 2.59
NAFTA 2.92 2.91 2.55 2.52
European Union 28 2.49 3.20 2.37 2.46
Australia and New Zealand 2.90 3.05 2.38 2.45
Notes:
ASEAN 5 5 Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore and Thailand.
Regional values are weighted averages that use trade transaction values as weights. Values
in 2011 columns are listed in bold if the value increased between 2000 and 2011.
Source: Author’s calculation.
190 Asia and global production networks
upstreamness increased for all regional groups, without exception. In
contrast, stages increased between 1997 and 2011 in three of the six cases.
Notably, the regional dimension for ordinary trade is somewhat different,
as the increase in upstreamness and stages was present in only three of
the six sources. Nonetheless, since processing and ordinary firms special-
ized in somewhat different industries, the differences might reflect such
composition differences, rather than differences in sourcing preferences.
To determine whether processing versus ordinary firm sourcing choices
differed by industry, Table 6.4 presents information on the stages charac-
terizing import of intermediates for processing and by ordinary importers
disaggregated by industry. The striking result here is the tight correspond-
ence between the values recorded for processing and ordinary trade by
industry. While the relative importance of stages for processing and ordi-
nary exports varies by industry, this suggests that the profit maximizing
organization of production chain input use did not differ significantly for
processing versus ordinary firms.
Table 6.4 Industry input import stages, by trade type
Stages
All
intermediates
import
Processing
intermediates
import
Ordinary
intermediates
import
2000 2011 2000 2011 2000 2011
Non- manufacturing 2.02 2.01 2.04 1.91 2.01 2.01
Chemicals and allied industries 2.70 2.80 2.56 2.72 2.76 2.81
Plastics and rubber 2.86 2.76 2.85 2.77 2.89 2.80
Raw hides, leather and fur 3.25 3.21 3.25 3.19 3.23 3.25
Wood and wood products 2.42 2.48 2.40 2.43 2.43 2.50
Textiles 2.67 2.65 2.67 2.68 2.64 2.66
Footwear and headgear 2.14 2.13 2.14 2.13 2.15 2.14
Stone, clay and glass 2.20 2.28 2.26 2.28 2.04 2.28
Metals 2.46 2.51 2.46 2.49 2.47 2.49
Non- electrical machinery 2.32 2.29 2.23 2.41 2.25 2.22
Electrical machinery 2.18 2.16 2.20 2.17 2.16 2.15
Transportation 2.41 2.44 2.37 2.38 2.45 2.47
Miscellaneous manufacturing 2.13 2.17 2.10 2.18 2.19 2.21
Overall 2.41 2.28 2.48 2.41 2.34 2.22
Note: Industry values are weighted averages that use trade transaction values as weights.
Values in 2011 column are listed in bold if the value increased between 2000 and 2011.
Source: Author’s calculation.
Changes in the production stage position of PRC trade 191
If changes in upstreamness or stages were driven solely by macro or
country factors, such as increases in assembly costs or changes in transpor-
tation charges, we would expect the changes in stages to be similar across
industries. However, comparison of trends in Table 6.4 reveals that stages
rose in six of the thirteen industries, while they declined in the remaining
industries. If the trends are evaluated using only processing or ordinary
trade, the industries that had rising stage imports in the case of processing
intermediate input imports were the same industries that also had ordinary
imports of intermediates that were characterized by rising stages. Thus, it
appears that fundamental changes in technology or organizational form
were more important in determining the trend in stages than general
macroeconomic factors.
For a last comparison, it is worth asking how trends in upstreamness
and stages for export of intermediate inputs compared with the values
observed in their imports. Notably, among intermediate inputs both
stages and upstreamness were declining. When weighted by the export
value of each HS6 intermediate input, the number of stages fell from 2.49
in 2000 to 2.40 in 2011, while the value of upstreamness declined from 2.83
to 2.60.
13
4. IMPORTED INPUT PRODUCT VARIETY
To provide another view on sourcing changes over time, I examine
changes in input diversity and input sourcing. A simple way to measure
input diversity is to count the number of unique HS6 products imported
by firms in the PRC. While the trade transactions are initially recorded at
the 8- digit level, the use of 8- digit PRC trade data is complicated by the
fact that the HS8 code lexicon was increased over the period of study. To
avoid the appearance of product introductions that were actually created
by innovations or modifications in the trade classification system, it is
safer to remain instead with counts based on HS6 codes.
On the import side, Table 6.5 demonstrates that between 1997 and
2011, both PRC processing and ordinary firms reduced the diversity of
their imports based on HS6 codes. However, since we are interested in the
operation of global value chains, it makes sense to track developments in
the import of intermediates and capital goods. Again, the data in Table 6.5
show that import diversity measured by unique product counts declined
between 1997 and 2011 for both processing and ordinary trade. However,
one possibility is that firms reduced the range of imported intermediates
and capital goods, as they moved out of unprofitable or unsuccessful
export product lines. Consistent with this conjecture, counts of unique
192 Asia and global production networks
HS6 export product lines contracted for both processing and ordinary
exporters.
14
Naturally, the use of HS6 counts at the national level is overly coarse
given the scale of the PRC’s economic activity. As an alternative, Table 6.5
also shows how unique counts of HS6- Province activities changed over the
time period. When geographic detail is added, the spread of ordinary trade
across provinces is evidenced by the 50 percent increase over the period in
the number of HS6- province ordinary transactions. In the case of process-
ing, the concentration of producers in a more limited number of provinces
is evidenced in the smaller counts. Most notable is the decrease in distinct
processing trade transactions, whether recorded for imports, imported
intermediates and capital goods, or exports.
The earlier data characteristics presented in Table 6.1 show that the indus-
try composition of processing trade has changed over the sample period.
Since the predominance of textile exports over non- electrical machinery
and electrical machinery activities was overturned by 2011, I check to see
whether the change in input sourcing diversity was related to industry
composition. To illustrate industry trends in the sourcing of intermediates
and capital goods, Table 6.6 presents the counts of HS6 products for these
Table 6.5 Unique transactions — processing and ordinary trade
Unique HS6 products Unique HS6 province
Processing Ordinary Processing Ordinary
Imports
1997 4 445 4 824 30 819 41 882
2001 4 309 4 865 28 787 51 478
2007 4 042 4 800 28 787 57 997
2011 3 891 4 801 27 267 61 277
Imported intermediate and capital goods
1997 3 441 3 634 26 643 33 751
2001 3 342 3 678 24 653 41 654
2007 3 157 3 632 25 189 47 030
2011 2 950 3 471 22 921 46 767
Exports
1997 3 996 4 835 19 278 56 191
2001 3 705 4 882 16 309 65 629
2007 3 693 4 795 18 427 77 698
2011 3 366 4 719 16 524 77 119
Source: Author’s calculation.
Changes in the production stage position of PRC trade 193
major industries. What is notable about the table is that there is no evidence
of a shrinking range of inputs purchased by the textile industry, while the
reduction in input range observed in the non- electrical machinery industry
is small and the reductions for the electrical machinery industry are moder-
ate. For this reason, the reduction in the range of HS6 products cannot be
blamed on the decline in the importance of textile production. Further, to
the extent that there were industry trends in the diversity of inputs sourced,
the trends were similar for both ordinary and processing traders. One likely
cause of the similarity is that developments in Chinese production of inputs
allowed the country’s firms to increase domestic content in production as
documented by Kee and Tang (2012). Thus, as new parts became available
domestically, it would have enabled both processing and ordinary export-
ing firms to replace imported varieties with local varieties.
Finally, for an alternative geographic approach, it is also possible to
track unique HS6- source region counts for processing and ordinary trade
in intermediates and capital goods. The counts, which are reported in
Table 6.7, reveal some modest shifts in the location of sourcing. First,
while the count of distinct intermediate inputs imported from Japan,
Hong Kong, China, the Republic of Korea and Taipei,China decreased
between 1997 and 2011, the counts for most other regions remained stable
or decreased. In the case of capital goods imports, the diversity of capital
goods declined across all regions. Here too, the fact that export of capital
goods expanded rapidly during this time period suggests that PRC firms
had the option of replacing imported capital goods with newly developed
local varieties.
Table 6.6 Imported intermediate and capital goods by industry –
processing and ordinary trade
1997 2001 2007 2011
Textiles
Processing HS6 500 497 496 481
Ordinary HS6 464 484 500 499
Non- electrical machinery
Processing HS6 336 314 333 319
Ordinary HS6 244 248 224 197
Electrical machinery
Processing HS6 238 232 218 188
Ordinary HS6 244 248 224 197
Source: Author’s calculation.
194 Asia and global production networks
5. ANALYSIS OF PRODUCT LEVEL TRADE DATA–
PRODUCTION POSITION AND PRC TRADE
GROWTH
To determine whether PRC imports and exports involve products that are
characterized by changing positions, as determined by Fally’s stages or
upstreamness measures, I implement a few simple estimating frameworks.
This begins with equations (6.1A) and (6.1B).
Dln
(
Import
)
pcho
5 b
1
Stages
Upstreamness
1 b
2
ln
(
Import, 2000
)
pcho
1 y
pcho
(6.1A)
Table 6.7 Imported intermediate inputs and capital goods by source
region, HS6 counts
1997 2001 2007 2011
Intermediate inputs imports
Hong Kong, China 3 014 2 962 1 938 1 546
Japan 2 728 2 741 2 718 2 556
ASEAN 5 2 123 2 265 2 284 2 135
Republic of Korea and
Taipei,China
2 687 2 714 2 662 2 504
NAFTA 2 503 2 550 2 703 2 622
European Union 28 2 639 2 748 2 808 2 704
Australia and New Zealand 1 205 1 365 1 731 1 596
Rest of the world 2 346 2 422 2 776 2 684
Capital goods imports
Hong Kong, China 648 642 395 314
Japan 629 620 598 542
ASEAN 5 507 530 459 396
Republic of Korea and
Taipei,China
600 596 574 519
NAFTA 607 626 603 551
European Union 28 618 637 627 571
Australia and New Zealand 342 369 401 342
Rest of the world 543 550 546 530
Notes:
ASEAN 5 5 Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore and Thailand; HS 5
harmonized system; NAFTA 5 North American Free Trade Agreement.
Number of unique HS6 codes of intermediates or capital goods.
Source: Author’s calculation.
Changes in the production stage position of PRC trade 195
Dln
(
Import
)
pcho
5
a
s
p
1
a
l
c
1
a
x
i
1
a
m
o
1 b
1
Stages
Upstreamness
1 b
2
ln
(
Import, 2000
)
pcho
1 y
pcho
(6.1B)
The dependent variable, D
ln
(
Import
)
,
which measures the change in
import value between 2000 and 2011, has subscripts,
pcho,
referring to
the province (p), country (c), hs6 good (h), and ownership type (o) of
each trade transaction.
15
To determine whether import growth differed
by product position in the value chain, each regression includes Fally’s
measure of either stages or upstreamness. For scaling, each observation
of changes in import value is also related to the import value in the initial
year, D
ln
(
Import, 2000
)
.
Due to unmeasured features that may have influenced changes in import,
the specifications beginning with (6.1B) also include a large set of fixed
effects, the first of which,
d
p
,
is province. This control is intended to capture
differences in provincial participation in international trade that arose
from factors such as differences in provincial endowments, geography,
and policy. For example, Defever and Riaño (2012) note the importance
of policy interventions, such as free trade zones at the subnational level in
the PRC, as factors that contributed to the unusually strong presence of
pure exporters firms whose exports comprised 90 percent or more of sales.
Others, including Lu et al. (2012), have suggested that the PRC is a lumpy
country. If so, the failure of factor price equalization within the country due
to dramatic differences in local endowments will influence regional speciali-
zation patterns. Further, as noted by Head et al. (2011), there is evidence
of provincial differences in sourcing choices, which suggests that provincial
differences in foreign direct investment (FDI) connections may establish
differential choices in the sourcing of intermediates. Thus, fixed effects for
provinces are meant to account for these factors and other elements that
may have caused unevenness in the growth of trade across the country.
The regression specifications also include fixed effects for firm owner-
ship type,
m
o
.
This set of fixed effects distinguishes between firms that
had foreign involvement (foreign owned firms and joint ventures), as
compared with the other main ownership types: state- owned enterprises
and private firms. The use of these indicators is justified by the differential
capabilities and opportunities that were available to firms in each of these
three ownership groups.
16
Country fixed effects
l
c
,
are added to capture differences in country trade
opportunities over time that were related to changes in income, exchange
rates, policy and other factors over the analysis period 2001–2011. Finally,
to capture differences in industry trends and opportunities, the fixed
196 Asia and global production networks
effects regressions include controls for industry,
x
i
.
When classifying each
transaction as a member of an industry, the transactions HS6 codes were
assigned to the industry categories, as described in Appendix Table 6A.1.
Table 6.8a illustrates how during 2001–2011 changes in PRC imports
of intermediates and overall imports were related to Fally’s stages and
upstreamness measures. In the case of imports, the results show that
imports of HS6 products that were characterized by higher values of stages
or upstreamness grew more rapidly than did HS6 product imports that
were lower on either of these scales. In the case of the stages measure, the
strength of this correlation was stronger for intermediate input imports
than it was for overall imports.
Next, to evaluate whether HS6 product export growth was systemati-
cally related to Fally’s (2012b) measures of upstreamness or stages, analo-
gous regression specifications were applied to changes in Chinese exports
of intermediate products and overall exports.
Dln
(
Export
)
pcho
5 b
1
Stages
Upstreamness
1b
2
ln
(
Export, 2000
)
pcho
1 y
pcho
(6.2A)
Dln
(
Export
)
pcho
5
a
s
p
1
a
l
c
1
a
x
i
1
a
m
o
(6.2B)
1 b
1
Stages
Upstreamness
1 b
2
ln
(
Export, 2000
)
pcho
1 y
pcho
When these specifications are used to examine the country’s export
growth, the results in Table 6.8b show that exports grew less rapidly in
sectors that were characterized by higher values of stages or upstreamness.
Thus the relationship between upstreamness or stages and export growth
was directly opposite to the correlations describing import growth.
While the initial results provide an overview of general trade trends based
on the full sample with ownership firm type fixed effects to control for
general differences in firm trade by firm ownership, it is possible that firm
ownership may have affected firm propensity to expand the import or export
of higher stage items. Thus, in the first three columns of Tables6.9a and
6.9b, the imports and exports of intermediate inputs are analyzed separately
for each of the three major firm ownership types: foreign owned, SOEs and
private firms.
17
Similar to the overall results in Tables6.8a and 6.8b, the new
regressions show that stages were positively related to import growth and
negatively related to export growth, regardless of firm ownership. However,
the correlation between stages and intermediates trade growth was stronger
for both exports and imports in the case of private firms than the correlation
for trade transactions that were handled by foreign firms.
Since differential trade growth could also be manifested along
197
Table 6.8a Stages/upstreamness and changes in Chinese imports, 2000–2011
All imports Imported intermediates
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Stages 0.148*** 0.357*** 0.255*** 0.401***
−0.027 −0.032 −0.031 −0.039
Upstreamness 0.183*** 0.308*** 0.267*** 0.242***
−0.01 −0.012 −0.015 −0.016
ln (Import_2000) −0.556*** −0.559*** −0.544*** −0.549*** −0.597*** −0.599*** −0.576*** −0.576***
−0.003 −0.003 −0.003 −0.003 −0.003 −0.003 −0.003 −0.003
Controls Industry Industry Industry Industry
Country Country Country Country
Province Province Province Province
Firm Type Firm Type Firm Type Firm Type
N 128 571 128 571 128 571 128 571 85 156 85 156 85 156 85 156
Adjusted R
2
0.262 0.264 0.364 0.366 0.283 0.285 0.385 0.386
Note: Standard errors in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Source: Author’s calculation.
198
Table 6.8b Stages/upstreamness and changes in Chinese exports, 2000–2011
All exports Exported intermediates
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Stages −0.280*** −0.408*** −0.486*** −0.358***
−0.033 −0.038 −0.038 −0.046
Upstreamness −0.503*** −0.389*** −0.344*** −0.240***
−0.012 −0.014 −0.017 −0.019
ln (Exports_2000) −0.865*** −0.852*** −0.865*** −0.857*** −0.826*** −0.827*** −0.820*** −0.819***
−0.003 −0.003 −0.003 −0.003 −0.004 −0.004 −0.004 −0.004
Controls Industry Industry Industry Industry
Country Country Country Country
Province Province Province Province
Firm Type Firm Type Firm Type Firm Type
N 110 489 110 489 110 489 110 489 70 049 70 049 70 049 70 049
Adjusted R
2
0.451 0.459 0.521 0.524 0.425 0.426 0.495 0.496
Note: Standard errors in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Source: Author’s calculation.
Changes in the production stage position of PRC trade 199
geographic lines, Tables 6.9a and 6.9b also test whether the correlation
between growth in intermediates imports and exports and the measure
of stages differed for different country regions. For this examination,
I report the regressions for three country groups: (1) the Republic of
Korea and Taipei,China, (2) Association of Southeast Asian Nations
(ASEAN) and (3) rich countries (Japan, the US, Canada, European
Union 28, Australia, and New Zealand). In the case of imported inputs,
import growth for all three country groups was most rapid for HS6
products that were characterized by higher levels of stages. However,
since the correlation is especially strong for the first two groups located
in Asia, as compared with the rich country aggregate, it appears that
nearby Asian locations were increasing their supply share of higher stage
intermediates.
In the case of intermediate exports, Table 6.8b indicates there was a
negative correlation between stages and export growth in the full sample.
However, in Table 6.9b the separate regressions for each of the geographic
regions provide no single response. Similar to the full sample, the data show
that the export growth to rich countries was much slower in high stage inter-
mediate products than it was in HS6 products that had lower values of the
Table 6.9a Stages and changes in Chinese imports of intermediates:
differences by firm ownership and source region, 2000–2011
By firm ownership By source region
(1)
Foreign
invested
enterprise
(2)
State-
owned
enterprise
(3)
Private
enterprise
(4)
Republic of
Korea and
Taipei,China
(5)
ASEAN
(6)
Rich
countries
Stages 0.116** 0.857*** 0.705*** 0.722*** 0.953*** 0.125***
−0.049 −0.072 −0.119 −0.075 −0.136 −0.048
ln (Imports_2000) −0.571*** −0.563*** −0.697*** −0.604*** −0.597*** −0.576***
−0.005 −0.006 −0.010 −0.006 −0.013 −0.004
Controls Industry Industry Industry Industry Industry Industry
Country Country Country Country Country Country
Province Province Province Province Province Province
Firm Type Firm Type Firm Type
N 50 170 24 774 10 212 25 397 7 116 51 410
Adjusted R
2
0.359 0.347 0.496 0.429 0.324 0.357
Note: Standard errors in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Source: Author’s calculation.
200 Asia and global production networks
stage measure. In contrast, there is no apparent correlation in the case of
exported intermediates destined for ASEAN countries, while the correlation
with exports to Taipei,China and the Republic of Korea group was positive.
The demand for imported intermediates is linked, in part, to the demand
for those inputs in the production of exports. Thus, the estimating equa-
tion is further changed to include the contemporaneous, 2000 to 2011,
change in export demand according to regression equation (6.3).
D
ln
(
Export
)
pcho
5
a
s
p
1
a
l
c
1
a
x
i
1
a
m
o
1 b
1
Stages
1 b
2
ln
(
Import, 2000
)
pcho
1 b
3
D
ln
(
Export
)
1 y
pcho
(6.3)
Table 6.10 first demonstrates the results of estimating this new equa-
tion with different measures of the change in export, beginning with
industry- province (ip) export changes, followed by industry- province-
ownership (ipo) changes in export. As expected, either export measure
is positively related to changes in intermediates export, and the esti-
mated coefficient on stages is similar regardless of the export measure.
Table 6.9b Stages and changes in Chinese exports of intermediates:
differences by firm ownership and destination region,
2000–2011
By firm ownership By destination region
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Foreign
invested
enterprise
State-
owned
enterprise
Private
enterprise
Republic of
Korea and
Taipei,China
ASEAN Rich
countries
Stages −0.369*** −0.008 −1.009*** 0.184** −0.041 −0.716***
−0.066 −0.077 −0.11 −0.083 −0.129 −0.063
ln (Exports_2000) −0.778*** −0.852*** −0.923*** −0.756*** −0.833*** −0.855***
−0.006 −0.007 −0.009 −0.007 −0.010 −0.005
Controls Industry Industry Industry Industry Industry Industry
Country Country Country Country Country Country
Province Province Province Province Province Province
Firm Type Firm Type Firm Type
N 37 291 22 433 10 325 22 098 7 979 38 504
Adjusted R
2
0.419 0.527 0.596 0.422 0.51 0.502
Note: Standard errors in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.
Source: Author’s calculation.
Changes in the production stage position of PRC trade 201
Table 6.10 Stages and changes in Chinese intermediate imports:
controlling for export demand, 2000–2011
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
ln (Imports_2000) −0.576*** −0.576*** −0.576*** −0.577*** −0.580***
−0.003 −0.003 −0.003 −0.003 −0.003
∆ln (Exports_All_ip) 0.096*** 0.015
−0.026 −0.029
∆ln (Exports_All_ipo) 0.105*** 0.101***
−0.015 −0.017
∆ln (Exports_Fin_ipo) −0.027*** −0.027***
−0.006 −0.006
∆ln (Exports_Int_ipo) −0.011* −0.003
−0.006 −0.006
∆ln (Exports_Cap_ipo) 0.017*** 0.011**
−0.006 −0.006
Stages 0.400*** 0.403*** 0.403*** 0.397*** 0.377
−0.039 −0.039 −0.039 −0.039 −0.263
*Chemicals −0.351
−0.273
*Plastics 1.081***
−0.274
*Furs 0.403
−0.558
*Wood 0.926***
−0.297
*Textile −0.611**
−0.297
*Footwear −1.153
−1.503
*Stoneware
and glass
0.541
−0.387
*Metals −0.318
−0.282
*Machinery −1.604***
−0.317
*Electrical
machinery
−0.912***
−0.297
*Transport
equipment
0.870
−0.664
*Miscellaneous 2.741***
manufacturing −0.394
N 85 142 85 142 85 142 85 142 85 142
Adjusted R
2
0.385 0.386 0.386 0.386 0.389
Notes: Standard errors in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. Regressions
include fixed effects for country, ownership, industry, and province.
Source: Author’s calculation.
202 Asia and global production networks
Nonetheless, the fact that the regression fit is somewhat better when
the industry- province- ownership (ipo) measures of export changes are
included suggests that trade decisions which link imports to exports are
tied to firm ownership type.
To further explore the connection between intermediates import and
provincial export, I generate three industry- province export measures.
The first measures changes in exports of final consumption goods
(∆
Exports
_
Fin
_
ipo
), the second measures changes in exports of inter-
mediate goods (∆
Exports
_
Int
_
ipo
), and the last measures changes in the
export of capital goods (∆
Exports
_
Cap
_
ipo
).
18
When the export data are
delineated along these usage lines, the association between intermediates
import and industry- province- ownership export reveals some interesting
differences. First, the strong positive association between intermediates
import and export is only apparent in the case of capital goods export.
In contrast, there is a negative association in the case of final consumer
goods and intermediates export. Nonetheless, while the coefficients on
each form of export demand differ dramatically, the estimated coef-
ficient on stages is almost identical to the value of stages coefficients in
the earlier regressions. Thus, even when controlling for different meas-
ures of export demand, the general finding remains: Chinese imports of
intermediate inputs have indeed been more rapid in higher- stage HS6
products.
The final column in Table 6.10 modifies regression equation (6.3) to
allow the coefficient on stages to differ across industries. This improves
the regression fit, and reveals considerable cross- industry differences in
the correlation between intermediates import and the measure of stages.
First, the correlations are strongly negative, and highly significant for
the textiles, non- electrical machinery and electrical machinery sectors.
Since these sectors were among the largest export sectors of the country,
it suggests that the negative correlation might be related to industry scale.
In contrast, large positive and significant correlations between interme-
diates import growth and stages are observed in the wood, plastics and
miscellaneous manufacturing sectors.
6. ANALYSIS OF PRODUCT LEVEL TRADE DATA –
TRANSACTION EXIT
While the initial regressions show how the stages characteristics of PRC
imports and exports, and imports of intermediates in particular, changed
between 2000 and 2011, the initial analysis is focused on trade relation-
ships that continued over the sample period. For this reason, the initial
Changes in the production stage position of PRC trade 203
regressions provide insight into the changing composition of trade for
products that were traded in all years. However, many trade transactions
observed in 2000 were not present in 2011. Thus, we can gain further
information on the changing composition of Chinese intermediate imports
by evaluating the characteristics that predisposed some of the original
transactions to end, while others continued 11 years later.
An overview of the product data suggests that PRC imports of inter-
mediates and capital goods were moving from lower stage to higher stage
HS6 products. For example, of the 3442 distinct HS6 intermediates and
capital goods imports recorded in 1997, the average value of stages for
the 563 HS6 products that were not imported in 2011 was 2.40, while the
average value of stages for the 2879 products that were imported in both
years was 2.45. Further, between 1997 and 2011 the PRC started to import
202 HS6 intermediate and capital goods products that it did not import in
1997. The average value of stages for this group was higher yet, at 2.56.
Thus, it appears that the product composition of the country’s import of
intermediates and capital goods was moving toward higher stage products.
To determine whether production stage helped to predict whether a
trade relationship would end, specification (6.4) examines the probability
that a particular trade transaction was terminated. The dependent variable
for this exercise is the dichotomous variable EXIT.
Prob
(
EXIT
)
pcho
5
a
s
p
1
a
l
c
1
a
x
i
1
a
m
o
(6.4)
1 b
1
Stages
1 b
2
ln
(
Import, 2000
)
pcho
1b
3
D
ln
(
Export
)
ipo
1y
pcho
Beginning with the universe of intermediate input import transactions
observed in 2000 at the province- industry- firmownership- hs6 (p- i- o- hs6)
level the indicator variable EXIT is set to 0 for p- i- o- hs6 transactions that
were also observed in 2011, and 1 for all cases where the p- i- o- hs6 trans-
action was not observed in 2011. However, since HS6 codes were refined
over the sample period, some ongoing trade transactions were recorded
under different HS6 headings in different years. Thus, to avoid the poten-
tial of classifying an ongoing transaction as an exit, HS6 codes were first
converted to a single HS6 classification using the World Bank concord-
ance for HS6 codes.
19
The variable stages is included in the regression to
learn whether the risk of exit was higher for some production stages than
others. The remaining regressors and fixed effects in specification (6.4) are
similar to those used to describe changes in import or export value.
The basic results are in Table 6.11. First, in columns 1–4, the basic
regression is run first for all Chinese imports, followed by individual
regressions run for import of intermediate inputs, capital goods and final
204
Table 6.11 Stages and the probability of exit from import
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
All Intermed Capgood Final Intermed Intermed Intermed
Stages 0.443*** 0.581*** - 0.074* 0.234*** 0.633*** 0.633*** −0.102*
−0.010 −0.013 −0.041 −0.027 −0.016 −0.016 −0.058
*ASEAN −0.112***
−0.021
*Rich 0.106***
−0.021
*Chemicals 0.418***
−0.062
*Plastics 0.689***
−0.067
*Furs −0.018
−0.222
*Wood 1.169***
−0.078
*Textile 1.109***
−0.077
*Footwear 0.394
−0.489
*Stoneware
& glass
−0.355***
−0.115
*Metals 1.642***
−0.068
*Machinery 1.668***
−0.091
205
*Electrical 0.207***
Machinery −0.075
*Transport −0.587***
Equipment −0.217
*Miscellaneous −1.169***
manufacturing −0.121
ln (Imports_2000) −0.078*** −0.076*** −0.069*** −0.088*** −0.076*** −0.076*** −0.081***
−0.001 −0.001 −0.002 −0.003 −0.001 −0.001 −0.001
∆ln (Exports_All_ipo) −0.052*** −0.050*** −0.033*** −0.036*** −0.050*** −0.050*** −0.052***
−0.004 −0.005 −0.008 −0.010 −0.005 −0.005 −0.005
N 261 233 165 795 48 809 39 140 165 795 165 795 165 795
Log likelihood −143 000 −89 200 −26 800 −20 300 −89 200 −89 200 −88 200
Notes:
Capgood 5 capital goods; Intermed 5 intermediate goods.
Standard errors in parentheses. * p , 0.10, ** p , 0.05, *** p , 0.01. Each regression has fixed effects that control for industry, country, province,
and firm ownership type.
Source: Author’s calculation.
206
Table 6.12 Industry exit from import of intermediates, by industry, 2000–2011
(1)
Machinery
(2)
Electronics
(3)
Transport
(4)
Miscellaneous
manufacturing
(5)
Textiles
(6)
Footwear
Stages
*Hong Kong,
China
1.136*** 0.493*** 0.661 −0.835*** 1.885*** 1.136***
−0.205 −0.128 −0.682 −0.259 −0.130 −0.205
*ASEAN5 0.839*** −0.428** −1.508* −0.073 −1.158*** 0.839***
−0.270 −0.17 −0.859 −0.367 −0.171 −0.270
*Japan 0.120 −0.158 −1.722* −0.558 −0.892*** 0.120
−0.287 −0.186 −0.984 −0.442 −0.269 −0.287
*Republic of
Korea and
Taipei,China
*NAFTA
0.500* −0.348** −1.622 −0.203 −0.616*** 0.500*
−0.266 −0.166 −1.010 −0.351 −0.160 −0.266
0.352 −0.763*** −2.002** −0.651* −0.001 0.352
−0.276 −0.179 −0.833 −0.384 −0.271 −0.276
*European Union 28 0.720*** −0.704*** −1.593* −1.040*** −0.593*** 0.720***
−0.270 −0.176 −0.872 −0.391 −0.194 −0.270
207
*Australia and 0.385 −0.175 −1.504 −2.237** 1.650** 0.385
New Zealand −0.427 −0.348 −1.399 −0.915 −0.668 −0.427
*Rest of the world 0.454 −0.196 −0.672 −0.779 −1.372*** 0.454
−0.337 −0.209 −1.075 −0.476 −0.229 −0.337
ln (Imports_2000) −0.095*** −0.051*** −0.119*** −0.090*** −0.129*** −0.095***
−0.005 −0.003 −0.012 −0.006 −0.003 −0.005
∆ln (Exports_All_ipo) −0.030** −0.023 −0.001 −0.056** −0.233*** −0.030**
−0.014 −0.017 −0.041 −0.026 −0.027 −0.014
N 14 447 15 808 1 941 8 274 27 139 338
Log likelihood −7 052 −9 139 −937 −4 292 −14 000 −165
Notes:
ASEAN 5 = Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore and Thailand; NAFTA = North American Free Trade Agreement.
Standard errors in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. Each regression has fixed effects that control for country, province, and firm
ownership type.
Source: Author’s calculation.
208 Asia and global production networks
consumption goods. In each regression, the results show that import trade
relationships at the province- HS6 product- country- ownership type level
were less likely to end in the case of transactions that were larger in value
in the initial year, 2000. In the full sample, import transactions in higher
HS6 stage products were more likely to end than were transactions involv-
ing lower HS6 stage products. However, the stage characteristics of exiting
products differed across good type. Notably, while there was a higher exit
rate for high stage imports of intermediate goods or consumer goods,
lower stage capital goods were at a greater threat of exit. To examine the
geographic dimensions of these correlations, columns 5 and 6 add inter-
actions between the variable stages and indicator variables for ASEAN
countries and rich countries. In the case of intermediate imports, the inter-
action terms reveal that the higher stage intermediate input imports were
at slightly lower risk of termination in the case of import from rich source
countries, while higher stage intermediate input imports were at slightly
higher risk of termination in the cases where they were imported from
ASEAN country sources. However, these apparent changes are driven by
changes in the industrial composition of PRC trade changes. In particular,
if the estimating framework adds interactions between stages and indus-
try indicator variables, the data reveal highly different exit risks across
industries based on stages. For example, higher stage products were at
particularly high exit risk in the wood, textile and machinery sectors, while
high sector products faced much lower exit risk in the cases of the trans-
portation and miscellaneous manufacturing sectors. When the industry
interactions are included, the country interaction terms that were shown
in columns 5 and 6 no longer have any statistically significant relationship.
Due to the large differences in the correlation of stages with exit across
industries, Table 6.12 runs separate exit regressions for a number of
the industries in the sample. The regression specification tests how exit
from transactions is related to the import source, controlling for general
country, province and ownership fixed effects. On an industry dimension,
one main distinction is between industries that are characterized by exit
from high stage imported inputs, regardless of source: namely machinery
and footwear. In contrast, in other industries the exit is similar across all
sources, with the exit concentrated in lower stage imported intermediates:
namely electronics, transportation equipment, and miscellaneous manu-
facturing. Alone, this evidence would suggest that changes in technology
have dictated the changing patterns in intermediates import. However, the
fact that other industries have differential stage correlations depending
on source (textiles), while the strength of the correlations differ markedly
across countries, suggest that there is no uniform technological develop-
ment behind the unbundling of production that governs the organization
Changes in the production stage position of PRC trade 209
of all industries. Further, although it is hard to characterize industry level
incentives for co- location, these results might also be affected by industry
needs to move groups of items/activities at the same time in the relocation
of modules of activity.
Since processing exports and ordinary exports were qualitatively similar
at the industry level, and because firms have shifted increasingly from
processing to ordinary exports, the analysis has focused primarily on the
trade in intermediate inputs, regardless of the customs regime. However,
to test for robustness, I experimented with some alternative samples.
First, processing trade, though a large component of the country’s overall
trade, is not ubiquitous, as the large majority of provinces are only
lightly involved in processing trade. Further, although the government
sought to change this pattern with its new “Go West” policies that were
introduced in 2006, examination of trade at the provincial level does not
suggest that the pattern has shifted. For this reason, as a first test for
robustness, I estimate the specification shown in Table 6.10, column 4 on
the subset of provinces that were the most heavily involved in processing
trade: Guandong, Jiangsu, Shandong, Shanghai, and Zhejian. When the
estimation is limited to the smaller subsample, the coefficient on stages in
Table6.10, column 4 drops almost imperceptibly from 0.397 to 0.396.
To provide further insight into changes in industry structure, I posed
the following question. If we look at the types of inputs that were intro-
duced into PRC processing trade, can we see anything systematic about
the handling of those items in later years? Implementation of this idea
required the identification of products that were common to supply
chains. Thus, the first step was to take processing trade data to form a
list of HS6 products that were processing intermediates or capital goods
between the years 1997 and 2001. To do so, BEC codes were applied to
assign goods to product groups, and all goods that were categorized as
final goods or primary goods were dropped from the sample. This left
3521 distinct HS6 codes that were either intermediate or capital goods.
Next, the sample was limited only to transactions that were known to
involve processing trade, due to their presence in the processing trade
regime. This restriction reduced the number of unique HS6 codes to 3300.
Notably, there is a strong overlap between intermediates and capital
goods trade conducted by processing and ordinary firms, as ordinary
firms handled 3448 distinct HS6 product categories during this same
period. For a final screen in creating a list of supply chain trade, the
list of distinct products was limited to those transactions that involved
foreign invested firms. This screen reduces the scope of HS6 items to
3200, of which 2691 were intermediate inputs, while 501 involved capital
goods imports. Since the data cross HS6 code groups that were classified
210 Asia and global production networks
according to the changing definitions from 1997, 2002, and 2007, the
World Bank concordance, as described by Cebeci (2012), was used to
form a single set of codes. Due to changes in definitions over time, this
consolidates groups of HS6 codes that were later regrouped. Adopting
this consolidation leaves 2405 unique consolidated groups of HS6 inter-
mediate product imports, and 449 groups of HS6 capital goods imports.
After identifying this subset of products, I ran the specification of Table
6.10, column 4 only on those goods. In this setting, the coefficient on
stages rises much more dramatically to a statistically significant value
of 0.87, which suggests that processing imports of intermediates were
growing most rapidly for high- stage products.
7. CONCLUSIONS
To assess changes in the position of the PRC in production this chapter
studies how the production position, or stages, of the country’s trade
changed during the 2000s. The data show that imported intermediates
grew more rapidly in high stage items items that embodied a greater
number of stages of handling prior to their import. Production position
was also related to the likelihood of transaction exit, as higher stage
intermediate imports were more likely to cease between 2000 and 2011
than were imports of lower stage intermediates. The data reveal shifts
in composition of intermediates trade along geographic, firm ownership
and industry lines. However, the strong heterogeneity in compositional
changes across industries suggests that the recent reconfiguration of indus-
try may be shaped not only by aggregate factors (such as changes in wages
or export demand) that would move all industries in a similar fashion, but
also by industry- level factors that allow for the unbundling of industry
production, and influence the locations at which activities cluster.
NOTES
1. Hummels et al. (2001) pioneered this approach in international data. Its refinement and
application to PRC trade is demonstrated in Johnson and Noguera (2012a).
2. Koopman et al. (2008); Ma et al. (2009); and Ma and Van Assche (2010) use this
approach to assess the contribution of PRC value- added in production, and to demon-
strate how economic factors influence the organization of global production networks.
More generally, Gaulier et al. (2007) provide insights into changes in country connec-
tions and product composition of PRC trade.
3. For example, Johnson and Noguera (2012b) finding that country bilateral value added
to export ratios decline when countries join regional trade agreements suggests that the
organization of production sharing activities responds to trade reforms.
Changes in the production stage position of PRC trade 211
4. Use of sequential production can be seen in Findlay (1978), Dixit and Grossman (1982),
Sanyal (1983), Yi (2003) and Baldwin and Venables (2010).
5. When Amiti and Freund (2010) apply US measures of industry skill- intensity to PRC
trade, they find that the distribution of imported inputs – both processing and ordinary
– shifted between 1992 and 2005 from less- skilled to more skilled sectors.
6. Koopman et al. (2008); Ma et al. (2009); and Ma and Van Assche (2010) exploit infor-
mation from Chinese processing trade activities.
7. The industry groups are: Textiles, Electrical machinery, Non- manufacturing, non-
electrical machinery, Metals, Footwear and headgear, Chemicals and allied industries,
Raw hides, Leather and fur, Plastics and rubber, Transportation, Stone clay and glass,
Wood and wood products, and miscellaneous manufacturing. The mapping between
HS codes and industries is listed in Appendix Table 6A.2.
8. At the firm level, Wang and Yu (2012) show that some firms specialized in processing
exports, while others engaged in both processing and ordinary exports. Notably, they
show that the productivity of pure processing firms is inferior to firms that are engaged
in both processing and ordinary trade.
9. Further, when Gangnes et al. (2012) study the effects of trade shocks on PRC trade,
they do not uncover any systematic evidence that processing exports had different
responses to OECD income changes than did nonprocessing exports, though they do
observe distinct responses for durable versus nondurable goods.
10. While the concept of upstreamness or stages is based on the idea of tasks, the creation of
the measures are based on US Bureau of Economic Analysis input–output tables from
2002. Thus, the measures are more closely related to the number of plants involved in
the production process than they are related to the number of tasks.
11. This can explain Levchenko’s (2007) finding that trade is enhanced by institutions that
support the formation of contractual arrangements.
12. This cannot be interpreted as a move into more sophisticated sectors, as Fally does not
uncover a positive correlation between the length of his production sequence measures
and sector technological levels. Recent declines in US measures of stages are in part due
to the rising importance of the service sector as a share of output.
13. The numbers in this example were calculated by applying Fally’s production measures
to the universe of data on Chinese export transactions, and calculating the raw average
outcome as well as the outcome when weighted by export transaction values.
14. This may be due to local provision of intermediates, consistent with Kee and Tang’s
(2012) evidence.
15. Due to revisions in HS6 codes over time, I use a World Bank consolidated HS6 codes,
documented by Cebeci (2012), to link transaction codes that changed during the
sample period. In the case where codes were changed, the data are aggregated accord-
ing to the linked/consolidated HS6 code. The concordance was downloaded from:
http://econ.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTDEC/EXTRESEARCH/EXT
PROGRAMS/EXTTRADERESEARCH/0,,contentMDK:23192741~pagePK:641681
82~piPK:64168060~theSitePK:544849,00.html.
16. For an overview on the relevance of firm- ownership type differences for firm opera-
tions, Hale and Long (2012) provide firm- level operational details and an overview of
the PRC policies.
17. In this project, foreign owned and joint venture firms are included in the category
foreign invested enterprises (FIE), while the category Private includes both private and
collective firms.
18. Each form of demand is created by applying the UN BEC codes to the HS6 trade data.
The intermediates group includes both parts and components and the semi- finished
categories. Final consumption and capital goods categories are defined according to
Appendix Table 6A.2.
19. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/2012/11/17122599/ concordance- among-
harmonized- system- 1996- 2002- 2007- classifications.
212 Asia and global production networks
REFERENCES
Amiti, M. and C. Freund (2010), ‘The anatomy of China’s export growth’, in R.C.
Feenstra and S.- J. Wei (eds), China’s Growing Role in World Trade, University
of Chicago Press, pp. 35–56.
Antras, P. and D. Chor (forthcoming), ‘Organizing the global value chain’,
Econometrica.
Antras, P., D. Chor, T. Fally, and R. Hillberry (2012), ‘Measuring upstreamness
of production and trade’, American Economic Review Papers & Proceedings.
Baldwin, R. and J. Lopez- Gonzalez (2013), ‘Supply- chain trade: a portrait
of global patterns and several testable hypotheses’, NBER Working Paper
18957.
Baldwin, R. and A. Venables (2010), ‘Relocating the value chain: offshoring and
agglomeration in the global economy’, NBER Working Papers 16611.
Brandt, L. and P.M. Morrow (2013), ‘Tariffs and the organization of trade in
China’, University of Toronto Working Paper–491.
Cebeci, T. (2012), A Concordance Among Harmonized System 1996, 2002 and
2007 Classifications, Washington, DC: World Bank, http://documents.
worldbank.org/curated/en/2012/11/17122599/concordance- among- harmonized-
system- 1996- 2002- 2007- classifications.
Defever, F. and A. Riaño (2012), ‘China’s pure exporter subsidies’, Centre for
Economic Performance Discussion Paper No. 1182.
Dixit, A. and G. Grossman (1982), ‘Trade and protection with multistage produc-
tion’, Review of Economic Studies, 49, 583–594.
Fally, T. (2012a), ‘Production staging: measurement and facts’, University of
Colorado, Boulder, Manuscript.
Fally, T. (2012b), ‘Data on the fragmentation of production in the U.S.’,
University of Colorado, Boulder, Manuscript.
Findlay, R. (1978), ‘An “Austrian” model of international trade and interest rate
equalization’, Journal of Political Economy, 86, 989–1007.
Gangnes, B., A.C. Ma, and A. Van Assche (2012), ‘Global value chains and the
transmission of business cycle shocks’, ADB Economics Working Paper Series,
No. 329.
Gaulier, G., F. Lemoine, and D. Unal- Kesenci (2007), ‘China’s emergence and
the reorganization of trade flows in Asia’, China Economic Review, 18, 209–243.
Hale, G. and C. Long (2012), Foreign Direct Investment in China: Winners and
Losers, Singapore: World Scientific.
Head, K., R. Jing, and J. Ries (2011), ‘Import sourcing of Chinese cities: order
versus randomness’, University of British Columbia, Manuscript.
Hummels, D., J. Ishii, and K.- M. Yi (2001), ‘The nature and growth of vertical
specialization in world trade’, Journal of International Economics, 54, 75–96.
Johnson, R. and G. Noguera (2012a), ‘Accounting for intermediates: produc-
tion sharing and trade in value added’, Journal of International Economics, 86,
224–236.
Johnson, R. and G. Noguera (2012b), ‘Fragmentation and trade in value added
over four decades’, NBER Working Paper 18186.
Kee, H.L. and H. Tang (2012), ‘Domestic value added in Chinese exports: firm-
level evidence’, Johns Hopkins School of Advanced International Studies,
Manuscript.
Changes in the production stage position of PRC trade 213
Koopman, R., Z. Wang, and S.- J. Wei (2008), ‘How much of Chinese exports is
really made in China? Assessing domestic value- added when processing trade is
pervasive’, NBER Working Paper 14109.
Levchenko, A. (2007), ‘Institutional quality and international trade’, Review of
Economic Studies, 74, 791–819.
Lu, D. (2010), ‘Exceptional exporter performance? Evidence from Chinese manu-
facturing firms’, University of Chicago, Manuscript.
Lu, M., C. Milner, and Z. Yu (2012), ‘Regional heterogeneity and China’s trade:
sufficient lumpiness or not?’, Review of International Economics, 20, 415–429.
Ma, A. and A. Van Assche (2010), ‘The role of trade costs in global production
networks: evidence from China’s processing trade regime’, World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper 5490.
Ma, A., A. Van Assche, and C. Hong (2009), ‘Global production networks and
China’s processing trade’, Asian Development Bank Institute Working Paper
Series Number 175.
Nunn, N. (2007), ‘Relationship- specificity, incomplete contracts and the pattern of
trade’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122, 569–600.
Sanyal, K.K. (1983), ‘Vertical specialization in a Ricardian model with a con-
tinuum of stages of production’, Economica, 50, 71–78.
Wang, Z. and Z. Yu (2012), ‘Trading partners, traded products and firm perform-
ances of China’s exporter- importers: does processing trade make a difference?’,
The World Economy, 35, 1795–1824.
Yi, K.- M. (2003), ‘Can vertical specialization explain the growth of world trade?’,
Journal of Political Economy, 111b, 52–102.
214 Asia and global production networks
APPENDIX 6A.1 DATA CLASSIFICATIONS
Industry categories are in Table 6A.1. Traded products are assigned to
five goods categories (Primary, Semi- finished, Parts and components,
Capital, and Consumption). The assignments are based on the UN BEC
(Broad Economic Categories) classifications of production stages that
provide a link between products at the 6- digit Harmonized System and the
production stage code (Table 6A.2).
Table 6A.1 Industry classifications
Name HS 2- digit codes
Non- manufacturing 01–27
Chemicals and allied industries 28–38
Plastics and rubber 39–40
Raw hides, leather and fur 41–43
Wood and wood products 44–49
Textiles 50–63
Footwear and headgear 64–67
Stone, clay and glass 68–71
Metals 72–83
Machinery 84
Electrical machinery 85
Transportation 86–89
Miscellaneous manufacturing 90–97
Table 6A.2 Goods classifications
Goods category BEC code
Primary goods 111, 21, 31
Intermediate goods
Semi- finished goods 121, 22, 322
Parts and components 42, 53
Final goods
Capital goods 41, 521
Consumption goods 112, 122, 51, 522, 61, 62, 63
215
7. External rebalancing, structural
adjustment, and real exchange rates
in developing Asia*
Andrei Levchenko and Jing Zhang
1. INTRODUCTION
The developing Asia region has been the fastest- growing in the world in
recent decades. As is common for fast- growing countries, the region’s
growth has been export- led, and many of the countries in it have been
running trade surpluses. As these countries develop, sustained economic
growth will require a rebalancing from reliance on exports and toward
greater domestic demand.
What will be the consequences of that rebalancing process, for the devel-
oping Asia countries themselves and for the rest of the world? A country
running a trade surplus is spending less than the value of its output.
Rebalancing an elimination of the trade surplus then by construction
increases the country’s total spending. If the country is small (i.e., does
not affect the world goods prices) and all goods are freely traded, rebal-
ancing directly increases nominal spending, but has no effect on the real
exchange rate, factor prices, or the sectoral allocation of employment.
A small country model with non- tradeable goods, sometimes called the
“dependent economy” or the Salter–Swan model (Salter 1959; Swan 1960)
predicts that a rise in domestic spending due to the elimination of the trade
surplus will increase demand for non- tradeables and their prices, thereby
moving factors of production into non- tradeables and appreciating the
country’s real exchange rate. The dependent economy model assumes a
small country and a single exportable good, and thus it makes no pre-
diction on how the patterns of international specialization or relative
factor prices will change in response to rebalancing. In the two- country
Ricardian model with a continuum of goods, Dornbusch et al. (1977)
show that an elimination of the trade surplus in a country will raise both
its relative and real wage, and reduce the set of goods that it exports. In
summary, classical theory predicts that an elimination of a trade surplus in
216 Asia and global production networks
a country: (i)increases both relative and real incomes; (ii) appreciates the
real exchange rate; (iii) increases the employment share in the non- traded
sector; and (iv) reduces exports. All of these effects are reversed in the
trade deficit countries as the trade imbalance is eliminated.
As insightful as these predictions are, classical theory leaves many unan-
swered questions. First and foremost, while the directions of the effects
outlined above are well- established, stylized small- country or two- country
models are too simplistic to reliably gauge the magnitudes involved.
Second, the world is a great deal more complex than the simple models.
The real world features many heterogeneous countries with highly asym-
metric trade relationships between them. While this distinction is non-
existent in two- country models, in the real world the elimination of the
People’s Republic of China’s (PRC) trade surplus will likely have a very
different global impact than the elimination of Japan’s trade surplus, since
those two countries occupy different positions in the world trading system.
In addition, the world is increasingly engaged in intermediate input trade
(“the global supply chains”), and thus a rebalancing in, say, the PRC will
have knock- on effects on countries supplying inputs to its traded and non-
traded sectors. Finally, the world has many surplus and many deficit coun-
tries at the same time. An elimination of the trade imbalance in several
surplus countries simultaneously may yield heterogeneous effects in the
different surplus countries. While the complexity of the real- world global
economy may not overturn the basic predictions of the classical theory, in
order to develop a set of quantitative results about the impact of rebalanc-
ing, we must develop a framework that goes some way toward reflecting
the rich heterogeneity of countries and trading relationships observed in
the world today.
This chapter uses a large- scale quantitative model of production
and trade to simulate the global impact of rebalancing. The analysis
is based on a Ricardian-Heckscher–Ohlin framework that features 75
countries (including 14 from developing Asia), 19 tradeable and 1 non-
tradeable sector, multiple factors of production, as well as the full set of
cross- sectoral input–output linkages forming a global supply chain. The
model is implemented on sectoral trade and production data in such a
way that it matches the sector- level bilateral trade shares in our sample
of countries, as well as the countries’ relative incomes. In the baseline
equilibrium, we solve the model under the observed levels of trade imbal-
ances in each country. We then compare outcomes to the counterfactual
scenario in which “external rebalancing” took place, and each country
is constrained to have balanced trade. This exercise thus follows the
approach of Obstfeld and Rogoff (2005) and Dekle et al. (2007, 2008).
We examine the impact of rebalancing on a range of outcomes, including
External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange rates 217
relative wages, real exchange rates, the size of the non- tradeable sector,
and finally welfare.
Our model quantifies these impacts for both developing Asia and the
rest of the world. In the surplus countries in the region (the PRC, the
Republic of Korea, Malaysia, among others) relative wages with respect
to the United States (US) rise by double digits, 17.5 percent at the median,
and the real exchange rate with respect to the US dollar appreciates by a
similar, slightly smaller, amount. Interestingly, the trade- weighted real
exchange rate in these countries appreciates by much less (1.5 percent at
the median), with the Republic of Korea and Taipei,China actually experi-
encing modest real depreciations in trade- weighted terms. This difference
is due to the fact that these countries trade a great deal among themselves,
and thus as they are all appreciating against the US dollar, their real
appreciation against one another is much more modest.
As expected, a rebalancing toward greater domestic demand in the
surplus countries is accompanied by an increase in the size of the
non- tradeable sector. At the median, the share of labor in the non-
tradeable sector rises by 4 percentage points. This is a modest change in
proportional terms: the average share of labor in the non- tradeable sector
is two- thirds in this group of countries. Finally, the impact on welfare of
the rebalancing is a fraction of 1 percent among the surplus countries (0.4
percent at the median). Welfare corresponds to the real income in this
model. A rebalancing leads to a rise in factor prices, and an increase in
the price level. The net effect on welfare is more subdued than either the
change in nominal factor prices or the change in the price level.
The impact is roughly opposite for the deficit countries in developing
Asia (India, Sri Lanka, Viet Nam, among others). While for four out
of seven developing Asia deficit countries wages relative to the US rise,
the average increase, at about 5.1 percent, is much more subdued than
for the surplus countries. While the real exchange with respect to the US
appreciates in most of these countries, the trade- weighted real exchange
depreciates in all of them, on average by 6 percent. As rebalancing requires
a reduction in domestic spending, the share of labor in the non- tradeable
sector shrinks by 3 percentage points. All in all, these countries experience
a significant reduction in welfare of about 2.6 percent on average.
It is intuitive that countries running surpluses tend to benefit from the
reductions in their own trade surplus, and vice versa. However, the multi-
lateral trade patterns are also important for understanding the impact of
rebalancing on these economies. Countries that currently export mostly
to the deficit countries (chiefly the US) tend to experience reductions in
welfare due to the rebalancing. By contrast, countries exporting to the
major surplus countries (chiefly the PRC) tend to benefit.
218 Asia and global production networks
In addition to the classical contributions discussed above, our chapter is
related to the more recent literature on the impact of external rebalancing.
Obstfeld and Rogoff (2005) simulate rebalancing in a three- country (the
US, Europe, Asia) Armington model. Dekle et al. (2007, 2008) perform
a similar exercise in a Ricardian model with 42 countries and two sectors
(tradeable and non- tradeable). Our chapter is the first to evaluate global
rebalancing in a multi- sector framework with a full- fledged within- and
cross- sectoral set of input–output linkages. This allows for a much greater
degree of precision regarding each country’s impact on its trading part-
ners. In addition, our chapter is the first, to our knowledge, to apply this
quantitative approach with particular emphasis on developing Asia.
The rest of the chapter is organized as follows. Section 2 lays out
the quantitative framework and discusses the details of calibration and
estimation. Section 3 discusses the main results, and Section 4 concludes.
2. QUANTITATIVE FRAMEWORK
Motivated by the discussion in the Introduction, our goal is to assess the
impact of global rebalancing in an appropriately rich quantitative model.
Classical theory emphasizes that in order to model rebalancing, it is essen-
tial for the framework to feature: (i) both traded and non- traded sectors
(Salter 1959; Swan 1960); and (ii) endogenous specialization (Dornbusch
et al. 1977). We also argued that a reliable assessment will require: (iii) a
large number of countries; and (iv) a sufficiently rich production structure
that features multiple sectors and a fully articulated set of input–output
linkages between them, forming a global supply chain. It turns out that
a multi- sector version of the Eaton and Kortum (2002) Ricardian model
(henceforth the EK approach) provides the necessary tractability to build
a quantitative framework of this scale.
2.1 The Environment
The world is comprised of
N 5 75
countries, indexed by n and i. There are
J 5 19
tradeable sectors, plus one non- tradeable sector
J 1 1.
Utility over
these sectors in country n is given by
U
n
5
a
a
J
j
5
1
w
1
h
j
(
Y
n
j
)
h2 1
h
b
h
h2 1
x
n
(
Y
n
J1 1
)
12 x
n
, (7.1)
where
Y
J1 1
n
is the non- tradeable- sector composite good, and
Y
j
n
is the com-
posite good in the tradeable sector j. That is, utility is Cobb–Douglas in
External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange rates 219
tradeables and non- tradeables, implying that consumers have a constant
expenditure share devoted to tradeable goods, equal to
x
n
in country n. In
turn, the bundle of tradeables is a constant elasticity of substitution (CES)
aggregate of the J tradeable sectors, with
h
the elasticity of substitution
between the tradeable sectors, and
w
j
the taste parameter for tradeable
sector
j.
The assumption that utility is Cobb–Douglas in tradeables and
non- tradeables will have quantitative implications for the extent of
labor reallocation following external rebalancing. Generally, a higher
elasticity of substitution would imply greater factor reallocation, as
demand will respond more to relative price changes. It is well known
that Cobb–Douglas utility implies an elasticity of substitution between
tradeables and the non- tradeables equal to 1. This assumption is not too
far from the available estimates. Herrendorf et al. (2013) estimate the elas-
ticity of substitution between services (which in our model is interpreted
as non- tradeables) and manufacturing of 0.9. Other estimates show even
smaller substitution possibilities. For instance, Świe¸cki (2013) estimates
the elasticity to be 0.2, implying very few substitution possibilities between
manufacturing and services. Under that elasticity, the labor reallocation
towards non- tradeables in surplus countries will be even smaller.
A related issue is the role of non-homothetic preferences. For instance,
a surplus country like the PRC will experience an income increase when
external rebalancing takes place. Non- homothetic preferences such that
higher incomes imply greater demand for non- tradeables would translate
into even greater reallocation of labor to the non- tradeable sector fol-
lowing rebalancing. As will become clear below, however, the change in
real income due to rebalancing is rather modest a fraction of 1 percent
for the surplus developing Asia countries. Thus, we would not expect a
large change in the relative demand for non- tradeables acting through a
non- homotheticity channel following rebalancing.
All goods and factor markets are competitive, and all production fea-
tures constant returns to scale, implying that all profits are zero. There are
two factors of production, labor (with country
n
endowed with
L
n
units)
and capital (
K
n
). Production uses labor, capital, and intermediate inputs
from other sectors. The cost of an input bundle in country
n
and sector
j
is:
c
j
n
5
(
w
a
j
n
r
12 a
j
n
)
b
j
a
q
J
1
1
k5 1
(
p
k
n
)
g
k,j
b
1
2 b
j
,
where
w
n
is the wage of workers,
r
n
is the return to capital, and
p
k
n
is the
price of intermediate input from sector k in country
n.
That is, the produc-
tion function is Cobb–Douglas in the two primary factors
K
n
and
L
n
and
220 Asia and global production networks
the intermediate inputs. The intermediate inputs can come from any other
sector.
The share of payments to labor in value added (also known as “labor
intensity”) is given by
a
j
.
It varies by sector: some sectors will be very
labor- intensive, others less so. The share of value added in the value of
total output is given
b
j
.
It varies across sectors as well: some sectors will
spend a lot on intermediate inputs relative to the value of gross output,
others less so. Finally,
g
k, j
captures the usage in sector
j
of intermediate
inputs coming from sector
k.
Precisely,
g
k,j
is the share of spending on
sector
k
inputs in total input spending in sector
j.
These shares will vary
by output industry
j
as well as input industry
k.
That is, we allow for the
apparel sector, say, to use a great deal of textile inputs, but much fewer
basic metals inputs.
Each sector
j 5 1, . . . , J 1 1
is composed of a continuum of varie-
ties
q [
[
0,1
]
unique to each sector. Perfectly competitive producers can
produce each variety q in each sector j in every country n. However, pro-
ductivities will differ across countries in each q and j. Producing one unit
of good q in sector j in country n requires
1
z
j
n
(
q
)
input bundles. Following
the EK approach, productivity
z
j
n
(
q
)
for each
q [
[
0,1
]
in each sector
j is random, and drawn from the Fréchet distribution with cumulative
distribution function:
F
j
n
(
z
)
5
e
2
T
j
n
z
2q
In this distribution,
T
j
n
is a central tendency parameter. It varies by both
country and sector, with higher values of
T
j
n
implying higher average
productivity draws in sector j in country n. The parameter
q
captures
dispersion, with larger values of
q
implying smaller dispersion in draws.
The intuition for this physical environment is as follows. Each j should
be thought of as a very large sector, say textiles, apparel, or electrical
machinery. Within each sector, there is a large number of varieties
q.
If j is
apparel, then blue cotton T- shirts, green cotton T- shirts, black socks, etc,
are different varieties q within apparel. Each country can produce each
q,
but productivities will vary across countries: Japan may happen to be
better at blue cotton T- shirts than Viet Nam, but Pakistan may be better
than Japan at producing black socks. While we may not be able to say with
confidence whether Japan or Pakistan is better at making black socks, we
will be able to make statements about the average productivity of each
country in the apparel sector, captured by
T
j
n
.
Since there is a continuum
of varieties
q,
and the Fréchet distribution has infinite support, even
countries with a very low
T
j
n
relative to their trading partners will have a
few q’s in which they got an unusually high draw, and thus they would be
External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange rates 221
able to produce individual varieties even in its (on average) comparative
disadvantage sectors.
Why impose the assumptions that there is a continuum of varieties in
each sector, and that productivity draws come from a Fréchet distribu-
tion? The reasons are realism and tractability. Real- world trade flows
within broad sectors are characterized by substantial two- way trade: pairs
of countries often ship similar products to each other. This setup allows
us to model that phenomenon and thus successfully match global bilateral
trade flows within each sector. The Fréchet distributional assumption
helps because it yields especially simple analytical expressions for bilateral
trade shares, thus making model estimation and calibration easy even for
a very large number of countries.
The production cost of one unit of good q in sector j and country n is
thus equal to
c
j
n
/z
j
n
(
q
)
.
International trade is subject to “iceberg” costs:
d
j
ni
. 1
units of good q produced in sector j in country i must be shipped
to country n in order for one unit to be available for consumption there.
The trade costs need not be symmetric
d
j
ni
need not equal
d
j
in
and will
vary by sector. We normalize
d
j
nn
5 1
for any n and j. The price at which
country i supplies tradeable good q in sector j to country n is:
p
j
ni
(
q
)
5
a
c
j
i
z
j
i
(
q
)
b
d
j
ni
.
Buyers of each good q in tradeable sector j in country n will shop glo-
bally, and will only buy from the cheapest source country. Thus the price
actually paid for this good in country n will be:
p
j
n
(
q
)
5
min
i5 1,. . .,N
{
p
j
ni
(
q
) }
.
International trade happens whenever the cheapest provider of some
variety q to some market n is foreign. Note that there are several ways to
be the cheapest supplier of good q in sector j in country n. A country may
become the cheapest source of a good because it is productive (high
z
j
i
(
q
)
),
it has cheap inputs (low
c
j
i
), or it has low trade costs.
Output in sector j is produced from varieties
q [
[
0,1
]
using a CES
production function:
Q
j
n
5
c
3
1
0
Q
j
n
(
q
)
e2 1
e
dq
d
e
e2 1
,
where
e
denotes the elasticity of substitution across varieties
q,
Q
j
n
is the
total output of sector j in country
n,
and
Q
j
n
(
q
)
is the amount of variety q
222 Asia and global production networks
that is used in production in sector j and country n. Note that some of the
Q
j
n
(
q
)
’s will be imported, except in the non- tradeable sector.
Trade is not balanced. We incorporate trade imbalances following the
approach of Dekle et al. (2007, 2008) and assume that at a point in time,
a trade imbalance represents a transfer from the surplus to the deficit
country. Specifically, the budget constraint (or the resource constraint) of
the consumer is
a
J1 1
j
5
1
p
j
n
Y
j
n
5 w
n
L
n
1 r
n
K
n
2 D
n
, (7.2)
where
p
j
n
are prices of sector j output in country
n,
and
D
n
is the trade
surplus of country n. When
D
n
is negative, countries are running a deficit
and consume more than their factor income. The deficits add up to
zero globally,
a
n
D
n
5 0, and are thus transfers of resources between
countries.
2.2 Characterization of Equilibrium
Given the preferences and technology described above and the exog-
enous parameters of the model, we can find the global equilibrium in this
economy. Factors of production (
K
n
and
L
n
) are perfectly mobile across
sectors within a country, but immobile across countries. Intuitively, the
global equilibrium is a set of resource allocations and prices such that
all markets clear, both domestically and internationally. What follows
is the formal definition of equilibrium and the detailed statement of the
equilibrium conditions in this economy.
The competitive equilibrium of this model of the world economy with
exogenous trade deficits consists of a set of prices, allocation rules, and
trade shares such that: (i) given the prices, all firms’ inputs satisfy the
first- order conditions, and their output is given by the production func-
tion; (ii) given the prices, the consumers’ demand satisfies the first- order
conditions; (iii) the prices ensure the market clearing conditions for labor,
capital, tradeable goods and non- tradeable goods; and (iv) trade shares
ensure exogenous trade deficit for each country.
The set of prices includes the wage rate
w
n
,
the rental rate
r
n
,
the sectoral
prices
{
p
j
n
}
J
1
1
j
5
1
,
and the aggregate price
P
n
in each country n. The allocation
rules include the capital and labor allocation across sectors
{
K
j
n
, L
j
n
}
J
1
1
j
5
1
,
final consumption demand
{
Y
j
n
}
J
1
1
j
5
1
,
and total demand
{
Q
j
n
}
J
1
1
j
5
1
(both
final and intermediate goods) for each sector. The trade shares include
the expenditure share
p
j
ni
in country n on goods coming from country i in
sector j.
External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange rates 223
2.2.1 Demand and prices
It can be easily shown that the price of sector j’s output will be given by:
p
j
n
5
c
3
1
0
p
j
n
(
q
)
12 e
dq
d
1
12 e
.
Following the standard EK approach, it is helpful to define
F
j
n
5
a
N
i5 1
T
j
i
(
c
j
i
d
j
ni
)
2q
.
This value summarizes, for country
n,
the access to production technolo-
gies in sector j. Its value will be higher if in sector
j,
country n’s trading
partners have high productivity (
T
j
i
) or low cost (
c
j
i
). It will also be higher
if the trade costs that country n faces in this sector are low. Standard steps
lead to the familiar result that the price of good j in country n is simply
p
j
n
5 G
(
F
j
n
)
2
1
q
(7.3)
where G 5
[
G
(
q
1
1
2
e
q
) ]
1
1 2 e
,
with
G
the Gamma function. The consump-
tion price index in country n is then:
P
n
5 B
n
a
a
J
j
5
1
w
j
(
p
j
n
)
12 h
b
1
12 h
x
n
(
p
J1 1
n
)
12 x
n
, (7.4)
where
B
n
5 x
2x
n
n
(
1
2 x
n
)
2
(
1
2 x
n
)
.
Given the set of prices
{
w
n
, r
n
, P
n
,
{
p
j
n
}
J
1
1
j
5
1
}
N
n
5
1
,
we first characterize the
optimal allocations from final demand. Consumers maximize utility (7.1)
subject to the budget constraint (7.2). The first order conditions associated
with this optimization problem imply the following final demand:
p
j
n
Y
j
n
5 x
n
(
w
n
L
n
1 r
n
K
n
2 D
n
)
w
j
(
p
j
n
)
1
2 h
a
J
k5 1
w
k
(
p
k
n
)
12 h
, for all j 5
{
1, . . ,J
}
(7.5)
and
p
J
1
1
n
Y
J
1
1
n
5
(
1
2 x
n
) (
w
n
L
n
1
r
n
K
n
2
D
n
)
.
2.2.2 Production allocation and market clearing
The EK structure in each sector j delivers the standard result that the
probability of importing good q from country i,
p
j
ni
,
is equal to the share
of total spending on goods coming from country i,
X
j
ni
/X
j
n
,
and is given by
224 Asia and global production networks
X
j
ni
X
j
n
5 p
j
ni
5
T
j
i
(
c
j
i
d
j
ni
)
2
q
F
j
n
.
Let
Q
j
n
denote the total sectoral demand in country n and sector j.
Q
j
n
is
used for both final consumption and intermediate inputs in domestic
production of all sectors. That is,
p
j
n
Q
j
n
5 p
j
n
Y
j
n
1
a
J
k5 1
(
1 2 b
k
)
g
j,k
a
a
N
i5 1
p
k
in
p
k
i
Q
k
i
b
1
(
1 2 b
J1 1
)
g
j,J1 1
p
J1 1
n
Q
J1 1
n
.
Total expenditure in sector
j 5 1, . . . , J 1 1
of country n,
p
j
n
Q
j
n
,
is the
sum of (i) domestic final consumption expenditure
p
j
n
Y
j
n
;
(ii) expendi-
ture on sector j goods as intermediate inputs in all the traded sectors
g
J
k5 1
(
1
2 b
k
)
g
j,k
(
g
N
i5 1
p
k
in
p
k
i
Q
k
i
)
,
and (iii) expenditure on the j’s sector inter-
mediate inputs in the domestic non- traded sector
(
1
2
b
J1 1
)
g
j,J1 1
p
J
1
1
n
Q
J
1
1
n
.
These market clearing conditions summarize the two important features
of the world economy captured by our model: complex international
production linkages, as much of world trade is in intermediate inputs, and
a good crosses borders multiple times before being consumed (Hummels
et al., 2001); and two- way input linkages between the tradeable and the
non- tradeable sectors.
In each tradeable sector
j,
some goods q are imported from abroad and
some goods q are exported to the rest of the world. Country n’s exports in
sector j are given by
EX
j
n
5
g
N
i5 1
I
i2 n
p
j
in
p
j
i
Q
j
i
,
and its imports in sector j are
given by
IM
j
n
5
g
N
i5 1
I
i2 n
p
j
ni
p
j
n
Q
j
n
,
where
I
i2 n
is the indicator function. The
total exports of country n are then EX
n
5
g
J
j5 1
EX
j
n
,
and total imports are
IM
n
5
g
J
j5 1
IM
j
n
.
Exogenous trade deficit requires that for any country
n,
EX
n
2 IM
n
5 D
n
.
Given the total production revenue in tradeable sector j in country n,
g
N
i
5
1
p
j
in
p
j
i
Q
j
i
,
the optimal sectoral factor allocations must satisfy
a
N
i5 1
p
j
in
p
j
i
Q
j
i
5
w
n
L
j
n
a
j
b
j
5
r
n
k
j
n
(
1 2 a
j
)
b
j
.
For the non- tradeable sector
J 1 1,
the optimal factor allocations in
country n are simply given by
p
J1 1
n
Q
J1 1
n
5
w
n
L
J1 1
n
a
J1 1
b
J1 1
5
r
n
K
J1 1
n
(
1
2 a
J1 1
)
b
J1 1
.
Finally, for any n the feasibility conditions for factors are given by
External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange rates 225
a
J
1
1
j
5
1
L
j
n
5 L
n
and
a
J
1
1
j
5
1
K
j
n
5 K
n
.
2.3 Welfare
Welfare in this framework corresponds to the indirect utility function.
Straightforward steps using the CES functional form can be used to show
that the indirect utility in each country n is equal to total income divided
by the price level. Since both goods and factor markets are competitive,
total income equals the total returns to factors of production. Thus total
welfare in a country is given by
(
w
n
L
n
1
r
n
K
n
)
/P
n
,
where the consumption
price level P
n
comes from equation (7.4). Expressed in per- capita terms it
becomes
w
n
1 r
n
k
n
P
n
, (7.6)
where
k
n
5 K
n
/L
n
is capital per worker. This expression is the metric of
welfare in all counterfactual exercises below. Importantly, we do not
include the direct effect of consuming (or transferring away) D
n
when
calculating the welfare levels of countries. Rather, we focus on real factor
incomes.
2.4 Calibration
The equations above define the equilibrium in this economy. Analytical
solutions of this model are not available. However, the equilibrium can be
found numerically. Essentially, the equilibrium conditions are simply a set
of non- linear equations in the prices and resource allocations. Solving the
model amounts to finding a solution to this set of equations.
Any numerical implementation, of course, requires us to take a stand
on the values of every parameter in the model. Specifically, we must take
a stand on the following sets of parameters: (i) moments of the produc-
tivity distributions
T
j
n
and
q;
(ii) trade costs
d
j
ni
;
(iii) production function
parameters
a
j
,
b
j
,
g
k, j
,
and
e;
(iv) country factor endowments L
n
and K
n
;
and (v) preference parameters
x
n
,
w
j
,
and
h.
What follows is a detailed dis-
cussion of how each parameter is picked. As there are many parameters to
be chosen, we follow three broad approaches in choosing them. First, in
some cases we use data and model- implied relationships to estimate sets of
parameters structurally. This is the most sophisticated approach. Second,
some parameters can be easily computed with basic data, without the need
to rely on the model structure explicitly. Finally, in a very limited set of
226 Asia and global production networks
cases, we simply adopt parameter values estimated elsewhere in the litera-
ture and commonly used. This approach is followed only in cases where
the model does not provide enough guidance on how to compute these
parameters based on data.
The structure of the model is used to estimate the sector- level
technology parameters
T
j
n
for a large set of countries. The estimation
procedure relies on fitting a structural gravity equation implied by the
model, and using the resulting estimates along with data on input costs
to back out the underlying technology. Intuitively, if controlling for the
typical gravity determinants of trade, a country spends relatively more
on domestically produced goods in a particular sector, it is revealed to
have either a high relative productivity or a low relative unit cost in that
sector. The procedure then uses data on factor and intermediate input
prices to net out the role of factor costs, yielding an estimate of relative
productivity. This step also produces estimates of bilateral sector- level
trade costs
d
j
ni
.
The parametric model for iceberg trade costs includes
the common geographic variables such as distance and common border,
as well as policy variables, such as regional trade agreements and cur-
rency unions. The detailed procedures for all three steps are described in
Levchenko and Zhang (2011) and reproduced in Appendix 7A.1.
Estimation of sectoral productivity parameters
T
j
n
and trade costs
d
j
ni
requires data on total output by sector, as well as sectoral data on bilateral
trade. For 52 countries in the sample, information on output comes from
the 2009 UNIDO Industrial Statistics Database. For the European Union
countries, the EUROSTAT database contains data of superior quality,
and thus for those countries we use EUROSTAT production data. The
two output data sources are merged at the roughly 2- digit International
Standard Industrial Classification of All Economic Activities (ISIC)
Revision 3 level of disaggregation, yielding 19 manufacturing sectors.
Bilateral trade data were collected from the UN COMTRADE database,
and concorded to the same sectoral classification. We assume that the
dispersion parameter
q
does not vary across sectors. There are no reli-
able estimates of how it varies across sectors, and thus we do not model
this variation. We pick the value of
q 5 8.28,
which is the preferred esti-
mate of EK.
1
It is important to assess how the results below are affected
by the value of this parameter. One may be especially concerned about
how the results change under lower values of
q.
Lower
q
implies greater
within- sector heterogeneity in the random productivity draws. Thus,
trade flows become less sensitive to the costs of the input bundles (
c
j
i
),
and the gains from intra- sectoral trade become larger relative to the gains
from inter- sectoral trade. Elsewhere (Levchenko and Zhang 2011) we
re- estimated all the technology parameters using instead a value of
q 5 4,
External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange rates 227
which has been advocated by Simonovska and Waugh (2011) and is at or
near the bottom of the range that has been used in the literature. Overall,
the outcome was remarkably similar. The correlation between estimated
T
j
i
’s under
q 5 4
and the baseline is above 0.95, and there is actually
somewhat greater variability in
T
j
i
’s under
q 5 4.
The production function parameters
a
j
and
b
j
are estimated using the
UNIDO and EUROSTAT production data, which contain information
on output, value added, employment, and wage bills. To compute
a
j
for
each sector, we calculate the share of the total wage bill in value added,
and take a simple median across countries (taking the mean yields essen-
tially the same results). To compute
b
j
,
we take the median of value added
divided by total output.
The intermediate input coefficients
g
k, j
are obtained from the direct
requirements table for the United States. We use the 1997 Benchmark
Detailed Make and Use Tables (covering approximately 500 distinct
sectors), as well as a concordance to the ISIC Revision 3 classification
to build a direct requirements table at the 2- digit ISIC level. The direct
requirements table gives the value of the intermediate input in row k
required to produce one dollar of final output in column j. Thus, it is the
direct counterpart to the input coefficients
g
k, j
.
Note that we assume these
to be the same in all countries.
2
In addition, we use the US IO matrix
to obtain
a
J1 1
and
b
J1 1
in the non- tradeable sector, which cannot be
obtained from UNIDO.
3
The elasticity of substitution between varieties
within each tradeable sector,
e,
is set to 4 (as is well known, in the EK
model this elasticity plays no role, entering only the constant
G
).
The total labor force in each country,
L
n
,
and the total capital stock,
K
n
, are obtained from the Penn World Tables 6.3. Following the standard
approach in the literature (see, e.g., Hall and Jones 1999, Bernanke and
Gürkaynak 2001, and Caselli 2005), the total labor force is calculated
from the data on the total GDP per capita and per worker.
4
The total
capital is calculated using the perpetual inventory method that assumes a
depreciation rate of 6 percent:
K
n,t
5
(
1
2
0.06
)
K
n,t
2
1
1
I
n,t
,
where I
n,t
is
total investment in country n in period t. For most countries, investment
data start in 1950, and the initial value of
K
n
is set equal to
I
n,0
/
(
g 1
0.06
)
,
where
g
is the average growth rate of investment in the first 10 years for
which data are available.
The share of expenditure on traded goods,
x
n
in each country is sourced
from Uy et al. (2013), who compile this information for 36 developed and
developing countries. For countries unavailable in their data, values of
x
n
are imputed based on their level of development. We fit a simple linear
relationship between
x
n
and log PPP- adjusted per capita GDP from the
Penn World Tables on the countries in the Uy et al. (2013) dataset. The
228 Asia and global production networks
fit of this simple bivariate linear relationship is quite good, with an R
2
of
0.55. For the remaining countries, we then set
x
n
to the value predicted
by this bivariate regression at their level of income. The taste parameters
for tradeable sectors
w
j
were estimated by combining the model struc-
ture above with data on final consumption expenditure shares in the US
sourced from the US IO matrix, as described in Appendix 7A.1. The elas-
ticity of substitution between broad sectors within the tradeable bundle,
h,
is set to 2. Since these are very large product categories, it is sensible
that this elasticity would be relatively low. It is higher, however, than the
elasticity of substitution between tradeable and non- tradeable goods that
is set to 1 by the Cobb–Douglas assumption.
2.5 Basic Patterns
All of the variables that vary over time are averaged over the period
2005–2007 (the latest available year on which we can implement the quan-
titative model). To assess the impact of rebalancing we use values of
D
n
for
2011, which is the latest available year total trade data are available for a
large sample of countries. The trade balance
D
n
is defined as goods exports
minus goods imports, and the data to compute trade balances are sourced
from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators. Appendix Table
7A.1 lists the 20 sectors along with the key parameter values for each
sector:
a
j
,
b
j
,
the share of non- tradeable inputs in total inputs
g
J
1
1, j
,
and
the taste parameter
w
j
.
Table 7.1 reports the sample of developing Asian countries and their
trade balances, both in absolute terms and as a share of each coun-
try’s GDP. In absolute terms, the largest trade surplus ($224 billion)
belongs to the PRC, and the largest trade deficit ($110 billion) to India.
Of course, those are the largest countries in absolute terms, and thus
their trade balances as a share of GDP (3 percent of GDP for PRC,
–6 percentof GDP for India) are actually some of the lowest in this
group of countries. Relative to GDP, Kazakhstan and Malaysia have
the largest trade surplus (22 percent and 16 percent, respectively),
and Fiji and Sri Lanka the largest deficits (23 percent and 11 percent,
respectively).
Table 7.2 reports the same data for the rest of the sample, broken down
by country group/region. As is well known, the US has the largest trade
deficit in absolute terms ($711 billion), and Germany, the largest trade
surplus ($199 billion).
External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange rates 229
3. COUNTERFACTUAL: IMPACT OF EXTERNAL
REBALANCING
This section traces out the impact of external rebalancing on outcomes
in developing Asia and the rest of the world. We proceed by first solving
the model under the baseline values of all the estimated parameters and
observed trade imbalances, and present a number of checks on the model
fit with respect to observed data. Then, we compute counterfactual
welfare and sectoral factor allocations under the assumption that all trade
imbalances disappear (D
n
5 0 for all n). We present the impact of external
rebalancing on relative wages, real exchange rates, welfare, as well as the
sectoral structure of these countries.
Note that in our framework trade deficits take the form of transfers and
thus external rebalancing amounts to simply removing those transfers.
The exercise follows the treatments of external rebalancing in Obstfeld and
Rogoff (2005) and Dekle et al. (2007, 2008).
The model is static, and thus does not allow us to think about
Table 7.1 Developing Asia: country sample and deficits
Country 3- letter code Trade balance
US$ billion Percent of GDP
Bangladesh BAN −7.31 −6.89
Fiji FIJ −0.79 −22.54
India IND −110.54 −6.17
Indonesia INO 31.07 4.00
Kazakhstan KAZ 37.25 22.17
Malaysia MAL 42.49 15.89
Pakistan PAK −12.35 −6.39
People’s Republic of China PRC 223.70 3.38
Philippines PHI −15.03 −7.08
Republic of Korea KOR 29.35 2.75
Sri Lanka SRI −5.75 −10.57
Taipei,China TAP 21.26 4.74
Thailand THA 20.74 6.24
Viet Nam VIE −3.94 −3.43
Note: This table reports, for countries in the developing Asia region, the trade balances
in US$ billion and as percent of GDP, as well as the 3- letter codes used to denote the
countries.
Source: World Development Indicators.
230 Asia and global production networks
Table 7.2 Rest of the world: country sample and deficits
Country 3- letter code Trade balance
US$ billion Percent of GDP
Organisation for Economic Co- operation and Development
Australia AUS 20.31 1.61
Austria AUT −4.89 −1.23
Belgium- Luxembourg BLX −12.23 −2.49
Canada CAN −10.56 −0.64
Denmark DEN 8.61 2.66
Finland FIN 5.75 2.31
France FRA −82.75 −3.11
Germany GER 198.81 5.77
Greece GRC −38.31 −13.17
Iceland ISL 0.85 6.39
Ireland IRE 56.88 26.92
Italy ITA −29.5 −1.39
Japan JPN 42.20 0.74
Netherlands NET 53.60 6.66
New Zealand NZL 2.12 1.41
Norway NOR 60.58 13.41
Portugal POR −23.35 −10.05
Spain SPA −63.57 −4.45
Sweden SWE 12.05 2.40
Switzerland SWI 24.33 4.02
United Kingdom UKG −163.53 −6.96
United States USA −711.41 −4.84
Central and Eastern Europe
Bulgaria BGR −3.67 −7.25
Czech Republic CZE 1.71 0.82
Hungary HUN 2.95 2.19
Poland POL −15.41 −3.13
Romania ROM −12.96 −7.32
Russian Federation RUS 167.14 9.99
Slovak Republic SVK 0.79 0.87
Slovenia SVN −1.51 −3.13
Ukraine UKR −14.64 −9.71
Latin America and Caribbean
Argentina ARG 12.79 3.14
Bolivia BOL 1.00 4.58
Brazil BRA 22.09 0.96
Chile CHL 12.13 5.22
Colombia COL 3.21 1.04
External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange rates 231
Table 7.2 (continued)
Country 3- letter code Trade balance
US$ billion Percent of GDP
Latin America and Caribbean
Costa Rica CRI −6.25 −16.22
Ecuador ECU −1.10 −1.77
El Salvador SLV −4.48 −20.13
Guatemala GTM −4.78 −10.82
Honduras HND −4.13 −25.19
Mexico MEX −6.37 −0.58
Peru PER 8.10 4.90
Trinidad and Tobago TTO 4.62 −21.28
Uruguay URY −1.08 −2.50
Venezuela RB VEN 35.82 10.09
Middle East and North Africa
Egypt Arab Rep. EGY −20.24 −9.03
Iran Islamic Rep. IRN 48.03
Israel ISR −5.61 −2.44
Jordan JOR −7.96 −28.80
Kuwait KWT 64.24 42.69
Saudi Arabia SAU 196.47 38.24
Turkey TUR −74.93 −9.95
Sub- Saharan Africa
Ethiopia ETH −5.16 −18.17
Ghana GHA −3.17 −8.88
Kenya KEN −7.42 −22.56
Mauritius MUS −2.13 −20.36
Nigeria NGA 29.68 12.56
Senegal SEN −1.97 −14.52
South Africa ZAF 1.93 0.50
Tanzania TZA −3.87 −16.56
Notes:
5 data not available; RB 5 República Bolivariana.
This table reports the country sample outside of the developing Asia region, trade balances
in US$ billion and as percent of GDP as well as the 3- letter codes used to denote the
countries.
Source: World Development Indicators.
232 Asia and global production networks
what the surplus countries are getting in return for running a surplus.
Presumably, in the real world they are accumulating foreign assets that
they can draw on to raise consumption at some future date. Thus, our
welfare comparisons should not be thought of as capturing the full
present discounted value of eliminating trade imbalances. Rather, they
should be seen as capturing utility from current period consumption,
relative to the counterfactual current period consumption in the world
without imbalances. Note that while our welfare results are subject to
this caveat, predictions about real exchange rates and factor alloca-
tions are more straightforward to understand, since both refer to static
prices and resource allocations, and thus for those it is not crucial what
happens in future periods.
Since the model is static and there is no capital accumulation, our exer-
cise also does not feature the impact of rebalancing on the capital stock.
At the extreme, if all trade imbalances were turned into capital stock, then
a deficit country would experience not just a static loss of income but also
a dynamic loss of capital per worker. It would not be feasible to model
this channel in our model, because it cannot be identified empirically how
much of the trade deficit in each country is consumed or invested, much
less what consumption and investment would have been in the rebalancing
counterfactual.
3.1 Model Fit
Table 7.3 compares the wages, returns to capital, and trade shares in
the baseline model and in the data. The top panel shows that mean and
median wages implied by the model are very close to the data. The cor-
relation coefficient between model- implied wages and those in the data is
0.99. The second panel performs the same comparison for the return to
capital. Since it is difficult to observe the return to capital in the data, we
follow the approach adopted in the estimation of
T
j
n
’s and impute
r
n
from
an aggregate factor market clearing condition:
r
n
/w
n
5
(
1
2 a
)
L
n
/
(
a
K
n
)
,
where
a
is the aggregate share of labor in GDP, assumed to be two- thirds.
Once again, the average levels of
r
n
are very similar in the model and the
data, and the correlation between the two is about 0.97.
Next, we compare the trade shares implied by the model to those in the
data. The third panel of Table 7.3 reports the spending on domestically
produced goods as a share of overall spending,
p
j
nn
.
These values reflect the
overall trade openness, with lower values implying higher international
trade as a share of absorption. The averages are quite similar, and the
correlation between the model and data values is 0.84. Finally, the bottom
panel compares the international trade flows in the model and the data.
External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange rates 233
The averages are very close, and the correlation between model and data
is nearly 0.75.
We conclude from this exercise that our model matches quite closely
the relative incomes of countries, as well as bilateral and overall trade
flows observed in the data. We now use the model to carry out a number
of counterfactual scenarios to assess the impact of external rebalancing.
3.2 Main Results
Table 7.4 presents the impact of rebalancing in developing Asia. To ease
interpretation, we split that group of countries into those with surpluses
and deficits. Conveniently, there are seven in each group. The table
reports the change in the wage (relative to the US wage), the change in
the real exchange rate (RER) with respect to the US, the change in the
trade- weighted real exchange rate, the absolute change in the share of
labor employed in the non- tradeable sector, and the percentage change
Table 7.3 The fit of the baseline model with the data
Model Data
Wages:
mean 0.407 0.413
median 0.147 0.154
corr(model, data) 0.990
Return to capital:
mean 0.966 1.074
median 0.757 0.758
corr(model, data) 0.947
p
j
nn
mean 0.586 0.565
median 0.631 0.607
corr(model, data) 0.839
p
j
ni
, i 2 n
mean 0.006 0.006
median 0.0002 0.0002
corr(model, data) 0.747
Notes: This table reports the means and medians of wages relative to the US (top panel);
return to capital relative to the US (second panel), share of domestically produced goods
in overall spending (third panel), and share of goods from country i in overall spending
(bottom panel) in the model and in the data. Wages and return to capital in the data are
calculated as described in Appendix 7A.1.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
234 Asia and global production networks
in welfare. The units are in percentage points, with the exception of the
change in the labor share, which is expressed in absolute terms.
The RERs are defined as follows. The RER with respect to the United
States is the ratio of the price levels:
Table 7.4 Developing Asia: impact of external rebalancing
(1)
w
n
(2)
RER
(with respect
to US)
(3)
RER
(trade-
weighted)
(4)
∆ Share of
L
n
in NT
(5)
Welfare
Surplus countries
Indonesia 17.47 13.33 1.48 0.04 0.07
Kazakhstan 71.36 36.45 25.25 0.36 1.36
Malaysia 25.57 15.69 4.67 0.14 1.88
People’s
Republic of
China
16.67 12.87 1.39 0.03 0.34
Republic of
Korea
14.11 11.57 −2.24 0.01 −0.03
Taipei,China 16.22 12.25 −0.14 0.03 0.46
Thailand 18.72 13.78 1.47 0.05 0.41
Mean 25.73 16.56 4.56 0.10 0.64
Median 17.47 13.33 1.47 0.04 0.41
Deficit countries
Bangladesh 6.80 8.34 −1.65 −0.03 −2.57
Fiji −1.84 4.27 −5.55 −0.08 −4.58
India −0.25 1.17 −12.63 −0.04 −1.78
Pakistan 6.31 8.26 −8.29 −0.03 −2.86
Philippines 5.09 5.80 −5.97 −0.03 −1.34
Sri Lanka −12.13 −1.99 −10.46 −0.16 −8.14
Viet Nam 7.18 8.02 −2.25 −0.02 −1.98
Mean 1.59 4.84 −6.68 −0.06 −3.32
Median 5.09 5.80 −5.97 −0.03 −2.57
Notes:
NT 5 non- tradeable; RER 5 real exchange rate; US 5 United States of America.
Units are in percentage points, with the exception of column (2), which is the absolute
change in the share of labor in the non- tradeable sector. This table reports the changes in
wages relative to the US, the real exchange rate (both relative to the US price level and
trade- weighted), the absolute change in the share of labor in the non- tradeable sector, and
the change in welfare, due to the closing of trade imbalances world- wide.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange rates 235
RER
n,US
5
P
n
P
US
.
Thus, by convention, an increase in RER
n,US
represents a real apprecia-
tion for country n. The trade- weighted RER is defined similarly, except
that in the denominator is the trade- weighted geometric average of all the
countries with which n trades:
RER
n,tw
5
P
n
q
i
P
tw
ni
i
,
where
tw
ni
is the share of trade with country i (imports plus exports) in
total country n’s trade (imports plus exports).
A number of results stand out. The surplus countries experience a large
increase in wages relative to the US, about 20 percent on average. The
magnitude of the shift in the RER relative to the US is of similar, but
somewhat smaller, magnitude. This is to be expected, given that the US
is the largest deficit country in the world. As the US is forced to consume
less, its labor demand falls, and so do wages.
5
Interestingly, the appreciation in the trade- weighted RER for the
surplus countries in developing Asia is much more subdued, 1.47 percent
at the median compared to 13.3 percent for the US- based RER. This is to
be expected: much of these countries’ trade is with each other, and thus
even as they are all appreciating relative to the US, their trade- weighted
appreciation is much smaller. The Republic of Korea and Taipei,China
even experience modest RER depreciations.
In all of the surplus countries, external rebalancing leads to an increase
in the share of labor employed in the non- tradeable sector, as expected.
Now that these countries are not transferring income abroad, domestic
demand rises, and with it demand for non- tradeables. The change is
modest on average: at the median there is a 4 percentage point increase
in the share of labor in the non- tradeable sector. On average in this group
of countries, the share of labor in the non- tradeable sector is two- thirds.
For the PRC, for instance, the labor share in non- tradeables increases by
3 percentage points.
Finally, the impact of external rebalancing on welfare is much smaller
than on either relative wages or RERs. At the median, these countries
experience a rise in welfare of 0.41 percent, 2 orders of magnitude less
than the average increase in the relative wage. This is sensible: as these
countries’ relative wages rise dramatically, so do domestic prices. The net
impact is positive (with the sole exception of the Republic of Korea), but
236 Asia and global production networks
much smaller than the gross changes in either wages or price levels. Note
that our metric for welfare is real factor income (7.6). Thus, we ignore any
direct impact of changes in D
n
on consumption.
The bottom half of Table 7.4 presents the results for the deficit countries
in developing Asia. Starting with the relative wage, for four out of seven
countries in this sample the relative wage (compared to the US) actually
rises. This is because while these countries do have deficits, the deficit of
the US is still larger. By the same token, six out of seven of these countries
actually experience a real appreciation relative to the US, even though
they also have to close their deficits. The picture becomes much clearer
when we move to the trade- weighted exchange rates. By this metric, every
single one of these countries experiences a real depreciation, with an
average of 6–7 percent.
Predictably, the share of labor devoted to the non- tradeable sector
falls in these countries due to the rebalancing. The absolute magnitudes
are similar to the surplus countries, but with the opposite sign. Finally,
all of the countries in this sample experience a fall in welfare, of about 3
percent on average. This is a much more sizeable welfare change than for
the surplus countries.
Table 7.5 presents the outcomes of the rebalancing for the rest of the
world. For the US, welfare falls by 0.85 percent. Looking at the summary
statistics across regions, we see that by and large welfare falls due to the
rebalancing, which reflects the net trade surplus Asia runs with the rest of
the world.
3.2.1 Interpretation
As expected, countries that currently run deficits spend less after the
rebalancing, and their welfare falls. Countries with observed surpluses
spend more, and their welfare rises. The relationship between welfare
changes and the initial trade balance is thus positive, and is depicted in
Figure 7.1. The initial trade balance explains quite well the subsequent
welfare change. The correlation between these two for developing Asia
is 0.81. Note that our welfare numbers do not include the direct effect of
consuming the trade surplus (see Section 2.3). The positive welfare impact
of rebalancing comes from the general equilibrium effect of changes in
domestic spending on the demand for factors of production, and thus on
real wages and the return to capital.
While changes in domestic spending have an impact on countries, in
a world integrated through trade we would also expect changes in the
trade balances of one’s trading partner to affect welfare. Intuitively, an
increase in spending in one’s trading partner is expected to stimulate a
country’s exports and therefore increase the demand for that country’s
External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange rates 237
Table 7.5 Rest of the world: impact of external rebalancing
(1)
w
n
(2)
RER
(with respect
to US)
(3)
RER
(trade-
weighted)
(4)
∆ Share of
L
n
in NT
(5)
Welfare
Organisation for Economic Co- operation and Development
Australia 16.88 12.92 2.15 0.02 0.41
Austria 10.71 8.96 −1.88 −0.01 −0.23
Belgium-
Luxembourg
9.36 8.17 −1.65 −0.01 −0.43
Canada 5.89 4.26 0.27 0.00 −0.27
Denmark 14.82 11.69 1.03 0.01 0.12
Finland 14.29 11.54 −1.26 0.01 0.04
France 7.48 6.34 −3.63 −0.01 −0.38
Germany 16.00 12.25 2.20 0.02 0.36
Greece −11.14 −6.64 −17.30 −0.07 −3.40
Iceland 17.63 13.52 2.13 0.02 0.40
Ireland 33.55 20.29 12.82 0.15 1.71
Italy 9.41 7.82 −2.36 −0.01 −0.28
Japan 13.41 11.03 −1.81 0.00 −0.04
Netherlands 18.37 13.40 2.49 0.03 0.59
New Zealand 13.75 10.87 −0.79 0.01 −0.02
Norway 26.27 18.36 8.61 0.07 1.22
Portugal −3.11 −1.13 −9.36 −0.05 −1.84
Spain 4.17 3.96 −5.79 −0.02 −0.79
Sweden 14.43 11.61 0.23 0.01 0.05
Switzerland 16.08 12.39 2.56 0.03 0.25
United
Kingdom
4.61 4.66 −5.07 −0.02 −0.99
United States 0.00 0.00 −9.54 −0.03 −0.85
Mean 11.49 8.92 −1.18 0.01 −0.20
Median 13.58 10.95 −1.02 0.01 −0.03
Central and Eastern Europe
Bulgaria −2.32 1.87 −6.97 −0.09 −3.12
Czech
Republic
12.86 10.26 −0.44 0.01 0.04
Hungary 13.71 10.64 0.08 0.01 0.20
Poland 7.97 7.54 −3.41 −0.02 −0.73
Romania 4.40 5.18 −4.31 −0.04 −1.31
Russian
Federation
48.2 30.07 18.58 0.15 1.24
238 Asia and global production networks
Table 7.5 (continued)
(1)
w
n
(2)
RER
(with respect
to US)
(3)
RER
(trade-
weighted)
(4)
∆ Share of
L
n
in NT
(5)
Welfare
Central and Eastern Europe
Slovak
Republic
12.91 10.27 −0.56 0.01 0.07
Slovenia 9.08 7.92 −1.79 −0.02 −0.41
Ukraine −3.84 3.44 −11.86 −0.10 −5.08
Mean 11.44 9.69 −1.19 −0.01 −1.01
Median 9.08 7.92 −1.79 −0.02 −0.41
Latin America and Caribbean
Argentina 16.43 11.78 1.33 0.02 0.67
Bolivia 13.03 10.70 0.20 0.01 0.41
Brazil 14.20 11.32 0.11 0.01 0.13
Chile 17.15 12.25 2.98 0.03 0.80
Colombia 12.71 9.84 3.30 0.01 0.09
Costa Rica −17.65 −9.17 −12.48 −0.12 −6.78
Ecuador 8.91 7.75 0.43 −0.01 −0.60
El Salvador −4.84 −1.20 −2.23 −0.09 −3.41
Guatemala −21.90 −11.24 −14.43 −0.14 −8.75
Honduras −13.93 −3.87 −5.57 −0.16 −7.98
Mexico 5.93 4.44 0.96 0.00 −0.49
Peru 22.83 15.40 6.43 0.07 1.20
Trinidad and
Tobago
42.53 22.05 15.67 0.14 1.63
Uruguay 6.83 7.02 −4.02 −0.03 −1.06
Venezuela,
RB
51.46 25.05 19.67 0.20 1.91
Mean 10.25 7.48 0.82 0.00 −1.48
Median 12.71 9.84 0.43 0.01 0.09
Middle East and North Africa
Egypt, Arab
Rep.
−4.06 3.54 −8.03 −0.08 −5.55
Iran, Islamic
Rep.
52.80 37.61 25.26 0.16 0.82
Israel 6.10 5.34 −1.42 −0.02 −0.68
Jordan −27.74 −5.33 −23.57 −0.21 −18.50
Kuwait 62.02 34.61 22.50 0.37 2.27
Saudi Arabia 475.00 94.41 79.80 4.60 −34.55
External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange rates 239
factors of production. It turns out that a country’s welfare changes due
to global rebalancing are strongly positively correlated with whether it
exports mostly to the deficit or to surplus countries. Figure 7.2 presents
a scatterplot of welfare changes on the y- axis against the export- share-
weighted deficit of a country’s trading partners. That is, if a country
exports disproportionately to countries currently running deficits, it will
have negative values on the x- axis, and vice versa. There is a pronounced
positive relationship: countries exporting mostly to deficit countries tend
to experience a fall in welfare, while countries exporting more to surplus
countries tend to increase their welfare. The correlation between the
two variables is 0.82. This scatterplot demonstrates the importance of
Table 7.5 (continued)
(1)
w
n
(2)
RER
(with respect
to US)
(3)
RER
(trade-
weighted)
(4)
∆ Share of
L
n
in NT
(5)
Welfare
Middle East and North Africa
Turkey −2.90 1.69 −9.61 −0.09 −3.68
Mean 80.17 24.55 12.13 0.68 −8.55
Median 6.10 5.34 −1.42 −0.02 −3.68
Sub- Saharan Africa
Ethiopia 7.59 10.73 −5.77 −0.03 −3.90
Ghana 6.73 7.51 −4.06 −0.03 −1.60
Kenya 1.21 2.02 −9.71 −0.03 −1.68
Mauritius −12.99 −5.25 −11.59 −0.13 −6.33
Nigeria 76.01 52.98 43.97 0.26 0.39
Senegal 6.62 7.08 −4.18 −0.02 −1.62
South Africa 12.40 10.11 −2.05 0.00 −0.04
Tanzania −9.77 −2.06 −10.63 −0.07 −6.67
Mean 10.98 10.39 −0.50 0.00 −2.68
Median 6.68 7.29 - 4.98 - 0.03 −1.65
Notes:
NT 5 non- tradeable; RB 5 República Bolivariana; RER 5 real exchange rate; US 5
United States of America.
Units are in percentage points, with the exception of column (2), which is the absolute
change in the share of labor in the non- tradeable sector. This table reports the changes in
wages relative to the US, the real exchange rate (both relative to the US price level and
trade- weighted), the absolute change in the share of labor in the non- tradeable sector, and
the change in welfare, due to the closing of trade imbalances world- wide.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
240 Asia and global production networks
multilateral trade relationships for fully understanding the importance of
rebalancing.
To be more concrete, we can compare the major export destinations
of Sri Lanka and Bangladesh to those of Kazakhstan and Taipei,China.
Thirty- seven percent of Sri Lanka’s and 30 percent of Bangladesh’s
exports go to the US and the UK, the major deficit countries in the world.
Thus, a rebalancing hurts the demand for their exports, and leads to
reductions in their welfare. By contrast, 21 percent of Kazakhstan’s and 35
percent of Taipei,China’s exports go to the PRC, the major trade surplus
country. This difference in the identity of the major export destination
corresponds well to the difference in the welfare impact of rebalancing in
these four countries.
4. CONCLUSION
Fast- growing countries often run sustained trade surpluses. A natural
question going forward is what would be the long- run impact of external
rebalancing narrowing or elimination of trade imbalances on the
BAN
FIJ
IND
INO
KAZ
MAL
PAK
PRC
PHI
KOR
SRI
TAP
THA
VIE
–10
–5
0
5
–0.3 –0.2 –0.1 0 0.1 0.2 0.3
Percent change in welfare (%)
Trade balance/GDP
Note: This figure displays the welfare gains to developing Asian countries from external
rebalancing against their trade balance as a share of GDP, along with the least- squares fit.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure 7.1 Developing Asia: initial trade balances and change in welfare
External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange rates 241
economies of developing Asia and the rest of the world. In this chapter,
we evaluate this question using a quantitative multi- country, multi-
sector model of world production and trade that includes 14 economies
of developing Asia as well as 61 other major economies from the rest of
the world.
In our developing Asia sample, there are seven surplus countries and
seven deficit ones. For the surplus countries (the PRC, Malaysia, and
others), the global external rebalancing brings about a significant rise in
relative wages, a real appreciation, an increase in the size of the non- traded
sector, and an increase in welfare of a fraction of 1 percent on average.
For the deficit countries, the impacts are the opposite: a real deprecia-
tion, a shrinking of the non- traded sector, and a 2–3 percent reduction in
welfare. We show that multilateral trade relationships are important for
developing the full account of the impact of global rebalancing: countries
currently exporting mostly to deficit countries tend to lose from rebalanc-
ing, whereas countries exporting to the surplus countries tend to gain in
welfare.
BAN
FIJ
IND
INO
KAZ
MAL
PAK
PRC
PHI
KOR
SRI
TAP
THA
VIE
–10
–8
–6
–4
–2
0
2
4
–200 –150 –100 –50 0 50
Percent change in welfare (%)
Trade-weighted deficit of export destinations ($ billion)
Note: This figure displays the welfare gains to developing Asian countries from external
rebalancing against the export- share weighted trade imbalances of their trading partners,
along with the least- squares fit. The units on the x- axis are US$ billions.
Source: Authors’ calculations.
Figure 7.2 Developing Asia: trade balances in export destinations and
change in welfare
242 Asia and global production networks
NOTES
* We are grateful to the participants of the ADB Global Supply Chain Conference for
helpful suggestions.
1. Shikher (2005, 2011, 2012), Burstein and Vogel (2012), and Eaton et al. (2011), among
others, follow the same approach of assuming the same
q
across sectors. Caliendo and
Parro (2010) use tariff data and triple differencing to estimate sector- level
q.
However,
their approach may suffer from significant measurement error: at times the values of
q
they estimate are negative. In addition, in each sector the restriction that
q . e 2 1
must
be satisfied, and it is not clear whether Caliendo and Parro (2010) estimated sectoral
q
’s
meet this restriction in every case. Our approach is thus conservative by being agnostic
on this variation across sectors.
2. Di Giovanni and Levchenko (2010) provide suggestive evidence that at such a coarse
level of aggregation, input–output matrices are indeed similar across countries. To check
robustness of the results, we collected country- specific I–O matrices from the GTAP
database. Productivities computed based on country- specific IO matrices were very
similar to the baseline values. In our sample of countries, the median correlation was
0.98, with all but 3 out of 75 countries having a correlation of 0.93 or above, and the
minimum correlation of 0.65.
3. The US IO matrix provides an alternative way of computing
a
j
and
b
j
.
These parameters
calculated based on the US IO table are very similar to those obtained from UNIDO,
with the correlation coefficients between them above 0.85 in each case. The US IO table
implies greater variability in
a
j
’s and
b
j
’s across sectors than does UNIDO.
4. Using the variable name conventions in the Penn World Tables,
L
n
5
1000* pop*rgdpch/
rgdpwok.
5. Note that this is not a necessary outcome. Rebalancing in the US requires a shift of
domestic factors of production from the non- tradeable to the tradeable sectors. If the
tradeable sectors were more labor- intensive than the non- tradeable sectors, this may
actually raise labor demand in the US, since in that case factors would be reallocating
from capital- to labor- intensive sectors. In practice, it is if anything the opposite: trade-
able sectors are on average less labor intensive than non- tradeable ones, though the dif-
ference is not drastic (Table 7A.1).
REFERENCES
Bartelsman, E.J. and W. Gray (1996), ‘The NBER manufacturing productivity
database’, NBER Technical Working Paper 205.
Bernanke, B. and R. Gürkaynak (2001), ‘Is growth exogenous? Taking Mankiw,
Romer, and Weil seriously’, NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 16, 11–57.
Berthelon, M. and C. Freund (2008), ‘On the conservation of distance in interna-
tional trade’, Journal of International Economics, 75, 310–320.
Burstein, A. and J. Vogel (2012), ‘International trade, technology, and the skill
premium’, Mimeo, UCLA and Columbia University.
Caliendo, L. and F. Parro (2010), ‘Estimates of the trade and welfare effects of
NAFTA’, Mimeo, University of Chicago.
Caselli, F. (2005), ‘Accounting for cross- country income differences’, in S. Durlauf
and P. Aghion (eds), Handbook of Economic Growth, 1, Elsevier- North Holland,
679–741.
Dekle, R., J. Eaton, and S. Kortum (2007), ‘Unbalanced trade’, American Economic
Review: Papers and Proceedings, 97, 351–355.
External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange rates 243
Dekle, R., J. Eaton, and S. Kortum (2008), ‘Global rebalancing with gravity:
measuring the burden of adjustment’, IMF Staff Papers, 55, 511–540.
di Giovanni, J. and A.A. Levchenko (2010), ‘Putting the parts together: trade,
vertical linkages, and business cycle comovement’, American Economic Journal:
Macroeconomics, 2, 95–124.
Do, Q.- T. and A.A. Levchenko (2007), ‘Comparative advantage, demand for
external finance, and financial development’, Journal of Financial Economics,
86 (3).
Dornbusch, R., S. Fischer, and P. Samuelson (1977), ‘Comparative advantage,
trade, and payments in a Ricardian model with a continuum of goods’, American
Economic Review, 67, 823–39.
Eaton, J. and S. Kortum (2002), ‘Technology, geography, and trade’, Econometrica,
70, 1741–1779.
Eaton, J., S. Kortum, B. Neiman, and J. Romalis (2011), ‘Trade and the global
recession’, NBER Working Paper No. 16666.
Finicelli, A., P. Pagano, and M. Sbracia (2013), ‘Ricardian selection’, Journal of
International Economics, 89, 96–106.
Hall, R. and C. Jones (1999), ‘Why do some countries produce so much more
output per worker than others?’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 83–116.
Herrendorf, B., R. Rogerson, and A. Valentinyi (2013), ‘Two perspectives on
preferences and structural transformation’, American Economic Review, 103,
2752–2789.
Hummels, D., J. Ishii, and K.- M. Yi (2001), ‘The nature and growth of vertical
specialization in world trade’, Journal of International Economics, 54, 75–96.
Levchenko, A.A. and J. Zhang (2011), ‘The evolution of comparative advantage:
measurement and welfare implications’, NBER Working Paper No. 16806.
Obstfeld, M. and K.S. Rogoff (2005), ‘Global current account imbalances and
exchange rate adjustments’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 36, 67–146.
Salter, W.E.G. (1959), ‘Internal and external balance: the role of price and expend-
iture effects’, Economic Record, 35, 226–238.
Shikher, S. (2005), ‘Accounting for international trade’, Mimeo, Suffolk University.
Shikher, S. (2011), ‘Capital, technology, and specialization in the neoclassical
model’, Journal of International Economics, 83, 229–242.
Shikher, S. (2012), ‘Putting industries into the Eaton- Kortum model’, Journal of
International Trade and Economic Development, 21, 807–837.
Simonovska, I. and M.E. Waugh (2011), ‘The elasticity of trade: estimates and
evidence’, University of California Davis Working Paper No. 11- 2.
Swan, T.W. (1960), ‘Economic control in a dependent economy’, Economic Record,
36, 51–66.
Świe¸cki, T. (2013), ‘Intersectoral distortions, structural change and the welfare
gains from trade’, Mimeo, Princeton University.
Uy, T., K.- M. Yi, and J. Zhang (2013), ‘Structural change in an open economy’,
Journal of Monetary Economics, 60, 667–682.
Waugh, M. (2010), ‘International trade and income differences’, American Economic
Review, 100, 2093–2124.
244 Asia and global production networks
APPENDIX 7A.1 PROCEDURE FOR ESTIMATING
T
j
n
,
D
j
ni
,
AND
w
j
This appendix reproduces from Levchenko and Zhang (2011) the details
of the procedure for estimating technology, trade costs, and taste param-
eters required to implement the model. Interested readers should consult
that paper for further details on estimation steps and data sources.
7A.1 Tradeable Sector Relative Technology
We now focus on the tradeable sectors. Following the standard EK
approach, first divide trade shares by their domestic counterpart:
p
j
ni
p
j
nn
5
X
j
ni
X
j
nn
5
T
j
i
(
c
j
i
d
j
ni
)
2q
T
j
n
(
c
j
n
)
2q
,
which in logs becomes:
Let the (log) iceberg costs be given by the following expression:
ln d
j
ni
5 d
j
k
1 b
j
ni
1 CU
j
ni
1 RTA
j
ni
1 ex
j
i
1 v
j
ni
,
where
d
j
k
is an indicator variable for a distance interval. Following EK, we
set the distance intervals, in miles, to [0, 350], [350, 750], [750, 1500], [1500,
3000], [3000, 6000], [6000, maximum). Additional variables are whether
the two countries share a common border (
b
j
ni
), belong to a currency union
(
CU
j
ni
), or to a regional trade agreement (
RTA
j
ni
). Following the arguments
in Waugh (2010), we include an exporter fixed effect
ex
j
i
.
Finally, there is
an error term
v
j
ni
.
Note that all the variables have a sector superscript j: we
allow all the trade cost proxy variables to affect true iceberg trade costs
d
j
ni
differentially across sectors. There is a range of evidence that trade
volumes at sector level vary in their sensitivity to distance or common
border (see, among many others, Do and Levchenko 2007, Berthelon and
Freund 2008).
This leads to the following final estimating equation:
ln
a
X
j
ni
X
j
nn
b
5 ln
(
T
j
i
(
c
j
i
)
2q
)
2 qex
j
i
2ln
(
T
j
n
(
c
j
n
)
2q
)
Exporter Fixed Eect
Importer Fixed Eect
2qd
j
k
2 qb
j
ni
2 qCU
j
ni
2 qRTA
j
ni
2 qv
j
ni
.
Bilateral Observables Error Term
External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange rates 245
This equation is estimated for each tradeable sector j 5 1,. . .J. Estimating
this relationship will thus yield, for each country, an estimate of its
technology- cum- unit- cost term in each sector j,
T
j
n
(
c
j
n
)
2q
,
which is obtained
by exponentiating the importer fixed effect. The available degrees of
freedom imply that these estimates are of each country’s
T
j
n
(
c
j
n
)
2q
relative
to a reference country, which in our estimation is the United States. We
denote this estimated value by
S
j
n
:
S
j
n
2
T
j
n
T
j
us
a
c
j
n
c
j
us
b
2q
,
where the subscript us denotes the United States. It is immediate from this
expression that estimation delivers a convolution of technology parameters
T
j
n
and cost parameters
c
j
n
.
Both will of course affect trade volumes, but we
would like to extract technology
T
j
n
from these estimates. In order to do that,
we follow the approach of Shikher (2012). In particular, for each country n,
the share of total spending going to home- produced goods is given by
X
j
nn
X
j
n
5 T
j
n
a
Gc
j
n
p
j
n
b
2q
Dividing by its US counterpart yields:
X
j
nn
/X
j
n
X
j
us,us
/X
j
us
5
T
j
n
T
j
us
a
c
j
n
c
j
us
p
j
us
p
j
n
b
2q
5 S
j
n
a
p
j
us
p
j
n
b
2q
,
and thus the ratio of price levels in sector j relative to the US becomes:
p
j
n
p
j
us
5
a
X
j
nn
/X
j
n
X
j
us,us
/X
j
us
1
S
j
n
b
1
q
. (7A.1)
The entire right- hand side of this expression is either observable or esti-
mated. Thus, we can impute the price levels relative to the US in each
country and each tradeable sector.
The cost of the input bundles relative to the US can be written as:
c
j
n
c
j
us
5
a
w
n
w
us
b
a
j
b
j
a
r
n
r
us
b
(
1
2 a
j
)
b
j
a
q
J
k5 1
a
p
k
n
p
k
us
b
g
k,j
b
1
2 b
j
a
p
J1 1
n
p
J1 1
us
b
g
J 1 1,j
(
1
2 b
j
)
.
Using information on relative wages, returns to capital, price in each
tradeable sector from (7A.1), and the non- tradeable sector price relative
to the US, we can thus impute the costs of the input bundles relative to
246 Asia and global production networks
the US in each country and each sector. Armed with those values, it is
straightforward to back out the relative technology parameters:
T
j
n
T
j
us
5 S
j
n
a
c
j
n
c
j
us
b
2q
.
7A.2 Trade Costs
The bilateral, directional, sector- level trade costs of shipping from country
i to country n in sector j are then computed based on the estimated
coefficients as:
ln d
ˆ
j
ni
5 q
d
ˆ
j
k
1 q
ˆ
b
j
ni
1 q
CU
j
ni
1 q
RTA
j
ni
1 q
ex
j
ni
1 q
v
ˆ
j
ni
for an assumed value of
q.
Note that the estimate of the trade costs includes
the residual from the gravity regression
qv
ˆ
j
ni
.
Thus, the trade costs computed
as above will fit bilateral sectoral trade flows exactly, given the estimated
fixed effects. Note also that the exporter component of the trade costs
qex
j
ni
is part of the exporter fixed effect. Since each country in the sample appears
as both an exporter and an importer, the exporter and importer estimated
fixed effects are combined to extract an estimate of
qex
j
ni
.
7A.3 Complete Estimation
So far we have estimated the levels of technology of the tradeable sectors rel-
ative to the United States. To complete our estimation, we still need to find
(i) the levels of T for the tradeable sectors in the United States; (ii) the taste
parameters
w
j
,
and (iii) the non- tradeable technology levels for all countries.
To obtain (i), we use the NBER- CES Manufacturing Industry Database
for the US (Bartelsman and Gray 1996). We start by measuring the
observed total factor productivity (TFP) levels for the tradeable sectors in
the US. The form of the production function gives
ln Z
j
us
5
ln
L
j
us
ln
1b
j
a
j
lnL
j
us
1 b
j
(
1
2 a
j
)
ln K
j
us
1
(
1 2 b
j
)
a
J1 1
k5 1
g
k,j
lnM
k,j
us
(7A.2)
where
L
j
denotes the measured TFP in sector j,
Z
j
denotes the output,
L
j
denotes the labor input,
K
j
denotes the capital input, and
M
k, j
denotes
the intermediate input from sector k. The NBER- CES Manufacturing
Industry Database offers information on output, and inputs of labor,
capital, and intermediates, along with deflators for each. Thus, we can
7
7
7
7
7
External rebalancing, structural adjustment, and real exchange rates 247
estimate the observed TFP level for each manufacturing tradeable sector
using the above equation.
If the United States were a closed economy, the observed TFP level for
sector j would be given by L
j
us
5
(
T
j
us
)
1
q
. In the open economies, the goods
with inefficient domestic productivity draws will not be produced and will
be imported instead. Thus, international trade and competition introduce
selection in the observed TFP level, as demonstrated by Finicelli et al.
(2013). We thus use the model to back out the true level of
T
j
us
of each
tradeable sector in the United States. Here we follow Finicelli et al. (2013)
and use the following relationship:
(
L
j
us
)
q
5 T
j
us
1
a
i2 us
T
j
i
a
c
j
i
d
j
us,i
c
j
us
b
2q
Thus, we have
(
L
j
us
)
q
5 T
j
us
c
1 1
a
i2 us
T
j
i
T
j
us
a
c
j
i
d
j
us,i
c
j
us
b
2q
d
5 T
j
us
c
1 1
a
i2 us
S
j
i
(
d
j
us,i
)
2q
d
. (7A.3)
This equation can be solved for underlying technology parameters
T
j
us
in the US, given estimated observed TFP
L
j
us
,
and all the
S
j
i
’s and
d
j
us,i
’s
estimated in the previous subsection.
To estimate the taste parameters
{
w
j
}
J
j
5
1
,
we use information on final
consumption shares in the tradeable sectors in the US. We start with
a guess of
{
w
j
}
J
j
5
1
and find sectoral prices
p
k
n
as follows. For an initial
guess of sectoral prices, we compute the tradeable sector aggregate price
and the non- tradeable sector price using the data on the relative prices of
non- tradeables to tradeables. Using these prices, we calculate sectoral unit
costs and
F
j
n
’s, and update prices according to equation (7.3), iterating
until the prices converge. We then update the taste parameters according
to equation (7.5), using the data on final sectoral expenditure shares in the
US. We normalize the vector of
w
j
’s to have a sum of one, and repeat the
above procedure until the values for the taste parameters converge.
Finally, we estimate the non- tradeable sector TFP using the relative
prices. In the model, the non- tradeable sector price is given by
p
J1 1
n
5 G
(
T
J1 1
n
)
2
1
q
c
J1 1
n
.
Since we know the aggregate price level in the tradeable sector
p
T
n
,
c
J1 1
n
,
and the relative price of non- tradeables (which we take from the data), we
can back out
T
J1 1
n
from the equation above for all countries.
248 Asia and global production networks
Table 7A.1 Sectors
ISIC code Sector Name
a
j
b
j
g
J
1
1, j
w
j
15 Food and beverages 0.290 0.290 0.303 0.169
16 Tobacco products 0.272 0.490 0.527 0.014
17 Textiles 0.444 0.368 0.295 0.019
18 Wearing apparel, fur 0.468 0.369 0.320 0.109
19 Leather, leather products,
Footwear
0.469 0.350 0.330 0.015
20 Wood products (excl.
furniture)
0.455 0.368 0.288 0.008
21 Paper and paper products 0.351 0.341 0.407 0.012
22 Printing and publishing 0.484 0.453 0.407 0.005
23 Coke, refined petroleum
products, nuclear fuel
0.248 0.246 0.246 0.141
24 Chemical and chemical
products
0.297 0.368 0.479 0.009
25 Rubber and plastics products 0.366 0.375 0.350 0.014
26 Non- metallic mineral products 0.350 0.448 0.499 0.073
27 Basic metals 0.345 0.298 0.451 0.002
28 Fabricated metal products 0.424 0.387 0.364 0.013
29C Office, accounting, computing,
and other machinery
0.481 0.381 0.388 0.051
31A Electrical machinery,
communication equipment
0.369 0.368 0.416 0.022
33 Medical, precision, and optical
instruments
0.451 0.428 0.441 0.038
34A Transport equipment 0.437 0.329 0.286 0.220
36 Furniture and other
manufacturing
0.447 0.396 0.397 0.065
4A Non- tradeables 0.561 0.651 0.788
Mean 0.400 0.385 0.399 0.053
Min. 0.248 0.246 0.246 0.002
Max. 0.561 0.651 0.788 0.220
Notes:
5 data not available; ISIC 5 International Standard Industrial Classification of All
Economic Activities.
This table reports the sectors used in the analysis. The classification corresponds to the
ISICRevision 3, 2- digit, aggregated further due to data availability.
a
j
is the value- added
based labor intensity;
b
j
is the share of value added in total output;
g
J
1
1,j
is the share of
non- tradeable inputs in total intermediate inputs;
w
j
is the taste parameter for tradeable
sector j, estimated using the procedure described in Section A7.3.
Variable definitions and sources are described in detail in the text.
249
8. Global supply chains and
macroeconomic relationships in
Asia
Menzie Chinn*
1. INTRODUCTION
One of the key challenges to the analysis of open economy macroeconomic
interactions involves the understanding of how flows in goods and serv-
ices, capital and asset prices respond in a world where trade is not limited
to final goods, but includes (potentially many) stages of intermediate
production. That is particularly true in parts of the world deeply involved
in trade in global supply chains the phenomenon wherein a final good
is produced in separate countries. Nowhere has this process of produc-
tion fragmentation extended as far as in East Asia: hence, the need for an
examination of the macroeconomic implications for the region.
In this chapter, I survey the various channels by which economic inter-
actions might evolve with increasing integration. First, I assess the impli-
cations for the measurement of macroeconomic variables; in particular the
real exchange rate the relative price of traded goods and services will
become more difficult to measure. One can no longer merely apply the
final good prices to deflate the nominal exchange rate; rather one would
need to keep track of the value added at each stage of production and
where it took place.
Second, I assess the ramifications for the measurement of the relation-
ship between exchange rates and trade flows, when relative prices and
trade flows are properly measured.
Third, the impact of greater vertical specialization on exchange rate
pass- through into traded goods prices is examined.
Fourth, I assess the evidence on business cycle synchronization. With
production fragmented across economies, in principle an additional
channel has been added to the other means by which shocks are propa-
gated across economies.
Finally, I investigate the conjecture that increasing integration by
250 Asia and global production networks
way of global supply chains will lead to increasing motivation for poli-
cymakers to stabilize nominal exchange rates, insofar as exchange rate
volatility complicates planning and production in integrated production
chains.
The following conclusions stem from the survey.
First, the conventional means of measuring international competitive-
ness are going to be less and less adequate, as production becomes more
fragmented. Relatedly, it will become less and less tenable to estimate
the traditional partial equilibrium trade equations in order to obtain
macro- level trade elasticities, as mis- measurement of trade flows becomes
more pronounced, and appropriate deflators for real exchange rates
diverge further from the typically used deflators.
Second, the increasing role of intermediate inputs will likely drive
down exchange rate pass- through. This is true even if the increase is
due to increasing arms- length transactions. However, to the extent that
pass- through is less pronounced the greater the amount of intra- firm
trade, a further decrease in exchange rate pass- through is likely to occur.
Third, business cycle correlations are rising throughout the region. The
more prominent increases are often associated with the People’s Republic
of China (PRC), a finding consistent with the country’s growing role in the
global supply chain. Furthermore, the propagation of shocks throughout
the East Asia system is consistent with the PRC driving movements in
output, at least in the Republic of Korea and Taipei,China.
Finally, there is evidence that the central banks of the region are paying
more heed to the Chinese currency’s value, at the high frequency (daily)
and at lower frequency (monthly), with respect to rates of depreciation,
as well as levels of exchange rates. Since these relationships are not struc-
tural, there is no guarantee that they will remain in place. At the same
time, continued integration by way of production fragmentation should
make central bankers pay extra attention to stabilizing currency values
against each other.
2. THE MEASUREMENT OF THE REAL EFFECTIVE
EXCHANGE RATE
1
The real exchange rate occupies a central role in international finance as
the key relative price between home and foreign goods. In a world where
trade is in final goods, and all goods are traded, the real exchange rate
definition is relatively clear:
q
t
; s
t
2 p
t
1 p*
t
(8.1)
Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships in Asia 251
where s is the log nominal exchange rate expressed in home currency units
per foreign, and p is the log price level for home final goods, and p
*
for
foreign final goods. Then q denotes the number of home units of final
goods necessary to obtain one unit of foreign.
This simple expression can be complicated in a number of ways, depend-
ing upon whether there are nontraded goods, or whether final goods are
the only goods traded.
2
The fact that there are multiple countries should
not complicate the expression terribly. Then the real exchange rate is a
weighted average of the exchange rates and price levels corresponding
to the various trade partners. The complication involves what weights to
attribute to each bilateral real exchange rate.
3
The correct definition of the real exchange rate is altered when there is
trade in intermediate goods. Then one can ask either of two questions. The
first is whether agents have preferences over the value added originating
in different countries, or preferences over final goods. This distinction is
sometimes characterized as the difference between trade in tasks versus
trade in goods.
Let’s consider the first approach. Then, the appropriate definition of
the relative price of traded output is the relative price of value added
expressed in common currency terms. In practical terms, this greatly com-
plicates the calculation of the relative price. Now one has to keep track of
where inputs come from, and measure the appropriate price deflators for
the amount of value added actually incorporated into the good in a given
country.
Bems and Johnson (2012) argue that the conventional real effective
exchange rates incorporating prices of gross sales do not conform to any
theoretically justified measure – not even one in which goods are produced
without imported intermediates. In addition, the popular expedient of
using consumer price indices instead of price indices of the goods traded
introduces another possible difference. Of course the relevant question is
whether in practice the conventional measures deviate substantially from
the theoretically more correct measures.
In practice, Bems and Johnson find that in many cases the appropri-
ate effective exchange rates do differ from the conventionally used ones.
However, the differences are most pronounced for exactly those instances
wherein one would expect the biggest differences the PRC, Germany,
other East Asian economies. Figures 8.1a–c depict the conventional (IMF)
real effective exchange rates and the Bems–Johnson value added counter-
parts for the PRC, Japan and Republic of Korea (all graphed so that a rise
denotes an appreciation).
Interestingly, the big differences in the real exchange rate values are not
driven by the adjustment in trade weights. Rather the main factor is in the
252 Asia and global production networks
Value added deflator IMF price deflator
–0.2
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
1980
(a) People’s Republic of China
IndexIndexIndex
(b) Japan
(c) Republic of Korea
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
Value added deflator IMF price deflator
–0.8
–0.7
–0.6
–0.5
–0.4
–0.3
–0.2
–0.1
0.0
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
Value added deflator IMF price deflator
–0.6
–0.5
–0.4
–0.3
–0.2
–0.1
0.0
0.1
0.2
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
Note: IMF – International Monetary Fund.
Source: Bems and Johnson (2012) and IMF.
Figure 8.1 Real effective exchange rates (1995 = 100)
Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships in Asia 253
use of a value- added deflator, rather than the consumer price index (CPI).
It has always been known that the use of the CPI is likely to lead to mis-
taken inferences regarding relative prices due to the heavy weight adduced
to services and other nontraded goods in CPIs.
4
For instance, over the 1995–2009 period, the Chinese effective exchange
rate appreciated 11.4 percentage points more than was implied using the
conventional (CPI, trade weighted) measured using log changes (Figure
8.1a).
5
Relative to 2000, the differential is 8.8 percentage points. Had
this result been known in 2005–2006, the controversy over yuan (CNY)
exchange rate misalignment might have been less heated. Most of the dif-
ference is attributable not to the difference in trade weights, but rather to
the difference in use of the deflator.
6
Japan is another case of a country deeply involved in the East Asian
global supply chain. In this instance, as of 2009, the cumulative gap
between the conventional and value added series, both based on year
1995, amounted to 21.7 percentage points more after taking into account
intermediate goods and the correct deflator than was indicated using the
conventional measure (Figure 8.1b). This result casts in a different light
the increase in the trade balance in the years leading up to the global
financial crisis; apparently the improvement was driven by a greater than
measured yen depreciation. The Korean value added measure also shows
a less pronounced appreciation than the conventional measure (Figure
8.1c).
Notice the correct deflator is not the deflator for all of gross domestic
product (GDP), but for the value added component imbedded in traded
goods. The two might move together, but there are no guarantees. CPIs
are likely to deviate even further from the ideal deflator.
The Bems–Johnson approach focuses on value added. An alternative
approach is to view trade as driven by preferences over final goods – that
is, the price of the final good, but taking into account the price savings
due to outsourcing of production is key. This approach is taken up by
Bayoumi et al. (2013).
In this approach, one wants to take into account the costs along the
entire production chain, i.e., taking into account outsourcing of produc-
tion. As mentioned before, this approach makes more sense if preferences
are expressed over goods, rather than value- added. Bayoumi et al. imple-
ment this alternative approach and show that the impact vis- à- vis the
Bems–Johnson formulation is in several cases minor. On the other hand,
in the case of the PRC, use of outsourcing means that the appreciation
in the value of final goods is less than the appreciation in terms of tasks.
This approach is consistent with the Thorbecke (2011) measurement of
the integrated exchange rate measure for the PRC, which incorporates
254 Asia and global production networks
information on inputs from other East Asian countries in the production
of Chinese exports.
On the other hand, for the United States (US), the difference is neg-
ligible. Finally there are intermediate cases such as Germany, where the
trade- in- tasks and trade- in- goods measure deviates sometimes, and at
other times, does not.
7
To the extent that competitiveness is appropriately defined over the
value added component of exports and imports, this issue of measurement
is quantitatively important in the East Asian region.
3. ASSESSING THE IMPLICATIONS FOR TRADE
FLOWS
3.1 Background
One of the reasons that one would want to measure correctly exchange
rates is so that one could obtain accurate measures of competitiveness, and
hence of the responsiveness of trade flows to price changes.
The typical macroeconomist’s approach is to assume that one can esti-
mate trade elasticities in a partial equilibrium framework following the
“imperfect substitutes” methodology outlined in, for instance, Goldstein
and Khan (1985). That is, one can write out export and import equations
(assuming log- linear functional forms, where lowercase letters denote log
values of upper case):
ex
t
5 d
0
1 d
1
q
t
1 d
2
y
RoW
t
1 d
3
z
i
t
1 e
1t
(8.2)
im
t
5 b
0
1 b
1
q
t
1 b
2
y
i
t
1 b
3
z
RoW
t
1 e
2t
(8.3)
where y is income, z is a supply (shift) variable, and
b
1
, 0,
b
2
. 0,
b
3
. 0
and,
d
1
. 0,
d
2
. 0
and
d
3
. 0.
Notice that exports are the residual of production over domestic con-
sumption of exportables; similarly imports are the residual of foreign
production over foreign consumption of tradables. The difference between
this specification and the standard is the inclusion of the exportables supply
shift variable, z. In standard import and export regressions, this term is
omitted, implicitly holding the export supply curve fixed; in other words, it
constrains the relationship between domestic consumption of exportables
and production of exportables to be constant. A bout of consumption at
home that reduces the supply available for exports would induce an appar-
ent structural break in equation (8.2) if the z term is omitted. Similarly,
Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships in Asia 255
omission of the rest- of- world export supply term from the import equation
makes the estimated relationships susceptible to structural breaks.
8
The preceding estimation procedure assumes that the export and import
equations can be estimated separately. This would be most appropriate if
trade was in final goods, but clearly this is a less and less tenable propo-
sition over time. Johnson (2014) summarizes the prevailing estimates:
exports of value added are equal to about 70 percent–75 percent of gross
exports, down from about 85 percent in the 1970s–1980s.
The foregoing is a reduced form approach. As documented in Hillberry
and Hummels (2012), estimation of such reduced form equations is typi-
cally plagued by endogeneity issues (as well as measurement error). To
the extent that the relative price variable is the real exchange rate, which
incorporates the nominal exchange rate, the problem is mitigated. In the
typical econometric exercise, the real exchange rate is weakly exogenous
for trade flows.
9
In the macroeconomic literature, most attempts to deal with the issue of
vertical specialization have been ad hoc in nature. In addressing US trade
for instance, Chinn (2010) takes an indirect approach. He adduces the high
income elasticities to production fragmentation, which in turn is increas-
ing as tariffs are reduced, following Hummels et al. (2001), Yi (2003) and
Chen et al. (2005). At this juncture it is useful to recognize that services
exhibit less of this fragmentation.
10
Chinn (2010) finds that the tariff factor and the square both enter with
statistical significance, indicating that lower tariffs increase trade flows.
However, as expected, higher energy costs, as proxied by the relative price
of oil, also enter in. These findings are indirectly supportive of the view
that vertical specialization is important. So too is the fact that income
elasticities differ substantially for durables and nondurables, particularly
on the US export side.
Clearly, the results pertaining to the US, with relatively low levels of
vertical specialization in trade flows, are of some, but limited, relevance.
11
Perhaps the most important instance would be the Chinese case. In their
study of Chinese imports and exports, Cheung et al. (2010, 2012) follow
previous studies by incorporating an ad hoc correction. This involves
adding processing imports into the export equation, and exports into the
processing imports equation.
Cheung et al. (2012) consider Chinese trade flows with respect to the
rest- of- the- world using the Chinese version of equations (8.2) and (8.3).
Then q is the real value of the RMB, and
z
RoW
t
replaced with w in the import
equation. The variable w is a shift variable accounting for other factors
that might increase import demand. Because of the PRC’s role in the
global supply chain, it is assumed that a fraction of imports is intermediate
256 Asia and global production networks
goods and its demand is driven by export activity; hence w could include
exports.
12
Also, to account for the PRC’s role in the global supply chain,
they include exports as an independent variable.
13
Exports enter in with
the expected sign (and a near unit elasticity). However, the real exchange
rate retains a negative and significant coefficient.
Another way Cheung et al. (2012) address the supply chain effect is
to disaggregate the trade flows. The Chinese customs agency categorizes
exports and imports into those goods that are to be used for process-
ing purposes, and those to be used as ordinary exports or imports.
For instance, processing imports are usually for manufacturing finished
products in the country for (re- ) exporting, and these imports are usually
subjected to more favorable tariff rates. In contrast, processing exports
are exports that are used by the importing country for processing and
assembly.
For both ordinary and processing exports, the typical result is that
the value of the yuan (CNY) enters in with the right sign and statistical
significance. One large difference is the fact that ordinary exports do not
exhibit a statistically significant sensitivity to rest- of- world GDP (unless a
post- World Trade Organization trend is included). In contrast, processing
exports always exhibit income elasticities in excess of unity.
Next, they investigate whether the corresponding disaggregation yields
more promising results for imports. For ordinary imports, the income
elasticity is positive but not statistically significant, while the exchange rate
has the wrong effect. If one includes exports (which is not well motivated
for ordinary imports), the results are largely negative as well, since no
economic variable enters with significance.
For processing imports, both income and the real exchange rate
enter significantly, but the latter enters with the wrong sign. Including
exports results in properly signed coefficients for the exchange rate and
export variables. Income now enters with a negative, and significant,
sign. These results demonstrate that obtaining a correctly signed price
elasticity depends on accounting, however imperfectly, for imported
inputs.
3.2 Using the “Correct” Real Exchange Rate Measure
An ideal approach would estimate a relationship between the trade flows
and the real exchange rate, measured in consistent terms. As Johnson
(2014) observes, there are two ways to proceed. The first is to work with a
model couched in terms of value added. Another is to remain in the final
goods framework, and work backward to calculate the amount of value
added at various stages of production. In the absence of that data, one can
Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships in Asia 257
return to the ad hoc procedure used by Cheung et al. (2010). If one esti-
mates a relationship with imports as a function of income, real exchange
rate, exports and a time trend over the 2000Q1–2009Q4 period using the
conventional real exchange rate measure, one obtains an estimated (and
statistically significant) import elasticity of 1.5; that is, an appreciation
of the CNY induces a decrease in imports, even after controlling (imper-
fectly) for the export motivation. Using the Bems–Johnson real exchange
rate measure the point estimate drops to 0.6, and is no longer statistically
significant.
In the case of the PRC, the use of a value added real exchange rate
helps to eliminate a strongly perverse finding. This suggests that, contrary
to some findings (including Cheung et al., 2010, 2012), trade flows (even
mismeasured) do respond to real exchange rate changes.
Whether in fact the true underlying trade elasticities have changed
is a separate matter that cannot be determined from these data. With
exchange rate changes operating only on value added, rather than on
gross sales, it is tempting to conclude that the measured impact on trade
flows will be less. The canonical example is the case wherein imported
inputs are used to produce an exported good. In that case, an exchange
rate depreciation raises the price of export (for simplicity one- for-one),
but also increases the price of the imported input (for simplicity,
one- for- one again). Then the exchange rate depreciation only affects
the relative price of the value added. The true impact (on value added)
should be unchanged, but will appear to be smaller over time as verti-
cal specialization proceeds, holding all else constant. Thorbecke and
Smith (2010) and Thorbecke (2011) estimate the impact of exchange rate
changes on gross trade flows, taking into account intermediate trade
flows.
14
What about evaluating bilateral trade elasticities? Here, the analysis
becomes more complicated, as one cannot simply examine the bilateral
trade, activity and price variables.
15
The response of one country’s exports
to a change in the nominal exchange rate will have different effects if, for
instance, three countries are involved in production sharing. If the CNY
appreciates against a currency of a country from which it imports inter-
mediate goods to be used in exports to the US, the gross price of Chinese
goods exported to the US will likely fall even if the bilateral dollar–yuan
rate has not changed. This will then have an impact on demand for
Chinese value added, even if the original shock did not involve a change in
Chinese value added.
16
258 Asia and global production networks
4. EXCHANGE RATE PASS- THROUGH
4.1 Background
Exchange rate pass- through is the relationship between trade prices (or
consumer prices) and exchange rates. Increased vertical specialization is
likely to reduce pass- through, according to various models, although the
effect is likely to be difficult to detect in the welter of other effects.
The standard approach to explaining exchange rate pass- through (e.g.,
Hooper and Mann, 1989) appeals to imperfect competition, but without
explicit micro- foundations. Let
P*
x
be the price of exports from the foreign
(*) country, denominated in foreign currency; and
C*
be the marginal cost
of production (also in foreign currency terms).
P*
x
5 mC*
(8.4)
where
m
is the cost- markup. The US import price (
PM
i
) is obtained
by multiplying through by the exchange rate (
E,
in currency i/foreign
currency unit, e.g., Korean won/US$):
PM
i
5
E
(
PX*
)
5
E
m
C*
(8.5)
Where the markup,
µ,
depends on the degree of substitutability between US
and imported goods, and capacity utilization in the foreign country, as in:
m 5
a
P
i
C*E
b
a
(
CU*
)
b
(8.6)
where
P
i
is the average local price level in local currency of the good in
question. Solving, and taking logs yields:
pm
i
5
(
1
2 a
)
e
1 a
p
i
1
(
1
2 a
)
c*
1 b
cu*
(8.7)
Note that
0pm
i
/0e ;
(
1
2 a
)
;
exchange rate pass- through (where
0
denotes partial derivative).
Further observe that the expression has implications for foreign firms’
(log) markup:
pm
$
2
e
2
c*
5 a
(
p
$
2
e
2
c*
)
1 b
cu*
(8.8)
so that the log markup or profit margin on sales to the US is a function
of gap between the US price and foreign cost. When
a
is near unity (or
Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships in Asia 259
pass- through is low) then a rise in e causes a decline in foreign profit
margins.
17
Note three limitations. First, the exposition above relies upon all
value added originating in a given country. Second, most of the studies
of exchange rate pass- through have focused on industrialized countries.
Third, these studies focused on macroeconomic determinants (most
importantly, inflation). Within this literature, the evidence in the years
before the financial crisis documented a decline in industrial country
exchange rate pass- through. These studies included a comprehensive
analysis by the Federal Reserve of US import prices (Marazzi et al., 2005),
and industrial countries generally (Sekine, 2006). Bailliu and Fujii (2004)
attribute the drop to the decline in trend inflation.
The development of open economy, New Keynesian models has focused
attention on the relationship between exchange rate pass- through and
whether pricing is undertaken in producer currency or local currency.
Local currency pricing is consistent with incomplete pass- through into
import prices. The fact that export price pass- through is also less than
complete suggests to Choudhri and Hakura (2012) that there is a mixture
of producer currency and local currency pricing occurring for both exports
and imports.
There is, of course, an endogeneity issue. Gopinath et al. (2010) show
that the selection of pricing currency depends upon the desired level of
exchange rate pass- through. This is the topic of some recent analyses,
which have focused on the microeconomic aspects of exchange rate
pass- through. In particular, increasing vertical specialization should on
average reduce exchange rate pass- through. That’s because, with imported
inputs, an exchange rate change will change marginal costs, as illustrated
in the example in the previous section. Hellerstein and Villas- Boas (2010)
and Neiman (2010) document the fact that exchange rate pass- through
varies inversely with the intensity of vertical specialization for US imports.
Of the $16 trillion of gross world trade in 2010, roughly $6.3 trillion is
intra- firm in nature, so presumably this phenomenon extends to other
currencies and trade flows (UNCTAD, 2013).
4.2 Application to East Asia
Ghosh and Rajan (2007) survey the literature on exchange rate
pass- through in Asia, and find a wide dispersion of estimates, ranging
from relatively high for developing Asian economies such as Thailand and
Indonesia, and substantially lower for industrial Japan. The dispersion
of estimates is not unexpected given the wide diversity of exchange rate
regimes (and relatedly, inflation outcomes).
260 Asia and global production networks
Choudhri and Hakura (2012) provide some recent estimates of import
and export exchange rate pass- through, obtained using vector autore-
gressions (VARs) over the 1979–2010 period. Estimates for selected East
Asian economies are presented in Figures 8.2a–b, for import and export
pass- through, respectively.
18
While the estimates for Hong Kong, China
and Singapore indicate very low import pass- through coefficients, in accord
with the predictions, those for Thailand and Singapore exceed the average
for emerging market economies. This suggests that, for now at least, mac-
roeconomic factors (inflation, exchange rate regime) trump micro factors.
Amiti et al. (2012) provide a microeconomic- based explanation for
exchange rate pass- through to be particularly muted. They note that large
exporters are often large importers. In such instances, in the presence
of strategic complementarities and high market shares, exchange rate
pass- through will tend to be small. To the extent that this characteriza-
tion applies to East Asian firms, then one would expect the relatively low
exchange rate pass- through coefficients to make sense, holding all else
constant. However, with the exceptions of both Hong Kong, China and
Singapore, pass- through coefficients appear fairly high, which suggests
that other macroeconomic factors that have been determined to be impor-
tant (inflation, exchange rate regime) trump micro factors. Nonetheless,
to the extent that the process of vertical specialization continues, then
pass- through coefficients should decline over time.
19
5. SYNCHRONIZATION OF BUSINESS CYCLES
5.1 Business Cycles
During the Great Recession, output in East Asia was hit particularly hard
as trade flows dropped precipitously. Several hypotheses were put forward
for why trade fell so much more than output, including the drying up of
trade financing, a composition effect (hard hit durables are much more
procyclical than nondurables), and the importance of vertical specializa-
tion.
20
On this point there is no complete agreement, but it at least seems
to be a plausible argument that high degrees of vertical specialization will
induce greater business cycle comovement.
Kose and Yi (2001) are an early expositor of the view that greater
vertical specialization leads to greater business cycle synchronization.
More recently Burstein et al. (2008) have argued that vertical spe-
cialization is an important determinant of synchronization. Arkolakis
and Ramanarayanan (2009) show that GDP growth will become more
synchronized if imperfect competition prevails.
Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships in Asia 261
–0.4
–0.2
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
SIN
MEX
HKG
ZAF
POL
JOR
PAK
COL
HUN
PER
BRA
CHL
KOR
THA
ARG
TUR
% change in import price for a one percentage point
change in the exchange rate
(a) Import pass-through
Sample average
–0.8
–0.4
0.0
0.4
0.8
1.2
1.6
SIN
MEX
JOR
HKG
ZAF
PAK
POL
CHL
HUN
THA
KOR
COL
ARG
TUR
BRA
PER
% change in export price for a one percentage point
change in the exchange rate
(b) Export pass-through
Sample average
Note: ARG = Argentina, BRA = Brazil; CHL = Chile; COL = Colombia; HKG =
Hong Kong, China; HUN = Hungary; JOR = Jordan; KOR = Republic of Korea; MEX
= Mexico; PAK = Pakistan; PER = Peru; POL = Poland; SIN = Singapore; THA =
Thailand; TUR = Turkey; ZAF = South Africa.
Source: Choudhri and Hakura (2012).
Figure 8.2 One quarter exchange rate pass- through for (a) emerging
market imports; (b) emerging market exports
262 Asia and global production networks
Carare and Mody (2012) have recently undertaken an empirical
analysis of this hypothesis. In it, they relate volatility spillovers and the
extentof vertical specialization, for a sample of 18 countries, over the
1977–2007 period. First, they estimate a factor structural VAR (Stock
and Watson, 2005). The FSVAR allows for a decomposition of the
variance of the shocks into domestic shocks and common international
shocks that affect all countries in the same quarter. Spillovers have a spe-
cific interpretation –country- specific shocks that affect other countries
after one quarter.
The degree of vertical specialization is taken from the OECD’s Measuring
Globalization publication, and is the share of imported inputs in exports.
They document a clear positive association between the change in growth
spillovers and the change in vertical specialization over the 1995–2000
period; when the change in vertical specialization between 1995 and 2000
rises by 1 percent, the change in the share of spillovers in volatility rises by
0.92 units. The bivariate relationship between vertical specialization and
spillovers is stronger than that between trade intensity and spillovers (the
partial effect is not discernable due to multicollinearity).
One drawback of this approach is that the link is between vertical spe-
cialization in the form of imports used for overall exports, and overall
sensitivity to spillovers from the rest of the world. That is, there is no direct
relationship between bilateral vertical specialization and the spillover
from a particular trading partner.
21
Ng (2010) examines a sample of 30 OECD countries over the 1970–2004
period, but investigates the relationship between bilateral correlation
and bilateral trade linkages. He regresses bilateral GDP correlation
coefficients, derived from HP- filtered GDP, on two measures of verti-
cal specialization the imported input share of gross output (weighted
using either exports or output). Ng controls for intra- industry trade,
trade intensity, similarity in industrial structure, and financial integration
(all bilateral). While the standard variables, such as trade intensity and
intra- industry trade, matter, the latter loses significance when the vertical
specialization measures are included; in addition, trade intensity takes on
the wrong sign.
Di Giovanni and Levchenko (2012) examine a larger, more detailed
dataset that encompasses 55 countries and 28 manufacturing sectors, over
the 1970–1999 period. They use a decomposition of the correlation of
output growth correlation into correlations between sector growth cor-
relations. They find that for this sample, vertical linkages account for 32
percent of the impact of bilateral trade on aggregate comovement of GDP
growth, a share that is consistent with previous studies such as Burstein et
al. (2008).
Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships in Asia 263
In interpreting these results in the context of East Asia, several caveats
are necessary. Ng’s sample only includes four East Asian countries: Japan,
the Republic of Korea, the PRC, and Taipei,China – plus Indonesia. The
di Giovanni and Levchenko study added Hong Kong, China in East Asia,
and they also include Malaysia and Singapore; however they omit the
PRC. Perhaps more importantly, the vertical integration statistics apply
to either before 2000, or up to 2000. In other words, most of the relation-
ship between vertical specialization and business cycle correlation that is
documented pertains to the extent of linkages in place over a decade ago.
This suggests that it might be useful to examine more recent trends
in business cycle dynamics, under the presumption that the links have
become stronger over time.
5.2 Recent Trends in East Asian Business Cycle Dynamics
In this section, I document the changes in business cycle dynamics over the
past thirty years. In the absence of recent data on the extent of bilateral
vertical specialization for all the relevant countries in the region, I limit
myself to documenting the business cycle dynamics.
To this end, I examine the time series properties of real GDP in the
region, utilizing quarterly data over the 1980Q1–2012Q4 period. The
use of quarterly data allows for a more detailed view of business cycle
dynamics. I focus on the four newly industrialized countries (NICs), of
Hong Kong, China, the Republic of Korea, Singapore and Taipei,China;
and the emerging Asian economies of the PRC, Indonesia, Malaysia,
Philippines and Thailand. I check the correlations with Japan, the US,
and, for comparison’s sake, Mexico.
In order to isolate the business cycle components, I employ several sta-
tistical techniques: a Hodrick–Prescott (HP) filter, quadratic detrending
and log- differencing.
22
The resulting bilateral correlations of HP- filtered
deviations of log GDP are then calculated for the 1990Q1–1997Q4
and 1999Q1–2012Q4 periods. The change in the correlation coefficients
between the two sub periods is reported in Table 8.1.
The results indicate that correlation coefficients among the East Asian
countries rise, sometimes significantly. In particular, the PRC’s correla-
tion rises with most of the East Asian countries rise, and substantially so
with Singapore and Japan the latter is important to the extent that it
matches the narrative of increasing linkages between the two economies.
23
Note the exception is Indonesia, but in this case the result is probably an
artifact of the sharp and permanent drop in the trend in Indonesian GDP
in 1997. This event distorts the estimated business cycle obtained using
the HP filter (as well as linear detrending). In fact, once one takes out the
264
Table 8.1 Change in business cycle correlations, using Hodrick–Prescott detrending
Correlation PRC JPN KOR TAP HKG INO MAL PHI SIN THA USA MEX
PRC 0.000
JPN 0.821 0.000
KOR 0.088 0.262 0.000
TAP 0.409 0.734 0.046 0.000
HKG −0.003 0.919 0.048 0.131 0.000
INO −0.250 0.086 −0.263 −0.418 −0.131 0.000
MAL 0.457 0.393 0.136 0.456 0.474 −0.251 0.000
PHI 0.838 0.287 −0.126 0.112 0.118 −0.035 0.002 0.000
SIN 0.510 0.613 0.074 0.721 0.455 −0.421 −0.042 −0.047 0.000
THA 0.143 0.265 −0.165 0.268 0.298 −0.051 −0.077 −0.069 −0.157 0.000
USA 0.123 0.564 0.288 0.490 0.533 −0.313 0.526 0.650 0.724 0.227 0.000
MEX 0.779 0.443 0.807 0.726 0.767 0.054 0.515 0.545 0.777 0.366 0.711 0.000
Notes:
PRC 5 People’s Republic of China; HKG 5 Hong Kong, China; INO 5 Indonesia; JPN 5 Japan; KOR 5 Republic of Korea; MEX 5 Mexico;
MAL 5 Malaysia; PHI 5 Philippines; SIN 5 Singapore; TAP 5 Taipei,China; THA 5 Thailand; USA 5 United States.
Dark- shaded cell values are greater than 0.30, light- shaded cell values are smaller than −0.15.
Source: Author’s calculations.
Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships in Asia 265
Indonesian entries, the dominant impression one obtains is that business
cycle correlations have risen, often substantially.
24, 25
The HP filter is but one way of identifying business cycles; it tends to
identify smaller cyclical deviations than those obtained using quadratic
detrending. If one uses quadratic detrending, once again one obtains
broadly similar results (as long as one ignores the Indonesian results). The
intra- East Asia correlations typically rise in the more recent period. This
characterization holds regardless of whether the sample ends in 2006 or
2012.
Using non- overlapping four quarter growth rates as a measure of busi-
ness cycles, one obtains results similar to those obtained using the HP filter
to define business cycles. Business cycle correlations have tended to rise,
as summarized in Table 8.2. The exceptions involve Indonesia, or involve
very modest declines. If the later subsample is extended to 2012, then the
pattern is more pronounced.
It is notable that the PRC’s correlation rises in a noticeable fashion
with Japan and Republic of Korea, using this definition of the business
cycle. So too do correlations between Japan and Taipei,China, as well as
Singapore and Taipei,China.
Typically, researchers have examined the static correlations as a way
of explaining the strength of economic interactions. An alternative is
to use an econometric methodology that allows for dynamics. I use a
simple non- structural VAR to characterize the dynamics relating key
variables to individual economies. Ideally, one would want to model all
the economies simultaneously; however, there are not enough observa-
tions to undertake such an analysis using this approach. Hence, I use a
more ad hoc approach, examining each East Asian country’s dynamics
separately.
26
In each case I estimate a two lag VAR including the US, Japan, the
PRC and each respective East Asian country, using the indicated ordering.
This means that I assume that all economic activity variables – in this case
the HP filter defined output gaps are endogenous, but the US business
cycle is more exogenous than Japan’s, Japan’s is more exogenous than the
PRC’s, and the PRC’s is more exogenous than the cycle of the individual
small East Asian economy.
27
In order to conserve space, I present the detailed results for two of the
larger economies of interest (Republic of Korea and Taipei,China), and
discuss the other economies’ results in general terms. Republic of Korea
and Taipei,China are two countries that account for large shares of global
imports used for exports.
28
The resulting impulse response functions
(IRFs) show the response of a variable to a one standard deviation shock
to a particular variable. Plus/minus one standard error bands are included
266
Table 8.2 Change in business cycle correlations, using non- overlapping four- quarter growth rates
Correlation PRC JPN KOR TAP HKG INO MAL PHI SIN THA USA MEX
PRC 0.000
JPN 0.514 0.000
KOR 0.465 −0.103 0.000
TAP 0.201 0.338 0.264 0.000
HKG 0.721 0.222 −0.431 0.356 0.000
INO −0.046 0.579 −0.036 −0.462 0.289 0.000
MAL 0.260 −0.074 0.347 0.276 0.163 −0.478 0.000
PHI 0.129 −0.094 −0.279 0.082 0.019 0.480 −0.567 0.000
SIN 0.215 0.060 −0.071 1.073 0.542 −0.138 0.302 0.139 0.000
THA 0.199 −0.003 −0.525 0.318 0.149 −0.121 −0.378 0.048 0.229 0.000
USA −0.531 −0.019 0.324 0.775 0.426 −0.095 0.091 0.132 −0.007 0.011 0.000
MEX −0.455 0.433 0.444 −0.008 0.177 −0.729 −0.281 −0.271 0.153 −0.008 0.008 0.000
Notes:
PRC 5 People’s Republic of China; HKG 5 Hong Kong, China; INO 5 Indonesia; JPN 5 Japan; KOR 5 Republic of Korea; MEX 5 Mexico;
MAL 5 Malaysia; PHI 5 Philippines; SIN 5 Singapore; TAP 5 Taipei,China; THA 5 Thailand; USA 5 United States.
Dark- shaded cell values are greater than 0.30, light- shaded cell values are smaller than −0.15.
Source: Author’s calculations.
Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships in Asia 267
to illustrate the degree of statistical precision or lack of in each set of
estimates.
In Figure 8.3a, the graph in the first row of the first column denotes
the response of the US GDP output gap to a shock to the US output
gap, over time, during the 1981Q1–1997Q4 period. The hump shaped
pattern indicates that after an initial positive impact, the response
increases before decaying toward zero. The impulse response is sta-
tistically significant. The second figure in the first column shows the
response of the Japanese output gap to the US output gap shock. As in
the third and fourth figures (the Chinese and Korean output gaps), the
output gap does not respond with statistical significance to US output
shocks.
The second column shows the impulse response functions for shocks to
the Japanese output gap, while the third and fourth show the correspond-
ing functions for Chinese and Korean output gaps. One general charac-
teristic of these figures is that only the impulse response functions in the
diagonal elements display much statistical significance.
These results can be interpreted as indicating that whatever macroeco-
nomic business cycle links there are between the US, Japan, the PRC and
the Republic of Korea they are not typically easy to detect in the pre- 1997
sample.
For the 1999Q1–2007Q4 period (Figure 8.3b), the IRFs provide a
substantially different story. The Japanese output gap responds to the
US output gap, as does the Korean. Now, Japanese and Korean output
gaps respond to the Chinese output gap (borderline significance). In other
words, the PRC’s business cycle has a noticeable impact on two other
economies with which the vertical specialization links are particularly
strong.
Given the strongly synchronized downturn in trade flows and eco-
nomic activity in 2008–2009, attributed by some to increasing vertical
specialization, my prior was that extending the sample to incorporate the
global recession would have strengthened these results. Surprisingly, the
aforementioned effects largely disappear when the sample is extended up
to 2012Q4 (results not shown). One interpretation of this phenomenon is
that the effect of the vertical specialization linkages have been obscured
by the divergence in macro policies, with Chinese GDP delinking from
the rest of the global supply chain. The alternative view would allow that
the measurement of the business cycle (i.e., output gap) has become much
more problematic at the end of the sample period.
Next I consider Taipei,China. In the early period (Figure 8.4a), there
are rarely any significant effects detected most economies’ output gaps
appear to be affected by their own lagged output gaps. In this respect, the
268
–0.004
0.000
0.004
0.008
0.012
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVUS to YDEVUS
–0.004
0.000
0.004
0.008
0.012
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVUS to YDEVJP
–0.004
0.000
0.004
0.008
0.012
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVUS to YDEVCH2
–0.004
0.000
0.004
0.008
0.012
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVUS to YDEVKO
–0.004
0.000
0.004
0.008
0.012
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVJP to YDEVUS
–0.004
0.000
0.004
0.008
0.012
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVJP to YDEVJP
–0.004
0.000
0.004
0.008
0.012
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVJP to YDEVCH2
–0.004
0.000
0.004
0.008
0.012
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVJP to YDEVKO
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVCH2 to YDEVUS
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVCH2 to YDEVJP
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVCH2 to YDEVCH2
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVCH2 to YDEVKO
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVKO to YDEVUS
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVKO to YDEVJP
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVKO to YDEVCH2
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVKO to YDEVKO
Response to Chole sky One S.D. Innovations ± 2S.E.
Note: VAR = vector autoregression.
Source: Author’s calculations.
Figure 8.3a Impulse response functions for Republic of Korea VAR, 1981Q1–1997Q4
269
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.01
0.00
0.01
0.02
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.01
0.00
0.01
0.02
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.01
0.00
0.01
0.02
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.01
0.00
0.01
0.02
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVUS to YDEVUS Response of YDEVUS to YDEVJP Response of YDEVUS to YDEVCH2 Response of YDEVUS to YDEVKO
Response of YDEVJP to YDEVUS Response of YDEVJP to YDEVJP Response of YDEVJP to YDEVCH2 Response of YDEVJP to YDEVKO
Response of YDEVCH2 to YDEVUS Response of YDEVCH2 to YDEVJP Response of YDEVCH2 to YDEVCH2 Response of YDEVCH2 to YDEVKO
Response of YDEVKO to YDEVUS Response of YDEVKO to YDEVJP Response of YDEVKO to YDEVCH2 Response of YDEVKO to YDEVKO
Response to Chole sky One S.D. Innovations ± 2S.E.
Note: VAR = vector autoregression.
Source: Author’s calculations.
Figure 8.3b Impulse response functions for Republic of Korea VAR, 1999Q1–2007Q4
270
–0.004
0.000
0.004
0.008
0.012
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.004
0.000
0.004
0.008
0.012
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.004
0.000
0.004
0.008
0.012
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.004
0.000
0.004
0.008
0.012
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.004
0.000
0.004
0.008
0.012
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.004
0.000
0.004
0.008
0.012
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.004
0.000
0.004
0.008
0.012
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.004
0.000
0.004
0.008
0.012
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.010
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response to Chole sky One S.D. Innovations ± 2S.E.
Response of YDEVUS to YDEVUS Response of YDEVUS to YDEVJP Response of YDEVUS to YDEVCH2 Response of YDEVUS to YDEVKO
Response of YDEVJP to YDEVUS Response of YDEVJP to YDEVJP Response of YDEVJP to YDEVCH2 Response of YDEVJP to YDEVKO
Response of YDEVCH2 to YDEVUS Response of YDEVCH2 to YDEVJP Response of YDEVCH2 to YDEVCH2 Response of YDEVCH2 to YDEVKO
Response of YDEVKO to YDEVUS Response of YDEVKO to YDEVJP Response of YDEVKO to YDEVCH2 Response of YDEVKO to YDEVKO
Note: VAR = vector autoregression.
Source: Author’s calculations.
Figure 8.4a Impulse response functions for Taipei,China VAR, 1981Q1–1997Q4
271
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.005
0.000
0.005
0.010
0.015
0.020
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.01
0.00
0.01
0.02
0.03
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.01
0.00
0.01
0.02
0.03
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.01
0.00
0.01
0.02
0.03
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–0.01
0.00
0.01
0.02
0.03
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Response of YDEVUS to YDEVUS Response of YDEVUS to YDEVJP Response of YDEVUS to YDEVCH2 Response of YDEVUS to YDEVKO
Response of YDEVJP to YDEVUS Response of YDEVJP to YDEVJP Response of YDEVJP to YDEVCH2 Response of YDEVJP to YDEVKO
Response of YDEVCH2 to YDEVUS Response of YDEVCH2 to YDEVJP Response of YDEVCH2 to YDEVCH2 Response of YDEVCH2 to YDEVKO
Response of YDEVKO to YDEVUS Response of YDEVKO to YDEVJP Response of YDEVKO to YDEVCH2 Response of YDEVKO to YDEVKO
Response to Chole sky One S.D. Innovations ± 2S.E.
Note: VAR = vector autoregression.
Source: Author’s calculations.
Figure 8.4b Impulse response functions for Taipei,China VAR, 1999Q1–2007Q4
272 Asia and global production networks
findings are similar to those obtained for Republic of Korea. In the more
recent 1999Q1–2007Q4 period, both Japanese and Taipei,China output
gaps respond to the US output gap shock.
In contrast to the results for the earlier period, in the latter period
(Figure8.4b), Taipei,China output responds positively to Chinese output,
and with statistical significance at the 3–4 quarter horizon. The US
appears to respond to the PRC, even though it is treated as more exog-
enous than the PRC; however the results are borderline significant.
29
Once
again, these results largely disappear once one extends the latter sample to
2012Q4.
A similar pattern of contrasting results holds for Singapore, Thailand
and Malaysia. In the early period, most output gaps are largely explained
by lagged own- economy output gaps. In the latter period, the output gaps
respond to the PRC’s output gap, with borderline statistical significance
(after accounting for US and Japan effects). The enhanced sensitivity of
these countries’ business cycles to the PRC’s is also detected in alternative
global models (Bussiere et al., 2012).
On the other hand, Indonesia and the Philippines do not exhibit any
substantial change in IRFs, particularly of own output gap to the Chinese
output gap, moving from the early period to the later. It is conceivable
that other factors obscure the relationship. For instance, Indonesia’s
intermediate exports to PRC are substantial, but involve mostly energy
exports. The Philippines experienced numerous political shocks during the
1980s and 1990s.
In sum, during this period when arguably global supply chains have
become increasingly important, business cycle correlations have risen,
and risen in a fashion mostly consistent with the pattern of linkages.
Moreover, using an HP- filtered measure of the business cycle, it appears
that in the period up to the onset of the global financial crisis, the PRC’s
role in determining business cycles in East Asia grew.
30
However, that
evidence is less visible in the period spanning the global recession and the
subsequent recovery.
6. EXCHANGE RATE STABILIZATION AND THE
CHINESE DOMINANCE THESIS
6.1 Previous Assessments
As vertical integration proceeds, it is likely that government reaction
functions in particular those of central banks will evolve. One con-
jecture is that to the extent that exchange rate movements complicate
Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships in Asia 273
decision making within the global supply chain, one would anticipate that
policymakers experience pressure to stabilize exchange rates.
31
On the other hand, it is unclear whether policymakers will want to stifle
one key avenue of macroeconomic adjustment. For instance, Bems (2012)
shows that increasing vertical specialization does not have unambiguous
effects on the amount of exchange rate adjustment necessary to effect a
given change in trade inflows. That’s because accounting for intermediates
means that countries are more closed than conventionally understood;
but accounting for domestic intermediates means that economies are
more open as services (which are typically thought of as untraded) are
incorporated in exports.
Nonetheless, the conventional wisdom holds that policymakers will
welcome more stable exchange rates when there is much production
sharing. If they are to stabilize against each other, which currency will they
stabilize against? There are several candidates –historically, the US dollar
is the obvious candidate, due to its use as a financing and invoicing cur-
rency. But with the PRC’s outsize role in trade transactions (and supply
chains), it seems reasonable to ask whether the regional central banks
will coordinate to an ever greater extent on the Chinese yuan, much as
European countries anchored their currencies to the Deutsche mark some
thirty years ago.
This hypothesis gains even more plausibility as Chinese authorities
embark on a project to internationalize the renminbi (RMB). The meas-
ures include allowing for RMB swaps, and encouraging invoicing in
CNY.
32
Figures 8.5 and 8.6 show the evolution of the regional currencies, includ-
ing the Chinese yuan (CNY), expressed in terms of IMF Special Drawing
Rights (SDRs), in the wake of the reform of the Chinese exchange rate
regime in July 2005, and after the financial crisis starting in July 2010.
Notice that the currencies of the region appear to follow the Chinese yuan,
suggesting that central banks in the region pay close attention to Chinese
currency interventions.
One way of making this assessment is to examine how daily currency
movements are related to movements in the major currencies – the United
States dollar (USD), the euro (EUR), the Japanese yen (JPY) and the
CNY (all expressed against the SDR). The regression coefficients are
then interpretable as the weight ascribed to each currency in the currency
basket targeted by the central bank.
D
e
i
SDR
t
5 a
0
1 a
1
D
e
USD
SDR
t
1 a
2
D
e
CNY
SDR
t
1 a
3
D
e
EUR
SDR
t
1 b
4
De
JPY/SDR
t
1 a
5
De
GBP/SDR
t
1 u
t
(8.9)
274 Asia and global production networks
Where
e
i/SDR
is the number of currency units per SDR, in logs, the i super-
script denotes the specific East Asian currency of interest, and
D
is the first
difference operator.
For instance, if
a
1
5 1
for i 5 KRW (Korean won), then the interpreta-
tion would be that the Bank of Korea targeted the US dollar.
Huang et al. (2013) examine daily data from January 1999 to July 2005,
and July 2005 to June 2013, for the Hong Kong dollar (HKD), Indian
rupee (INR), Indonesian rupiah (IDR), Korean won (KRW), Malaysian
ringgit (MYR), Singapore dollar (SGD), and Thai baht (THB), using
equation (8.8). In all cases, the weight ascribed to the USD declines going
from the first sample to the second, save the SGD and THB. Moreover,
the estimated weight on the CNY becomes statistically significant. Those
results confirm that at high frequencies (daily), the central banks have paid
much more attention to movements in the CNY than they did before July
2005.
Fratzscher and Mehl (2011) use a variant of this approach. In their
study, they assess the tripolar thesis the idea that the USD, EUR and
CNY are becoming the anchors for currency management using daily
–0.20
–0.15
–0.10
–0.05
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
Jun-05
Aug-05
Oct-05
Dec-05
Feb-06
Apr-06
Jun-06
Aug-06
Oct-06
Dec-06
Feb-07
Apr-07
Jun-07
Aug-07
Oct-07
Dec-07
Feb-08
Apr-08
Jun-08
Aug-08
Index
PRC Malaysia Singapore
Taipei,China Thailand Indonesia
Note: PRC = People’s Republic of China.
Source: Author’s calculations.
Figure 8.5 Log exchange rates against special drawing rights, 2005M06 = 0
Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships in Asia 275
data on nearly fifty exchange rates over the 1996 to 2011 period. They
undertake two types of analyses; the first is an unconditional factor
analysis, and the second, an extension of the first, augmented with policy
announcements.
In the unconditional analysis, the authors regress changes in the
exchange rates against the SDR on a US, euro area and regional factor,
and other conditioning variables. The US factor (the US dollar–SDR
exchange rate) is taken as exogenous, the euro factor is the residual from
the regression of the euro exchange rate on the dollar rate, and the regional
factor is a GDP- weighted average of the regional currencies (excluding the
CNY), orthogonalized by taking the residuals from a regression on the
dollar and euro rates.
33
Fratzscher and Mehl find that the regional factor is increasing in impor-
tance over time. The US factor is dominant both pre- and post- reform
(July 2005). The results for emerging Asia are reported in Figure 8.7. For
the currencies of that region, the coefficient on the US factor is 0.74 and
0.60, respectively. This means that after July 2005, a depreciation of 10
percent in the US dollar induces a depreciation of 6 percent in a currency.
The Asian regional factor coefficient increases from 0.19 to 0.25.
–0.15
–0.10
–0.05
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
Jun-10
Aug-10
Oct-10
Dec-10
Feb-11
Apr-11
Jun-11
Aug-11
Oct-11
Dec-11
Feb-12
Apr-12
Jun-12
Aug-12
Oct-12
Dec-12
Feb-13
Apr-13
Index
PRC Malaysia Singapore
Taipei,China Thailand Indonesia
Note: PRC = People’s Republic of China.
Source: Author’s calculations.
Figure 8.6 Log exchange rates against special drawing rights, 2010M06 = 0
276 Asia and global production networks
The interesting question is whether the CNY drives the regional factor.
Using Granger causality tests, the authors find that pre- 2005, one typically
cannot reject the hypothesis that the CNY does not Granger- cause the
regional factor; post- 2005, one rejects the null. In addition, replacing the
regional factor with the CNY rate yields similar results.
Fratzscher and Mehl then extend the analysis to include dummy
variables for Chinese statements regarding increased flexibility or reserve
diversification. The general pattern of factor loading estimates remains
intact, while Chinese official announcements have a greater impact in the
latter period.
34
6.2 Longer Term Trends and Exchange Rate Adjustment
The preceding section outlined approaches that examined the behavior of
exchange rates at high (daily) frequency. However, for macroeconomic
interactions, one needs to know how the exchange rates behave over the
longer term – monthly and quarterly. Not only are changes of interest, so
too are levels.
In this section I attempt to redress this deficiency by examining how
East Asian exchange rates have been managed in response to major
currencies.
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
Before 2005 After 2005
Factor value
US factor
Euro factor
Regional factor
Source: Fratzscher and Mehl (2011), Table 6.
Figure 8.7 Determinants of East Asian currency movements, 1997–2011
Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships in Asia 277
De
i
SDR
t
5 b
0
1b
1
e
i
SDR
t2 1
1 b
2
e
USD
SDR
t2 1
1 b
3
e
CNY
SDR
t2 1
1 b
4
e
JPY
SDR
t2 1
1 b
5
F
t2 1
1 b
6
De
i
SDR
t2 1
1 b
7
De
USD
SDR
t2 1
1
b
8
De
CNY/SDR
t2 1
1
b
9
De
JPY/SDR
t2 1
1
b
10
DF
t
1
u
t
(8.10)
where F is the financial stress index for the US.
This specification is an error correction model, which allows for a long
run cointegrating relationship between the log levels of the six exchange
rates against the SDR. The long run cointegrating relationship is given
by the expression
2b
k
/b
1
,
while
b
1
is an estimate of the rate of reversion
to long run equilibrium. Note the inclusion of the contemporaneous first
difference of the financial stress index is consistent with weak exogeneity
of US financial stress.
35
I estimate the specification in equation (8.10) over two samples,
1999M01 to 2005M06, and 2005M07 to 2013M04, and examine the evolu-
tion of weights attached to the USD and the CNY going between the two
subsamples.
36
This break matches with the reform in the Chinese exchange
rate regime. I do not include the HK$ (since at this frequency it is collinear
with the USD), but add in the currency for Taipei,China (NT$).
Note that the estimation of the error correction specifications is
appropriate if the series are cointegrated. While the series do not appear
to be cointegrated over the entire 1999M01–2013M04 period, they do
appear cointegrated over the subsamples, thus validating the estimation
procedure implemented.
Table 8.3 reports the results of estimating equation (8.10); the top half
presents results pertaining to the early subsample, before the reform of
the Chinese exchange rate regime. The bottom half applies to the later
subsample.
Because the CNY is effectively pegged to the USD during the early
period, it is not possible to identify a separate CNY effect. Hence, the
only currencies included in the estimation in the early period are the USD
and JPY. Nonetheless, it is still surprisingly difficult to identify a long run
relationship between the currency values in the early sub- period. By and
large the proportion of variation explained is nil, while there is some slight
evidence of mean reversion, as evidenced by negative estimated
b
1
coef-
ficients. Because the fit is so poor, there is only weak evidence of a long
run relationship between the various currencies and the USD and JPY
(denoted by the US(LR) and JP(LR) entries).
In the bottom half of Table 8.3, the results suggest a much better fit. In
all cases, there is evidence of reversion to long run relationships between
278 Asia and global production networks
the individual currencies and the CNY, USD and JPY. For instance, the
estimated
b
1
ranges between 0.16 and 0.21. This means the half- life of a
deviation of the exchange rate from the long run relationship ranges from
3 to 4 months, ignoring short run dynamics.
For the cases where the coefficients are statistically significant, the
CNY has taken on a more important role. For the SGD, the MYR and
Table 8.3 Coefficients from error correction model
KRW SGD NTD IDR MYR THB
Period: 1999M01–2005M06
B
1
−0.117† −0.110 0.141† −0.105† −9.593 −0.054
(0.075) (0.095) (0.075) (0.069) (9.703) (0.064)
US −0.055 0.036 −0.173** 0.129† 9.557 0.006
(0.039) (0.052) (0.069) (0.082) (9.705) (0.035)
JP 0.045 0.040 −0.038 −0.112 0.052** −0.005
(0.073) (0.031) (0.064) (0.132) (0.024) (0.065)
Adj R
2
0.03 0.02 0.14 0.02 0.01 −0.05
US(LR) −0.47 na na 1.23 na na
JP(LR) 0.38 na na −1.07 na na
Period: 2005M07–2013M04
B
1
−0.160*** −0.167** −0.156** −0.212*** −0.204** −0.151***
(0.063) (0.074) (0.064) (0.064) (0.081) (0.053)
CN −0.019 0.176* 0.029 −0.099 0.144* 0.171**
(0.086) (0.091) (0.048) (0.099) (0.082) (0.083)
US 0.247** −0.092** 0.016 −0.018 −0.025 −0.046
(0.108) (0.045) (0.058) (0.109) (0.043) (0.057)
JP −0.051 −0.005 0.032† 0.025 −0.009 −0.023
(0.051) (0.029) (0.024) (0.046) (0.027) (0.029)
Adj R
2
0.55 0.15 0.3 0.32 0.07 0.04
CN(LR) −1.19 1.05 0.19 −0.47 0.71 1.13
US(LR) 1.54 −0.55 0.10 −0.08 0.12 −0.30
JP(LR) −0.32 0.03 0.21 −0.12 −0.04 −0.15
Notes:
IDR 5 Indonesian rupiah; KRW 5 Korean won; MYR 5 Malaysian ringgit; NTD 5 New
Taiwan dollars; SGD 5 Singapore dollar; THB 5 Thai baht.
na 5not available; significant at † 20%; * 10%; ** 5%; *** 1%.
Coefficient estimates from equation (8.9). B
1
is coefficient on lagged level of dependent
variable. CN, US, JP are coefficients on respective currency values. CN(LR), US(LR), and
JP(LR) are implied long run elasticities. Bold face entries indicate that both the long run
and reversion coefficient used to calculate the long run elasticities are statistically significant
at the 10% marginal significance level.
Source: Author’s calculations.
Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships in Asia 279
the THB, the Chinese currency is the dominant factor, as measured by
the long run coefficient. In the case of the NTD, no currency seems to
have an important impact; however, a slight variation in the specification
(assuming US financial stress is not weakly exogenous with respect to the
Taipei,China currency) leads to a significant role for the Chinese currency.
One interesting counterexample is the KRW; in this case, the USD
remains the most important factor. This is somewhat surprising, given the
strong economic links to Japan and the PRC. However, this outcome is
consistent with results for daily data given in Huang et al. (2013).
Bringing together the results from other studies and the preceding
empirical exercise, it appears fairly clear that more currencies are becom-
ing anchored to the CNY, particularly since the reform of the Chinese
exchange rate regime in 2005. Why this phenomenon is occurring cannot
be determined within the context of these empirical studies, but one of the
reasons is likely because in the context of an integrated supply chain, large
exchange rate movements are unwelcome. With a lot of production costs
located in the PRC, it makes sense that the Chinese currency would serve
as one of the nominal anchors for the region’s currencies.
7. CONCLUSION
The increasing importance of global supply chains in East Asia has
sparked substantial research tracing out the microeconomic and trade
implications. The macroeconomics profession has been a relative late-
comer to examining the implications for the transmission of price and
output effects. Moreover, the ramifications for how policy reaction func-
tions will evolve in response to the changing nature of trade linkages have
only been touched upon. This survey suggests several conclusions.
First, the conventional means of measuring international competitive-
ness are going to be less and less adequate, as production becomes more
fragmented. Relatedly, it will become less and less tenable to estimate
the traditional partial equilibrium trade equations in order to obtain
macro- level trade elasticities, as mis- measurement of trade flows becomes
more pronounced, and appropriate deflators for real exchange rates
diverge further from the typically used deflators.
Second, the increasing role of vertical specialization will likely drive
down exchange rate pass- through. This is true even if the increase is
due to increasing arms- length transactions. However, to the extent that
pass- through is less pronounced the greater the amount of intra- firm
trade, a decrease in exchange rate pass- through is likely to occur.
Third, business cycle correlations are rising throughout the region. The
280 Asia and global production networks
more prominent increases are often associated with the PRC, a finding
consistent with the country’s growing role in the global supply chain.
Furthermore, the propagation of shocks throughout the East Asia system
is consistent with the PRC driving movements in output, at least in the
Republic of Korea and Taipei,China.
Finally, there is evidence that the central banks of the region are paying
more heed to the Chinese currency’s value. This is true at the high fre-
quency (daily) and at lower frequency (monthly); it is true with respect
to rates of depreciation, as well as levels of currency values. Since these
relationships are not structural, there is no guarantee that they will remain
in place. At the same time, continued integration by way of production
fragmentation should make central bankers pay extra heed to stabilizing
currency values against each other.
NOTES
* Paper prepared for the ADB Conference on Global Supply Chains and Trade in Value
Added. I thank David Hummels for very helpful comments. All remaining errors
remain solely my responsibility.
1. Data sources for each section are listed in Appendix 8A.1.
2. See Chinn (2006) for a discussion of the various different concepts of the real exchange
rate. In general, intermediates are not directly accounted for.
3. The conventional approach uses trade weights for traded goods, assuming goods are
differentiated by location.
4. There is a tradeoff between the use of the theoretically correct measures and the con-
ventional ones. The former requires detailed data on trade flows and from input–output
tables. Substantial measurement error is likely to be introduced as a consequence of
using conventional measures that use prices of final goods.
5. The sharp move in 1994 should be treated with caution, as the series is calculated using
official rates. Fernald et al. (1999) document the fact that pre- 1994, many transactions
were taking place at a different “swap” rate.
6. This leads to the question of whether simply using GDP deflators would mitigate the
problem substantially.
7. Koopman et al. (2012) approach the issue of measuring vertical specialization, defined
in various ways, in a manner that nests some of the other approaches. Their approach
incorporates measurement of domestic value added that is incorporated in imports used
in exports.
8. The problem, of course, is obtaining good proxies for these supply terms. In some previ-
ous studies, a measure of the US capital stock has been used. Obvious candidates, such
as US industrial production for US exports, exhibit too much collinearity with rest- of-
world GDP to identify the supply effect precisely. That is why this supply factor has
typically been identified in panel cross section analyses (Gagnon, 2003).
9. For instance, as in Chinn (2005).
10. Barrell and Dées (2005) and Camarero and Tamarit (2003) address the issue of very
high income elasticities by incorporating FDI into the specifications. IMF (2007) incor-
porates exports of intermediates in the import equation, and imports of intermediates
in the export equation, to account for vertical specialization. This procedure reduces the
estimated income elasticities.
11. Although even for the United States, the impact of vertical specialization is measurable;
Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships in Asia 281
the conventional and value added measures deviate by about 10 percent from 1995 to
2009.
12. One particularly difficult issue involves price deflators to use to convert nominal mag-
nitudes into real. Until 2005, the Chinese did not report price indices for imports and
exports; this limits the sample to one far too short to use in the analysis. Hence, we rely
upon a variety of proxy measures, each with some drawbacks. Since the trade flows are
reported in US dollars, the price measures we consider include the US producer price
index for finished goods, price indices from the World Bank, and Hong Kong, China
re- export unit value indices. We only report results based upon the last deflator; the
remaining results are qualitatively similar to those reported, and are available upon
request.
13. It could be argued that we should use processing exports instead of total exports.
Substituting one for the other does not lead to any consequential changes in the results.
We conjecture that this is the case because the two series share the same trajectory. See
Figure 3 in Cheung et al. (2012).
14. See Thorbecke (2006) for an examination of the impact of a yuan appreciation on the
US- PRC trade balance, taking into account imported intermediate goods.
15. Obviously, at a minimum, this approach would require correct measurement of bilat-
eral trade flows. Koopman et al. (2012) show that in many instances, particularly
involving East Asia, gross and value added trade balances can differ substantially.
16. This example is a modification of an example in Johnson (2014).
17. Estimates of exchange rate pass- through for industrial countries are around 0.5,
according to Campa and Goldberg (2005). Long run pass- through of 50 percent implies
that long- run profit margins for foreign exporting firms sustain extremely large shifts if
wages are sticky in the local currency.
18. Regression- based estimates are of similar magnitudes.
19. Ito and Chinn (2013) document the rapid rise in CNY invoicing in Chinese trade. To
the extent this is a largely exogenously driven process, exchange rate pass- through
should be expected to decline over time, holding all else constant.
20. See Baldwin (2009) for a summary of competing views.
21. In addition, most of the sample involves OECD countries, and includes only two East
Asian countries (Japan and the Republic of Korea).
22. An end- point problem arises in the context of the HP- filter, which is a two sided filter.
I have implemented the standard procedure, which is to extend the sample (in this case
by seven quarters) using an ARIMA (1,1,1) so the two- sided filter can be implemented
up to 2012Q4. A more economically substantive problem is that the recent observations
are likely to be based upon preliminary data, while data earlier in the sample are likely
to have undergone repeated benchmarking revisions.
23. If one expands the latter subsample to 2012, the business cycle correlations are typically
higher, attributable to the common shock associated with the global recession.
24. The fairly large change in the PRC- Philippines correlation probably reflects the end of
shocks to the Philippine economy arising from political events. The PRC- Philippines
correlation is actually negative in the earlier sample period.
25. Tempering the results, it is of note that the correlations also rise for Mexico and all
other countries in the sample. On the other hand, most of the Mexico pre- crisis correla-
tions were negative, or slightly positive (with Japan and United States), so that in the
latter sub- period, the Mexico correlations are still modest.
26. An alternative approach would be to use a VAR incorporating more macro variables,
such as interest or exchange rates, or employ a structural VAR. Given the brevity of the
available subsamples, and the large number of parameters that would have to be esti-
mated, I have opted for more parsimonious specifications. For an alternative approach,
see Bussiere et al. (2012).
27. This means a standard Cholesky decomposition is used, rather than the restriction
imposed by theory involving zero constraints.
28. Baldwin and Lopez- Gonzalez (2013), Table 23. This characterization applies to 2009.
282 Asia and global production networks
29. The results regarding US- PRC interactions differ because the impulse response func-
tions depend upon all the estimated parameters in the system of equations. In any case,
the quantitative impacts are very similar.
30. For an assessment based upon imports for production, see Ahuja and Nabar (2012).
31. For a practitioner’s view on how exchange rate movements complicate the management
of production chains, see Mahidhar (2006).
32. See Chinn (2012) for a discussion of what prerequisites need to hold for internation-
alization of a currency, with special reference to emerging market currencies. Ito and
Chinn (2013) examine the determinants of the use of the yuan as an invoicing currency.
33. The other conditioning factors are the three- month USD Libor- US Treasury (TED)
spread and the equity volatility index (VIX). These variables control for credit and
liquidity risk.
34. Spencer (2013) takes issue with the yuan bloc thesis. He undertakes a more limited
analysis, regressing exchange rates on four anchor currencies (US dollar, euro, yen,
and Chinese yuan), and finds that post- 2005, the dollar retains a high factor loading.
There is a problem of interpretation, since the yuan is managed against the dollar,
so movements adduced to the yuan might be more properly adduced to the dollar.
Nonetheless, the importance of the dollar persists even after the yuan is orthogo-
nalized against the other major currencies (although for the Korean won and the
Malaysian ringgit, the yuan coefficient is larger than the corresponding dollar coef-
ficient, so there does appear to be some evidence of a more prominent yuan bloc, even
in this analysis).
35. The financial stress index is suppressed in the early subsample.
36. I suppress inclusion of the US financial stress index in the early subsample, since it does
not vary much.
REFERENCES
Ahuja, A., and M. Nabar (2012), ‘Investment- led growth in China: global spillo-
vers’, IMF Working Paper No. 12/267.
Amiti, M., O. Itskhoki, and J. Konings (2012), ‘Importers, exporters, and exchange
rate disconnect’, mimeo.
Arkolakis, C., and A. Ramanarayanan (2009), ‘Vertical specialization and interna-
tional business cycle synchronization’, The Scandinavian Journal of Economics,
111, 655–680.
Bailliu, J., and E. Fujii (2004), ‘Exchange rate pass- through and the inflation
environment in industrialized countries: an empirical investigation’, Bank of
Canada Working Paper No. 2004–21.
Baldwin, R. (ed.) (2009), The Great Trade Collapse: Causes, Consequences and
Prospects, London: CEPR.
Baldwin, R. and J. Lopez- Gonzalez (2013), ‘Supply- chain trade: a portrait of
global patterns and several testable hypotheses’, NBER Working Paper No.
18957, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Barrell, R. and S. Dées (2005), ‘World trade and global integration in production
processes: a re- assessment of import demand equations’, ECB Working Paper
No. 503, Frankfurt: European Central Bank.
Bayoumi, T., M. Saito, and J. Turunen (2013), ‘Measuring competitiveness: trade
in goods or tasks?’, IMF Working Paper No. 13/100, Washington, DC: IMF.
Bems, R. (2012), ‘Intermediate inputs, external rebalancing and relative price
adjustment’, mimeo.
Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships in Asia 283
Bems, R., and R.C. Johnson (2012), ‘Value- added exchange rates’, NBER Working
Paper No. 18498, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Burstein, A., C. Kurz, and L. Tesar (2008), ‘Trade, production sharing, and the
international transmission of business cycles’, Journal of Monetary Economics,
55, 775–795.
Bussiere, M., A. Chudik, and G. Sestieri (2012), ‘Modelling global trade flows:
results from a GVAR model’, Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute
Working Paper No. 119, Dallas: Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.
Camarero, M. and C. Tamarit (2003), ‘Estimating the export and import demand
for manufactured goods: the role of FDI’, Leverhulme Center Research Paper
Series No. 2003/34, Nottingham: University of Nottingham.
Campa, J.M., and L.S. Goldberg (2005), ‘Exchange rate pass- through to import
prices’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 87, 679–690.
Carare, A., and A. Mody (2012), ‘Spillovers of domestic shocks: will they counter-
act the “Great Moderation”?’, International Finance, 15, 69–97.
Chen, H., M. Kondratowicz, and K.- M. Yi (2005), ‘Vertical specialization
and three facts about U.S. international trade’, North American Journal of
Economics and Finance, 16, 35–59.
Cheung, Y.- W., M. Chinn, and E. Fujii (2010), ‘China’s current account and
exchange rate’, in R. Feenstra and S.- J. Wei (eds), China’s Growing Role in
World Trade, University of Chicago Press for NBER.
Cheung, Y.- W., M. Chinn, and X.W. Qian (2012), ‘Are Chinese trade flows differ-
ent?’, Journal of International Money and Finance, 31, 2127–2146.
Chinn, M. (2005), ‘Doomed to deficits? Aggregate U.S. trade flows revisited’,
Review of World Economics, 141, 460–485.
Chinn, M. (2006), ‘A primer on real effective exchange rates: determinants, over-
valuation, trade flows and competitive devaluations’, Open Economies Review,
17, 115–143.
Chinn, M. (2010), ‘Supply capacity, vertical specialization and trade costs: the
implications for aggregate U.S. trade flow equations’, mimeo.
Chinn, M. (2012), ‘A note on reserve currencies with special reference to the G- 20
countries’, paper written for the International Growth Centre (IGC), India
Central Programme.
Choudhri, E. and D. Hakura (2012), ‘The exchange rate pass- through to import
and export prices: the role of nominal rigidities and currency choice’, IMF
Working Paper No. 12226, Washington, DC: IMF.
Di Giovanni, J., and A. Levchenko (2012), ‘Putting the parts together: trade,
vertical linkages, and business cycle comovement’, American Economic Journal:
Macroeconomics, 2, 95–124.
Fernald, J., H. Edison, and P. Loungani (1999), ‘Was China the first domino?
Assessing links between China and other Asian economies’, Journal of Inter-
national Money and Finance, 18, 515–535.
Fratzscher, M., and A. Mehl (2011), China’s dominance hypothesis and the
emergence of a tri- polar global currency system’, ECB Working Paper No.
1392.
Gagnon, J.E. (2003), ‘Long- run supply effects and the elasticities approach to
trade’, FRB International Finance Discussion Paper 754.
Ghosh, A., and R.S. Rajan (2007), ‘A survey of exchange rate pass- through in
Asia’, Asian- Pacific Economic Literature, 21, 13–28.
Goldstein, M., and M. Khan (1985), ‘Income and price effects in foreign trade’,
284 Asia and global production networks
in R. Jones and P. Kenen (eds), Handbook of International Economics, Vol. 2,
Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Gopinath, G., O. Itskhoki, and R. Rigobon (2010), ‘Currency choice and exchange
rate pass- through’, American Economic Review, 100, 304–336.
Hellerstein, R., and S.B. Villas- Boas (2010), ‘Outsourcing and pass- through’,
Journal of International Economics, 81, 170–183.
Hillberry, R. and D. Hummels (2012), ‘Trade elasticity parameters for a CGE
model’, in P.B. Dixon and D.W. Jorgenson (eds), Handbook of Computable
General Equilibrium Modeling, Elsevier.
Hooper, P., and C. Mann (1989), ‘Exchange rate pass- through in the 1980s: the
case of US imports of manufactures’, Brookings Papers in Economic Activity,
1, 297–337.
Huang, Y., D.L. Wang, and G. Fan (2013), ‘Paths to a reserve currency: interna-
tionalization of RMB and its implications’, paper prepared for ADBI workshop
Currency Internationalization: Lessons for the RMB, Tokyo.
Hummels, D., J. Ishii, and K.- M. Yi (2001), ‘The nature and growth of vertical
specialization in world trade’, Journal of International Economics, 54, 75–96.
International Monetary Fund (2007), ‘Chapter 3: Exchange rates and the adjust-
ment of external imbalances’, World Economic Outlook, Washington, DC:
IMF.
Ito, H. and M. Chinn (2013), ‘The rise of the “Redback” and China’s capital
account liberalization: an empirical analysis on the determinants of invoicing
currencies’, paper prepared for Asian Development Bank Institute workshop on
Currency Internationalization: Lessons for the RMB, Tokyo.
Johnson, R.C. (2014), ‘Five facts about value-added exports and implications for
macroeconomics and trade research’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 28 (2),
119–142.
Koopman, R., Z. Wang, and S.- J. Wei (2012), ‘Tracing value- added and double
counting in gross exports’, NBER Working Paper No. 18579, Cambridge, MA:
National Bureau of Economic Research.
Kose, M.A., and K.- M. Yi (2001), ‘International trade and business cycles: is
vertical specialization the missing link?’, The American Economic Review, 91,
371–375.
Mahidhar, V. (2006), ‘Managing in the face of exchange- rate uncertainty: a case
for operational hedging’, A Deloitte Research Study.
Marazzi, M., N. Sheets, R.J. Vigfusson, J. Faust, J.E. Gagnon, J. Marquez, R.F.
Martin, T.A. Reeve, and J.H. Rogers (2005), ‘Exchange rate pass- through to
U.S. import prices: some new evidence’, International Finance and Discussion
Papers No. 833.
Neiman, B. (2010), ‘Stickiness, synchronization, and pass through in intrafirm
trade prices’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 57, 295–308.
Ng, E.C.Y. (2010), ‘Production fragmentation and business- cycle comovement’,
Journal of International Economics, 82, 1–14.
Sekine, T. (2006), ‘Time- varying exchange rate pass- through: experiences of some
industrial countries’, BIS Working Paper No. 202.
Spencer, M. (2013), ‘A “yuan bloc” in Asia? Not yet’, Global Economic Perspectives,
New York: Deutsche Bank.
Stock, J., and M.W. Watson (2005), ‘Implications of dynamic factor models for
VAR analysis’, NBER Working Paper No. 11467, Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Global supply chains and macroeconomic relationships in Asia 285
Thorbecke, W. (2006), ‘How would an appreciation of the renminbi affect the US
trade deficit with China?’, BE Journal of Macroeconomics, 6, 1–17.
Thorbecke, W. (2011), ‘The effect of exchange rate changes on trade in East Asia’,
Asian Development Bank Institute Working Paper No. 263.
Thorbecke, W. and G. Smith (2010), ‘How would an appreciation of the RMB
and other East Asian currencies affect China’s exports?’, Review of International
Economics, 18, 95–108.
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (2013), World Investment
Report, UN: New York and Geneva.
Yi, K.- M. (2003), ‘Can vertical specialization explain the growth of world trade?’,
Journal of Political Economy, 111, 53–102.
286 Asia and global production networks
APPENDIX 8A.1
Section 2
Exchange rates: VAREER and REER_INS from Bems and Johnson
(2012).
Section 3
Data on exchange rates, GDP, trade flows, from Cheung et al. (2012).
Section 4
Quarterly real GDP in local currency, from IMF, International Financial
Statistics, except Euro area GDP from European Central Bank, and
Korean GDP from Organisation for Economic Co- operation and
Development via FRED, and Chinese GDP pre- 2000 from Cheung et al.
(2010).
Malaysian GDP starts in 1988, Thai GDP in 1993, Singapore GDP
begins in 1983Q2, Indonesian GDP starts in 1997, Taipei,China GDP data
in 1981. Annual data from IMF, World Economic Outlook (April 2013)
spliced to all series except Taipei,China using regressions in logs, where
annual data is interpolated via quadratic match average. All GDP series
except US, Japan, Republic of Korea, Euro area, and United Kingdom,
seasonally adjusted using ARIMA X- 12 applied to logged values.
HP detrending uses default l51600 for quarterly data; end point
problem addressed by using ARIMA(1,1,1) to project out seven quarters,
before HP filter is applied. For Indonesia, the ARIMA is applied only to
the 1997–2013Q1 sample.
Section 5
Exchange rates: Bilateral SDR exchange rates from the IMF, International
Financial Statistics (end of period). Euro/dollar exchange rates are from
the ECB. Data on the Taipei,China currency (NT$) is from the Bank of
China.
Financial stress indices are from the IMF (personal communication).
287
9. Mapping global value chains and
measuring trade in tasks
Hubert Escaith*
1. INTRODUCTION
Adequately measuring international trade taking place in global value
chains (GVCs) and its impact on national economies is still a work in
progress. Mapping GVCs, identifying where value- added is created,
how much and by whom, are the challenges that trade statisticians face.
Within supply chains, many production steps are carried out across dif-
ferent countries, with semi- finished products travelling along the produc-
tion chain between these countries. Each time these products criss- cross
national borders, international transactions are recorded at the full or
gross value of the product, which leads to multiple counts. At the end of
the supply chain, the parts are assembled for final use and then either con-
sumed domestically or exported. Ordinary concepts of country of origin
or country of destination do not fully apply anymore: if we look at the
national origin of the value- added incorporated in the final product, we
realize that significant shares of the value may come from other countries
than from the country of origin as ascribed by customs records.
Rising to this statistical challenge and producing the right numbers is
important for decision making in today’s world: not only business models
and strategies are changing, but also the way public policy makers should
understand their “home” country and their defensive and offensive inter-
ests in trade policy. The old division of labor between industrialized and
developing nations is losing its relevance, even if we are still far from
living in the same village. Meeting at the Los Cabos Summit in June
2012, G20 Leaders noted “. . . the relevance of regional and global value
chains to world trade, recognizing their role in fostering economic growth,
employment and development and emphasizing the need to enhance the
participation of developing countries in such value chains.”
GVCs may also change the way we understand trade theory. Some
researchers suggest they changed the old Ricardian law of comparative
advantages, as we shall see later. Even if this remains an open question, the
288 Asia and global production networks
fact is that GVCs alter many of the stylized facts on which trade or eco-
nomic development models are based. Even if for many dimensions, the
changes are of degree and of speed, on balance this is not old wine in a new
bottle: because of GVCs, something original and new is happening in the
international economy, with profound economic and social implications
at home. Theory and statistics go hand in hand; it is important to develop
the right empirical tools to back academic research and, in turn, highlight
new dimensions and identify gaps that require further attention.
The purpose of this chapter is to build on this compact between theory
and statistics in order to provide a road map for empirical work. It ana-
lyzes the challenge posed to trade statisticians by looking in the first place
for guidance from some relevant theoretical frameworks suggested by
trade and development models or business practices. The subsequent
sections enter into more detail on what kind of information needs to be
collected, and how. The review covers basically three lines of work, start-
ing from traditional trade statistics, then input–output accounting, then
finally reviewing recent developments in collecting micro- data on trade
by enterprise characteristics. At each step, examples involving the Asia-
Pacific region will be introduced; those examples are provided for didactic
purpose and do not pretend to offer an analysis, nor exhaust all the pos-
sibilities that a fully- fledged statistical exploration of trade in value- added
data would provide. The conclusion summarizes the main results and
looks for an integrating framework.
2. WHY AND WHAT? (THOU SHOULDST NOT
MEASURE WITHOUT A THEORETICAL
FRAMEWORK)
While slicing up the production process through international outsourc-
ing is not new, it is only recently that it became the dominant model in
industrial organization. Technical advances in transportation and com-
munications technology, as well as a series of institutional reforms, have
“flattened the world” and enabled the fragmentation of the production
process in different production stages, located in different countries.
This phenomenon has variously been called fragmentation, unbundling,
offshoring, vertical specialization, slicing- up of the value- added chain or
trade in tasks (WTO, 2008). Grossman and Rossi- Hansberg (2006) advo-
cate that the theory of trade in tasks is a new paradigm that differs from
the Ricardian law of comparative advantages.
1
Examples of processing trade existed since the 1970s; isolated cases
can even be traced in the early years of the 20th century. More recently,
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 289
fostering regional value chains was one of the driving factors behind
the signature of the North American Free Trade Agreement in the early
1990s. Yet the accession of the People’s Republic of China (PRC) to
the WTO in 2001 led to a quantum leap. In less than 10 years, trade in
intermediate products supplanted the old “Ricardian” trade in finished
goods in explaining emerging trade patterns, creating en passant a series of
accounting issues as goods in process of finalization criss- crossed several
international borders and inflated traditional statistics based on customs
values. While anecdotic data were available through case studies, aggre-
gate level analyses were more limited. An off- shoring index for the United
States (US) was calculated by Feenstra and Hanson in 1996, but it was
not before the 2000s that more systemic efforts were put in place. The first
worldwide estimates of trade in value- added were produced by scholars
(e.g., Daudin et al., 2006, building on Hummels et al., 2001); professional
statisticians joined efforts more recently and released in 2012 (WIOD) and
2013 (TiVA), the first “official” databases.
2
Before revising the different approaches that the statistical community
has adopted, the present chapter starts by taking the time to look at the
underlying models that have guided the work of the statisticians. Data
compiled by statisticians are the observed occurrences of a data- generating
process (DGP), and have only a meaning when put in relation to relevant
theoretical frameworks. Understanding the theoretical properties of this
DGP guides the work of the statisticians when looking at relevant indi-
cators, and provides the organizing principles that determine on which
aspects of the observed variables their attention should be concentrated.
Understanding that DGPs lie beyond the data is also important for the
user of statistics. As Koopmans (1947) once commented, without a model,
no practical inference for decision making is possible: “the rejection of
the help that economic theorizing might give leaves a void. . . . Without
resort to theory, in the sense indicated, conclusions relevant to the guid-
ance of economic policies cannot be drawn.” Oxley et al. (2008) go as far
as describing most attempts to measure complex socio- economic develop-
ments without some proper understanding or a theoretical definition, as
movies where “Mr Bean (counter) Measures the Economy”.
2.1 Looking for Relevant Models
The nature of trade along global production networks is multifaceted and
crosses several academic topics. The new trends in trade theory put much
emphasis on the micro- economic dimension of firm heterogeneity. The
management of international supply chains is now a profession and is
taught as a subject matter in engineering and business schools. Park et al.
290 Asia and global production networks
(2013) offer a commented review of the literature covering most, if not all,
its relevant strands. We propose here to look selectively for theoretical
guidelines in different places and then try to develop an integrating frame-
work. Pursuing a general to specific approach, our first model of reference
is network economics.
2.1.1 Network economics
The neoclassical approach to trade economics tends to focus on the bilat-
eral commerce between two parties and ignores much of the interactions
with other partners (for many years, the workhorse of the profession was
the two countries- two goods model). Global production networks (or
social networks, as the two share many points in common) are interested
in describing what kind of other third party connections two participants
have in common. A production network is, at its core, the nexus of inter-
connected functions, operations and transactions through which a specific
product or service is produced, distributed and consumed (Coe et al.,
2008).
In this framework, trade between two parties consists not only of the
characteristics proper of each partner (what they produce at what cost),
but also of their business environment (who they are in business with).
A neoclassical market could be seen as a collection of independent buy
and sell decisions, characterized by high entropy from a probabilistic per-
spective. In a trade and production network, what happens is the result
of a series of business decisions, some of them of long- term nature, such
as investment decisions. They will also involve a series of other partners
downstream, or can take place only after another upstream partner has
done its part of the contract and delivered the parts. The entropy of such
a system is much lower: trade takes place among pre- determined partners
glued together by arm’s length contracts or intra- firm relationship and
trade patterns that tend to reproduce themselves identically through time.
GVCs result from lead firms arbitraging between “make or buy” deci-
sions. The chemically pure example of the new model of globalized manu-
factures is perhaps the so- called “factoryless” firm, which creates networks
of workshops and manages its production lines in the cyberspace. Who
you are connected with is important: those networks determine and organ-
ize the production, distribution and use of knowledge and information.
The first tool associated with network economics is graph theory, as
this is the most intuitive way of representing the intricate relationships
between various firms and how they interact in order to conceive, produce
and deliver a product to its final market (Box 9.1). The graph model
introduces three crucial concepts: nodes or vertices (firms, consumers),
edges (connections) and orientation (upstream to downstream, loops).
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 291
BOX 9.1 WORLD TRADE NETWORK AS A GRAPH
Graph theory is particularly useful for analyzing international trade,
if only for its (apparent) simplicity. Graphs, understood as math-
ematical constructs (Figure 9.1) are simplified maps composed
exclusively of vertices (nodes) and edges (connections). Actual
trade networks are best described as directed graphs, or digraphs,
because they are made of directed edges (imports from, exports
to). A digraph G
n,k
consists of a set of vertices and a set of directed
edges (arcs), each linking a source vertex v
j
to a target vertex v
i
.
A
C
D
2
9
8
15
10
3
B
Source: Elaborated by the author.
Figure 9.1 Simple representation of trade as a graph
Despite their simplicity, graphs can be developed as relatively
complex mathematical models, providing important insights on
the way the actors (nodes) interact. From an historical per-
spective, the best- known example of graph analytics is the
Königsberg Bridge Problem solved by the Swiss mathematician
Euler (1707–1783). Its modern version is the Traveling Salesman
Problem, one of the cornerstones of operation research. The
increasing importance of social networks and improved computer
software has recently revived the interest in this subject, fostering
the development of new indicators.
292 Asia and global production networks
Graph theory, the mathematical approach to networks, may
rapidly become cumbersome when graphs are densely popu-
lated (many nodes) and complex (many links between nodes).
The World Trade Web (WTW), where countries are referred to
as nodes and the flows between them as arcs, is an example of
such a complex network (Tang and Wagner, 2010). Graphs that
contain too many nodes and arcs to be effectively illustrated using
standard graphs have to be analyzed in terms of their statistical
properties.
The most common statistical approach to trade and production
networks is through an input–output matrix. The graph can be
reproduced as a table where the line shows for a given industry
i the probability of intermediate product transiting from i to j while
in process of production (the probability of industry i selling its
output to industry j), or being absorbed in final demand as a fin-
ished product. This provides a forward view of the graph, where
the product will go industry by industry to receive a series of
transformations before reaching the stage of final product where
it is consumed or invested domestically, or exported to a third
country where it will be absorbed.
a
But the graph can also be read
backward as a process where industry j purchases intermediate
inputs from node i. Those inputs can be goods or services, and
the suppliers may be located in different countries.
Table 9.1 Matrix representation of Figure 9.1
IO(G) A B C D
A 10 8
B 15
C 9 2
D 3
Source: Author’s illustration.
Our previous example can be represented in a tabular form, as
in Table 9.1. The backward and forward process is represented
by the matrix form IO(G), describing in a line the sales of outputs
to the different nodes of the network, and in columns the pur-
chase of inputs to these nodes. If we consider only the transac-
tions in intermediate inputs (excluding sales for final demand, or
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 293
Those building blocks are the essential constituting elements identifying a
network, thus are primary candidates on “what to measure”. Using these
simple building blocks, graph theory develops sophisticated indicators of
connectedness.
The graph approach tends to emphasize connectivity, and the related
field of network economics has developed several tools to qualify and
measure connectedness. As mentioned in Box 9.1, production networks
can also be analyzed using well- known input–output matrix algebra. The
representation of the network graph through an input–output matrix
extended to cover international transactions in intermediate goods cap-
tures directly or indirectly all the features of the graph, including the
notion of connectedness strength and the average distance between
connected nodes.
Value- added, finance and corporate ownership In a GVC network, the
connections between the nodes (industries) go beyond the trade dimen-
sion. The difference between the total value of the sales of industry j (the
sum of the weight of outgoing arcs) and the total value of inputs entering
into node j (the total value of incoming arcs) gives the value that the indus-
try created during the transformation of inputs into output. This value,
called value- added by the national accountants, plays a significant role
in the economic analysis of production networks: it serves to remunerate
the primary inputs (labor and capital) as well as paying indirect taxes on
production.
This value- added belongs also to another circuit income flows that
runs parallel to the product circuit. Income flows are made, for example,
of dividends, royalties and interest payments. Monetary income is created
in one industry but can be transferred to households or firms that are resi-
dent in other countries. This secondary circuit makes possible the financial
absorbing state in the Markov chain terminology), then we obtain
a square matrix listing all industries in all countries participating to
the network. The diagonal (sales of an industrial sector to itself)
does not need to be zero; as in our example, a sector/country is
made of several firms, which may specialize in different varieties
of the same product; obviously, the more aggregated the sector,
the higher the frequency of inter- industry transactions.
Note:
a
Exports of intermediate products to an industry located abroad were
already considered as part of the inter- industry network.
294 Asia and global production networks
viability of the product circuit (its reproduction) when the final products
are eventually purchased, consumed or invested thanks to the income
generated. It is possible (Escaith and Gonguet, 2011) to superpose a mon-
etary circuit to the product space defined by intra- industry international
trade. Eventually, the trade and production network also relates to the
corporate networks, as in a globalized world international trade is domi-
nated by a subset of large multinational enterprises (MNEs) and many
transactions take place within related firms and establishments. According
to the UN Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD, 2013),
MNE- coordinated GVCs account for some 80 percent of global trade.
For the same network, physical flows may differ from financial ones
for a series of reasons, ranging from supply- chain governance (intra- firm
trade may not entail change of ownership and actual payments for inputs
purchased, or the banks issuing and receiving payments may be located in
countries that differ from those involved in the physical flows) to tax plan-
ning.
3
Moreover, as we shall see later, physical flows between two partners
may not provide anymore an adequate picture of the trade relationship
between those countries. It is, in particular, the case when trade flows are
intermediated by a third country that plays the role of a “hub”. As Maurer
and Degain (2010) highlight, what you see (through traditional trade sta-
tistics) is not what you get.
Besides their theoretical and statistical implications, the coexistence of
three interconnected spaces product, income and finance circuits has
important consequences for understanding the dynamics of globalized
economies, the micro- macro interaction of national economies and the
accumulation of imbalances. All those aspects, obviously, shall call the
attention of the statistician when defining the new measures and indicators
required for representing the economic implications of global production
networks. Production is only one side of the GVC coin, as the rationales
behind those chains are also closely related to international economics,
which responds to its proper set of theoretical models.
2.1.2 Trade theory and development policy implications
The natural theoretical framework of reference for identifying the rel-
evant dimensions to be measured when analyzing global value chains is
trade theory, in particular its most recent avatars: new and “new” new
trade theories. The new trade theory is strongly associated with, inter alia,
Wilfred Ethier (1979) and Paul Krugman (1979) who, in the late 1970s,
incorporated increasing returns to scale into previous models. Increasing
returns are a deviation from the neo- classical hypothesis and tend to gen-
erate specialized and localized patterns. In particular, external benefits
such as agglomeration effects facilitate the creation of localized industrial
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 295
networks, as those discussed in the previous section. Those clusters are
self- reinforcing, thanks to the benefits provided by the size of the cluster
and the scope of specialization of participating firms. Thus, connectedness
within networks is, once again, an important dimension to measure.
Reductions in trade costs are also even more important in the new trade
theories. Not only do transaction costs explain the agglomeration of pro-
duction in a specific location, but their reduction was a necessary factor
in facilitating the international fragmentation of the production process
(WTO, 2008). More generally, gravity models that use some measure of
distance between trade partners as explanatory variables are standard
features of the trade- economist’s tool- box; a current topic of research
is measuring the effect of distance on trade in intermediate products
(typical of GVCs) and trade in final goods. Therefore, measuring those
trade costs should be an important item on the trade statistician’s agenda.
Transaction costs include border aspects (tariff and non- tariff measures),
as well as logistics and freight costs by mode of transport. Those transport
modes are also relevant for the environmental implication of international
trade.
The “new” new trade theory, by putting the emphasis on firm heteroge-
neity (Melitz, 2003) is another source of guidance on the relevant dimen-
sions to take into account in our attempt at measuring global value chains.
This new school, which has a clear empirical foundation, thrived on the
increasing availability of firm-level data-tracking trade operations by firm
characteristics.
4
Firms typically differ in terms of their productivity; some
of them find it profitable to sell only on the domestic market, while the
most productive export. Further empirical investigation shows that firm
heterogeneity is closely related to ownership and governance structures,
including global supply chain linkages. What the statistician should retain
here are two things. First, that the “representative firm” approach adopted
in input–output models is not sufficient for providing an adequate repre-
sentation of modern trade. Second, foreign direct investment flows have
to be part of the picture because foreign ownership is often a key factor
explaining GVC trade patterns.
As part of the larger trend of “new” new trade theory, a growing
strand is dedicated to analyzing trade within global value chains as “trade
in tasks”. Through GVCs, technology proper to lead firms (typically
installed in developed countries) can be used effectively by first- tier pro-
viders and affiliates located in developing countries. This is analytically
similar to a virtual migration of workers from cheap labor location to
high productivity locations, without actually paying the full increase in
labor cost. In more technical terms, trade in tasks is assimilated to a tech-
nological shock that changes a country’s labor endowments measured in
296 Asia and global production networks
productivity- equivalent units. This shock may allow firms in high labor
cost countries to remain competitive vis- à- vis the increasing competition
from emerging countries; on the other hand, it may also help firms in
developing countries to close their technological gap. Trade in tasks is
also trade in skills, as differences in wages across countries is determined
not only by the average wage level, but also by the relative abundance of
skilled labor. In practical terms, this has important effects on wages and
income distribution in both developed and developing countries. This
theoretical branch of trade policy signals, therefore, that any attempt to
“map” international trade in its new dimensions should include a measure
of labor by skills and industries.
GVCs offer new options to developing countries. Gereffi and Sturgeon
(2013) review the situation and policy options of emerging countries, but
the potential is also high for small developing countries that did not find
a niche in the older international division of labor. What Grossman and
Rossi- Hansberg (2006) and Baldwin (2006) tell us is that globalization
today differs from the old approach in that the opportunities for jobs and
value creation is occurring at a much finer level of disaggregation. GVCs
enable a finer degree of specialization, allowing the production process
to be fragmented into narrowly defined segments or “tasks”. Recently,
development theory has borrowed from network sciences to define the
concept of “product space”. This is a network approach to trade by
product grouping, similar to the idea of revealed comparative advantages
(Hidalgo et al., 2007). Countries export products for which they have
comparative advantages, but not all products have the same potential for
export diversification at the extensive margin. Being able to diversify into
new products depends not only on the relative situation of the developing
country from the production frontier, but also the easiness of moving to
other products (connectedness). Some areas of the product space may be
denser than others and transition easier. Environmental impacts of natural
resources based GVCs and international modes of transport are relevant
issues for sustainable development analysis. Finally, the macro- economics
of open economies be they developing or developed is also interested
in the outcome of the statistical research agenda on trade in value- added,
as signalled in Box 9.2.
2.1.3 International supply chain management
The last strand of literature to be called in the service of defining a
theoretical framework for “measuring trade in global value chains” is
the business school approach to international supply chain management.
Actually, the term GVC originated in the management literature and is
closely associated with international supply chains. Geoffrion and Powers
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 297
BOX 9.2 WHY IS TRADE IN VALUE- ADDED
IMPORTANT? A MACRO- POLICY
PERSPECTIVE
Rifflart and Schweisguth (2013) mention several areas where
measuring trade in value- added brings a new perspective and is
likely to impact policy choices:
1. Using accurate value- added trade data would improve
exchange rate assessments. Real effective exchange rates
based on value- added trade weights would reveal more
accurate measures of competitiveness of a country than
those based on gross trade weights.
2. Real effective exchange rates based on value- added trade
would improve estimates of the impact of changes in
relative prices, including that on global rebalancing. This
reflects the higher foreign content in the downstream coun-
try’s exports, which mitigates the impact of exchange rate
changes.
3. Decomposing foreign value- added in exports by source
country would help understand how disruptions to supply
chains can have spillover effects. Disruptions of trade flows
could be either policy induced, such as preferential/regional
trade agreements, or naturally caused, such as the 2011
earthquake in Japan.
4. Bilateral balances, if discussed for political economy con-
siderations, are better measured with value- added, rather
than gross, trade data. Accounting for trade in intermedi-
ate parts and components, and taking into account “trade
in tasks”, does not change the overall trade balance of a
country with the rest of the world, but it redistributes the
surpluses and deficits across partner countries.
5. Measuring trade in value- added sheds new light on today’s
trade reality, where competition is not between nations,
but between firms. Competitiveness in a world of global
value chains means access to competitive inputs and tech-
nology. Optimum tariff structure in such a situation is flat
(little or no escalation) and reliable (contractual arrange-
ments within supply chains, especially between affiliated
establishments, tend to be long term). As a consequence,
298 Asia and global production networks
(1995) provide a comprehensive review of the early literature and how
the corporate status of logistics has changed dramatically since the late
1970s. The main object of the business approach is value creation, and
most of the present- day literature refers formally or informally to earlier
work by Michael Porter on cluster and competitive advantages (Porter,
1985). Another important contribution, if only to be able to understand
the variations in the value- added per unit of output, is attributed to Stan
Shih, the founder of IT Acer Company, in the early 1990s. Shih realized
that value- added ratios define a “smiley curve” through the product cycle.
Manufacturing lies at the bottom of the value- added curve, while higher
value- added content is found in services, either at the upstream part of
the chain (R&D) or closer to the customer, at the down- stream segment
(branding, distribution, after- sale services).
This analysis has important implications on the trade and development
perspective, as most developing countries enter GVCs through cheap
labor at assembly level. More directly relevant for our present purpose, the
smiley curve tends to indicate that what is important when analyzing trade
in tasks are the business functions, rather than the tasks themselves. Lanz
et al. (2011) highlight the importance of “working with others” and look
at the “task intensity” by clusters of tasks.
Analyzing trade through business practices may also help in identifying
potential issues in data collection. Trade practices show that not all export-
ing firms trade directly, but many go through trade agents, or wholesal-
ers. Some estimates put at about 20 percent the value of international
trade done by agents. In practice, this means that customs registers will
not reflect the true industrial origin of the exported goods. The business
perspective shows the limits of the value- added dimension when looking
tariffs, non- tariff barriers and trade measures such as
anti- dumping rights are likely to impact domestic producers
in addition to foreign producers.
6. The impact of macro- economic shocks would be better
assessed. The 2008–2009 financial crisis was character-
ized by a synchronized trade collapse in all economies.
What role did global supply chains play in the transmis-
sion of a demand shock in markets affected by a credit
shortage? A better understanding of value- added trade
flows would provide tools for policymakers to anticipate
the impact of macro- economic shocks and adopt the right
policy responses.
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 299
at profitability and investment decisions from a micro- economic perspec-
tive. Value- added includes many elements that are actually costs for the
firms (wages, taxes, even part of the capital income, which corresponds
to the cost of capital). Similarly, high value- added per unit of output may
not correspond to high technology or to high quality jobs: the rate of
value- added in traditional agriculture is close to 100 percent, because the
monetary cost of inputs is nil. Conversely, high technology means high
volumes with good quality standards, but higher input consumption (i.e.,
lower value- added per unit of output).
2.2 What Should Be Counted?
The review of underlying theories and their main topics of interest should
help us advance more rapidly with the next question: what? We saw that
global production networks operate in many dimensions: trade in inter-
mediate goods, trade in factors of production, trade in tasks, financial and
income transfers, etc. Some of these dimensions may be more difficult to
measure as they are hidden below several layers of superficial informa-
tion. Moreover, trade in tasks itself (or the value- added content of trade)
can only be measured indirectly: strictly speaking, therefore, we cannot
measure it, but only provide an estimate.
A proper mapping of global value chains requires collecting informa-
tion on operational, financial and corporate governance aspects. Those
are fruits that hang at different heights of the tree, operational aspects
being low- hanging, while governance ones stay unseen at the top. It is also
important to compile the information, keeping the systemic dimension
that relates all those bounties within a comprehensive and analytically
relevant statistical model.
Our review of the relevant analytical approaches identified the follow-
ing points of interest, which are either flows (visible or invisible; physical
or financial) or actors (firms, households, markets):
Trade in intermediate inputs, including goods and services. This is
the glue connecting the firms participating in international supply
chains and, at the same time, the belt that keeps them moving
together. Trade flows are classified (according to the relevant
classification for goods and services) and divided as incoming
(inputs) or outgoing (output) for each relevant actor (firm or
sector).
Transaction costs: freight and insurance by modes of transport,
border and “behind the border” costs (tariff duties and cost of
complying with non- tariff measures).
300 Asia and global production networks
Balance between incoming and outgoing trade flows. This provides
the measure of the value- added created by each firm in the value
chain. Value- added should be disaggregated into its main compo-
nents (wages, profit and taxes, to use common language).
5
Jobs and skills, if possible related within broader business functions.
Capital and its ownership (tangible, intangible, technological content
and intellectual property, as it relates to trade in income through
royalties and fees).
Non- reproducible capital or inputs (natural resources, land, water)
used and consumed, as well as other environmental variables (trade
and production related carbon dioxide (CO
2
) emissions, etc.).
3. HOW TO MAP AND MEASURE?
This section will review some of the approaches that have been used by
trade statisticians to map the various dimensions of trade taking place
within global value chains and estimate its value.
3.1 Mapping the Flow of Goods and Services
The obvious starting point for mapping value chains is to look at the
intermediate inputs, which are used for the production of final (finished)
products.
6
Unlike final products, intermediate goods or services produced
by a given firm will be further processed by other downstream productive
establishments before being sold, either to another firm further down the
value chain, or as final products. Trade in intermediate inputs, includ-
ing goods and services, is the glue connecting the firms participating in
international supply chains and, at the same time, the belt that keeps them
moving together. Mapping those flows, using available trade statistics,
is therefore an intuitive way of describing the network. As mentioned by
Sturgeon and Memedovic (2010), revisiting existing trade data sets with a
new angle leads to considerable benefits, rapidly available and at relatively
little cost. One early example in the specialized literature is Yeats (2001).
Moreover, recent advances in the analysis of social networks provide a
series of quantitative indicators (and dedicated software) that go beyond
the simple mapping of trade patterns to compute synthetic indicators.
7
Trade flows are classified according to the relevant classification for
goods and services and divided as incoming (inputs) or outgoing (output)
for each relevant actor (firm or sector). Trade in goods is relatively well
mapped, and detailed information by products and partners is available
at dedicated databases like COMTRADE, maintained by the United
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 301
Nations Statistical Division. Differentiating between intermediate and
final goods can be solved relatively easily by doing a secondary classifi-
cation on the UN Broad Economic Categories (BEC) classification that
splits the Standard International Trade Classification (SITC) or, alter-
natively, the Harmonized System (HS) of merchandise, into their final
use (intermediate, capital or consumer goods). Crossing BEC and SITC
has the advantage of classifying each good by stage of production and by
industry (OECD, 2005).
The case of services is much more complex. Most existing statistics are
compiled for balance of payments purposes (the IMF BOP or the UN
Extended Balance of Payments Services Classification or EBOPS clas-
sifications) rather than analytical purpose (as in the UN Central Product
Classification or CPC). Moreover, only the most advanced countries
publish bilateral flows of services. When only the most aggregate values
are available (total imports and total exports of transport, travel and
“other services”), imputing bilateral flows remains a matter of guesswork
(Miroudot et al., 2009; and Timmer, 2012). The good news is that the task
may become easier in the future, as work is under way to develop a cor-
respondence table between EBOPS 2010 and CPC Version 2.0, which may
help in the future.
Trade in intermediate goods and services within GVCs is sometimes
seen as a statistical nuisance because it creates double counting. The value
of parts and components that compose goods in process of elaboration are
counted each time they (or the product in which they are embedded) cross
a border. This double counting tends to artificially inflate the importance
of trade and was probably one of the factors that led to a gradual increase
in the world trade to GDP ratio up to 1995 (WTO, 2013a and b). Yet, far
from being a double counting nuisance, trade in intermediate products
can, to the contrary, provide invaluable information on the topology of
value chains. Because the information on trade in intermediate inputs, at
least in the domain of merchandise, is very detailed (the HS classification
at its 6 digit level distinguishes some 5000 different categories of goods),
the mapping can be very precise and provides information on the pattern
of specialization of each country within regional or international produc-
tive clusters (Goyal, 2007; Flores and Vaillant, 2011). As we shall see later,
this is a clear advantage over more holistic accounting approaches such as
input–output models, because the mapping of trade in intermediate goods
allows one to understand very detailed inter- industrial interactions.
According to Ferrarini (2011), Ng and Yeats (1999) were the first to
compile detailed lists of the parts and components trade to assess the mag-
nitude of processing trade in East Asia.
8
IDE- JETRO in the late 1970s
was already compiling inter- industry trade flows of intermediate products
302 Asia and global production networks
in order to build its Asian input–output matrices, one of the first of such
attempts. Indeed, compiling and allocating trade flows of intermediate
products by country and sector of origin and destination is a critical step
in building international input–output matrices. Ferrarini (2011) provides
a very good example of the practical steps that statisticians must undertake
in order to have a good database on intermediate flows.
The first practical issue a researcher has to solve is that trade partners
usually have different perceptions of their mutual trade flows – something
called asymmetry in data. One important source of discrepancy is that an
export from A to B will usually be recorded ‘free on board’ (FOB), while
imports of B from A will be recorded on their higher ‘cost, insurance and
freight’ (CIF) basis.
9
Other sources of discrepancies are due to different
ways of recording merchandise in the export and import countries, or the
difficulty in tracing the actual country of origin or destination when goods
are transiting through international hubs such as Rotterdam, Singapore or
Hong Kong, China. As done by many other researchers, Ferrarini (2011)
uses BACI, a data set compiled by the Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et
d’Information Internationales (CEPII), which reconciles trade partners’
import and export data to obtain a symmetric matrix of trade flows.
Instead of using only one year, he averages two observation points (say
2006 and 2007), in order to reduce the incidence of outliers.
The next step is to differentiate between final and intermediate goods,
based on the correspondence between the HS at 6 digits and the BEC. In
practice, this can be quite a tricky issue because some items have mixed
use. The Ferrarini paper gives the example of “Internal combustion engine
spark plugs” (HS 851110), which can be mounted on an engine in a factory
(intermediate consumption of manufacture), purchased by a garage (inter-
mediate consumption of a service sector) or sold to car owners (adminis-
tration and household final consumption). Besides the conceptual issues
mentioned in Note 7, one of the biggest classification issues, at least in
terms of value, is the treatment of fuels. When a taxi driver fills up the
tank of her car, it is an intermediate consumption by the service sector;
the same purchase done to fill a private or a government car will be final
consumption. As it is very difficult to impute the imports of fuel according
to their use (unless one uses supply- utilization tables, but this technique is
proper to the IO approach and does not belong to the simpler trade flow
approach), fuels are therefore usually excluded from the computation (it is
at least the practice at WTO).
Once the dissociation between intermediate and final use is done, the
next step is to assign the goods to their sector of production in order to
have an economic perspective (this step is not compulsory if one needs
only to map trade without looking into the sectoral implications). Here,
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 303
it is often easier to use SITC rather than HS, as SITC has a clearer sec-
toral relationship. Fortunately, correspondence tables are maintained by
the UN Statistical Division, even if some fine tuning may be required in
specific cases.
To provide an example, Figure 9.2 shows the purchase of inputs by
selected Asia- Pacific sectors using trade in intermediate goods data esti-
mated for 2008 by IDE- JETRO for the Asia- Pacific region (Inomata,
2011). Note that a sector in one country can also be a provider for the
same sector in another country. After filtering out the intermediate trade
flows that represent less than 20 percent of the purchases of each importer,
a visual analysis of the graph provides a few interesting indications. The
main provider of inputs is the manufacturing sector (coded 3 in the graph).
The People’s Republic of China (C) and Japan (J) appear as the main
source of manufacturing inputs. Note also the role of Singapore (S), espe-
cially as provider of manufacturing inputs to Malaysia (M).
Besides the actual mapping of trade in intermediate products, some
quantitative indicators can be derived from this approach.
10
In- degree in
such a directed graph (digraph) is the number of international suppliers
(upstream connections) from which the sector sources its inputs (domestic
inputs are excluded from the graph). “Betweenness centrality” can be best
defined intuitively by the damage the removal of a vertex would do to the
network if it was removed: some nodes work as “hubs” and have a sys-
temic importance. Weighting this centrality criteria by the degree of con-
nections each of the connected vertices have will lead to the “Eigenvector
Centrality” indicator.
The list of indicators that can be constructed from a graph is long (and
increasing thanks to the new interest graph theory has been receiving in
the past decade).
11
Table 9.2 presents, for illustration purpose only, some
of the network statistics calculated on the graph in Figure 9.2. Individual
data show the first 15 vertices (country/sector) and the average for all
other 55 vertices.
A diachronic approach of graphs is also a source of interesting results.
Using the same set of countries that is used in Figure 9.2, Escaith and
Inomata (2013) describe the evolution of industrial networks in Asia-
Pacific through time, and the rise of the PRC as a hub. As shown in
Figure9.3, in 1985 there were only four key players in the region: Japan (J)
as hub, Indonesia (I), Malaysia (M) and Singapore (S). With time, Japan
also extended supply chain relationships to other East Asian economies,
especially to the group known as the newly industrialized economies
(NIEs). This is the phase when the relocation of Japanese production
bases to neighboring countries was accelerating, triggered by the Plaza
Accord in 1985. It saw the building of strong linkages between core parts
304 Asia and global production networks
suppliers in Japan and their foreign subsidiaries. The United States (U)
came into the picture in the late 1990s while the PRC began to emerge as
the third regional giant. By 2005, the center of the network had completely
shifted to the PRC, pushing the United States and Japan to the periphery.
The PRC became the supply chain hub, where final consumption goods
were produced for export to the US and European markets.
GVCs are primarily about making money (value- added, using the
national accounts jargon). The graph approach is the first step toward
analyzing the value- added that is generated at each step of the value
chain. The difference between the value of out- going flows (sales) and
incoming ones (purchases) provides a measure of the value- added gen-
erated in the process. Considering only imported inputs and exported
output flows, Figure 9.4 shows, for example, that the countries which
registered highest growth in their manufactured exports between 1995
and 2008 were those countries that had increased more rapidly their use
of imported inputs.
Using traditional trade statistics for analyzing global value chains is
particularly effective when the researcher is interested in a certain type
of product. Different from the value- added approach which will be
N7
N1
N4
N3
N5
N2
P2
P6
P3
P4
U2
U5
U4
U3
U1
U7
U6
C2
J4
J2
J6
J7
K2
K6
K4
K5
K3
K1
K7
J5
J3
J1
C6
C3
C7
C4
C5
17
M2
S2
S1
S6
S3
M3
M5
M1
M4
M6
N6
T1
T2
T3
T6
T4
T5
T7
I4
I6
I5
I2
Notes:
Letters denote the reporting economy (C: People’s Republic of China; I: Indonesia; J:
Japan; K: Korea; M: Malaysia; N: Taipei,China; P: Philippines; S: Singapore; T: Thailand;
U: USA) and numbers the sectors (1: Agriculture; 2: Mining; 3: Manufacturing; 4:
Electricity, gas and water; 5: Construction; 6: Trade and transport; 7: Other services).
To simplify the graph, flows lower than 20% of sectoral imported inputs were excluded.
Source: Digraph generated by NodeXL based on IDE- JETRO Asia Input–Output data.
Figure 9.2
Graph of intermediate inputs trade by industries in selected
Asia- Pacific reporters, 2008
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 305
reviewed in the next section and provides information at aggregated sec-
toral level –merchandise trade statistics can be disaggregated into more
than 5000 product categories in the Harmonized System. For example,
many researchers interested in the trade- development nexus and the issue
of value- chain upgrading want to analyze trade patterns according to the
technological sophistication of the products. Lall et al. (2005) provide a
detailed example of the calculation of sophistication scores for 237 exports
at the 3- digit SITC level and 766 exports at the 4- digit level. This classifica-
tion, while not pretending to be a world standard, has inspired analytical
work in UN agencies such as Economic Committee for Latin America
and the Caribbean (ECLAC) and UNCTAD. OECD and EUROSTAT
also have defined a classification of high- technology sectors and products
(Hatzichronoglou, 1997). The classification is based both on direct R&D
intensity and R&D embodied in intermediate and investment goods.
Table 9.2 Selected network indicators for the Asian input–output 2008
graph
Vertices
a
In- degree Betweenness
centrality
Eigenvector
centrality
S3 19 93.7 0.021
N3 25 95.6 0.021
K3 30 95.0 0.021
J3 31 94.1 0.021
J6 20 94.1 0.021
M3 25 97.0 0.021
U3 25 96.9 0.021
U6 18 96.9 0.021
I3 31 97.8 0.021
I6 18 97.8 0.021
T3 29 98.7 0.021
K6 20 87.7 0.021
C3 26 99.6 0.021
C6 22 99.6 0.021
S6 18 80.6 0.021
Other sectors
b
(simple average) 24 13.3 0.013
Notes:
a. First character denotes the trade partners, the number refers to the industrial sector
(seeFigure 9.2).
b. Simple average of all non- negative trade flows, including those inferior to 20% of total
inputs.
Source: See Figure 9.2.
306 Asia and global production networks
Interestingly, the latest revision of the classification includes services
(OECD, 2011).
Nevertheless, it remains important to keep in mind that such classifications
– based on imported and exported goods – can be greatly misleading when
trade takes place in GVCs where what is actually traded are the tasks and
not the products. Relatively simple tasks (e.g., assembly) can be incorpo-
rated into very sophisticated electronic equipment. This does not imply
that the sector/country’s production frontier has moved toward high-
technology. Therefore, popular indicators such as revealed comparative
advantages have to be treated carefully when trade in tasks is prevalent.
Another aspect of interest for the researchers following the new “new”
trade theory is product differentiation. Applying statistical filters to
the raw data (e.g., splitting HS categories by quality, using unit values)
should help to provide a better understanding of the industrial clusters
participating in GVCs.
J
M
T
N
U
C
S
K
I
P
2005
J
M
S
I
1985
Note: See Figure 9.2.
Source: Escaith and Inomata (2013).
Figure 9.3 Evolution of Asia- Pacific intra- industry network, 1985–2005
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 307
Using OECD data, Figure 9.5 gives an example of trade indicators
crossing technological content and quality differentiation for a selection.
Industries are classified by technological content and, for each HS6 product
they export, high, medium and low quality ranks are determined by looking
at the relative position of their unit value compared to world trade in
similar products (OECD, 2013). Within each of the industries, the graph
nicely illustrates the specialization of high- income countries (Japan, the
US) in high quality/high price products, while developing countries export
low or medium quality varieties. The graph shows also that the US is still an
exporter of medium and low priced products in the low technology sectors.
This specialization on different quality segments allows countries with
different comparative advantage to trade in the same type of products, in
apparent breach of the traditional trade theory that predicted a clear spe-
cialization by type of activity. This type of information is also relevant for
development economists, as it shows that lesser developed economies are
not condemned to compete head- to- head with emerging and developed
countries, but may find an entry niche in low quality segments, before
upgrading by climbing up the quality ladder.
AUS
BGR
BRA
CAN
PRC
DEN
CZE
GER
SPA
EST
FRA
UKG
GRC
HUN
INO
IND
IRE
ITA
JPN
KOR
LVA
MEX
NET
POL
POR
ROM
RUS
TUR
TAP
USA
ROW
0
5
10
15
20
25
–5 0 5 10 15 20 25
30
Manufacturing exports increase
Foreign content of exports (VS)
increase
Note: VS stands for Vertical Specialization (see text).
Source: Adapted from WTR (2013) on the basis of OECD- WTO TiVA database.
Figure 9.4 Export performance and reliance on imported inputs (1995–
2007, % annual growth)
308 Asia and global production networks
Medium–low technology
Low prices (%)
Low technology
JPN
JPN
PRC
PRC
INO
INO
IND
IND
USA
USA
High prices (%)
Medium prices (%)
High technology Medium–high technology
F
F
JPN
JPN
PRCINO
INO
IND
IND
PRC
USA
USA
Note: The position of a point in the triangular graph represents the relative share of low- ,
medium- and high- priced products for each technological category.
Source: Based on an interpretation of data displayed in Figure 5.12 of OECD (2013).
Figure 9.5 Exports by technology content and price level, selected Asia-
Pacific countries (2010)
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 309
Rauch (1999) looks into the issue from a different angle and offers a
classification of merchandise into three categories (homogeneous, ref-
erence priced, and differentiated). Products traded on an organized
exchange (Chicago Board of Trade, New York Mercantile Exchange,
etc.) are considered homogeneous goods. When manufactured goods are
not sold on mercantile exchanges but are sufficiently standardized to be
benchmarked for price and quality (chemicals, special types of steel), they
are classified as reference priced; all other products were deemed differen-
tiated. The latter category includes the inputs specifically tailored to the
end- user’s needs (e.g., automobile parts).
3.2 Measuring Trade in Value- Added
12
While mapping trade in intermediate inputs is important to under-
stand the topology of the production process, a value- added approach
enables one to assess the net economic contribution of each contribut-
ing sector/country and further disaggregate it into its main components
(wages, profits and taxes).
13
Estimates of the value- added content of
trade rely typically on Leontief inverse matrices based on international
input–output (IIO) tables, which integrate national accounts and bilat-
eral trade statistics. IIO tables present the advantage of capturing in a
cost- effective manner not only direct linkages and exchanges between
countries and sectors, but also after applying the standard Leontief
transformation, the indirect sectoral linkages. The IDE- JETRO’s Asian
Input–Output Tables are the earliest examples of systematic compila-
tion of IIO with a clear statistical objective (most academic researchers
have instead used non- official or ad- hoc data, such as GTAP or Eora
databases).
14
The most recent advances in compiling IIO rely principally on the
increasing availability of country supply- use tables, which – for each
sector provide a detailed picture of the supply of goods and services
inputs by origin (domestic production and imports) and the use of output
for intermediate, consumption and final use (consumption, gross capital
formation, exports). The supply- use table also provides information on
the value- added components (compensation of employees, other net
taxes on production, consumption of fixed capital, net operating surplus).
From 2010 to 2012, best practices in compiling such data were greatly
enhanced by the experience gained through an EU- funded project, the
World Input–Output Data Base (WIOD). The WIOD project also devel-
oped socio- economic satellite accounts that allow deriving employment or
environmental impact from the models (Box 9.3).
Once the IIO table is available, a series of trade indicators can be
310 Asia and global production networks
produced, each one capturing a specific aspect of trade in value- added.
Most, if not all, start from a simple accounting framework. The basic rela-
tionship, from a single country perspective, can be described as follows:
15
g 5 A*g 1 y
where:
BOX 9.3 DERIVING SOCIO- ECONOMIC IMPACT
FROM TRADE IN VALUE- ADDED
Since the 2008–2009 crisis, the trade- and- labor issue is par-
ticularly high on the research agenda. In a GVC framework,
the demand for labor is affected by those industries that have
to compete against imports of final goods and in industries that
provide intermediate inputs. Foreign competition may induce a
change in the absolute number of workers or in the skills required.
For example, firms in developed countries may specialize in higher
quality high technology and high skills processes. Conversely,
off- shoring and international outsourcing are additional sources of
jobs for firms that are able to qualify as GVC suppliers.
WTO and IDE- JETRO (2011) show that in the Asia- Pacific
region, each country tends to specialize in exporting value- added
that is generated by job skills that represent their comparative
advantage (for example, Japan and the US are specializing
in high- skill and high cost type of labor) while importing goods
and services where they do not have such advantages from
other developing Asian countries, especially the PRC. Foster et
al. (2012), using WIOD data and a more formal methodology,
examine the GVC- linked evolution of the skill- structure of labor
demand for a sample of 18 countries.
The trade and environment nexus is another high- priority item
in the research agenda. The Eora MRIO Database project has
been developed with the objective of tracking the environmental
“footprint” of consumption across countries. As we shall see,
the “demand- side” approach to measuring trade in value- added
builds largely on methodologies developed to track back to
developing countries the source of CO
2
emissions of products
consumed in developed countries.
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 311
g: is an n*1 vector of the output of n industries within an economy.
A: is an n*n technical coefficients matrix; where
a
ij
is the ratio of inputs
from domestic industry i used in the output of industry j.
y: is an n*1 vector of nal demand for domestically produced goods
and services (nal demand includes consumption, investment and
exports).
A country’s total value- added can be split in two parts: one is the VA
embodied in goods and services absorbed domestically (consumption
and investment), the other is the VA embodied in its exports. Assuming
the homogeneity of products made for the domestic market and products
made for exports, total imports embodied directly and indirectly within
exports are given by:
Import content of exports 5
m*
(
1
2
A
)
2
1
*e,
where:
m: is a 1*n vector with components m
j
(the ratio of imports to output in
industry j)
e: is a n*1 vector of exports by industry to the rest of the world.
In the same way, one can estimate the total indirect and direct contribution
of exports to value- added by replacing the import vector m above with an
equivalent vector that shows the ratio of value- added to output (v). So, the
contribution of exports to total economy value- added is equal to:
VAE:v*
(
1
2
A
)
2
1
*e;
(1 – A)
–1
being the Leontief inverse matrix (L)
Before revising in the following sections some of the main indicators
that are derived from this basic relationship, it is important to highlight
some of the limitations that are related to the definition of the technical
coefficients matrix A. Those technical coefficients are derived by normal-
izing the intermediate coefficients Z
ij
by the value of total production
(a
ij
= Z
ij
/Q
j
); where Z
ij
is the intermediate consumption of products from
sector i by j (i and j being possibly in different countries) and Q
j
is the total
production of sector j.
These I–O coefficients present the direct requirements of inputs from i
for producing one unit of output of industry “j”. For example, to produce
one unit of output, sector 2 will require a
12
units from sector 1. The techni-
cal coefficients tell only part of the story of the productive chain. In order
to be able to produce the a
12
units demanded by sector 2, the productive
sector 1 will need inputs from other sectors. To satisfy this endogenous
demand created by one additional unit of output in sector 2, individual
firms in each other connected sector will also require inputs produced
312 Asia and global production networks
by suppliers operating from other sectors. And so on and so forth, as
the indirect demands generated at each step create in turn additional
requirements.
The feedback sequence resulting from the initial demand injection can
be obtained by the series
I 1 A 1 A
2
1 A
3
1 . . . 1 A
n
where I is an identity matrix representing the initial demand injection and
A
n
is the progressive impact of initial demands at the n
th
stage of the pro-
duction chain. When n tends to infinity, the series has a limit equal to L.
The coefficients of the Leontief Inverse measure the depth (intensity) of the
backward linkages between sectors. They describe entirely the direct and
indirect flows of intermediate products involved by the productive chains.
But the elegance of the algebraic formulation hides some messy statisti-
cal issues. Q
i
results from aggregating the production of all establishments
surveyed when establishing the supply and use tables, mixing large and
small firms. These firms may use different technologies and may therefore
require different types and/or quantity of inputs. The higher the produc-
tive heterogeneity (as happens in developing countries), the less represent-
ative the average a
ij
= Z
ij
/Q
j
will be. Additionally, Q
i
aggregates sales to
the domestic sectors (firms, households and administration) and exports.
It is well documented by the new “new” trade literature that, within each
industrial sector, exporting firms are usually the largest and the most tech-
nically advanced ones. Therefore, one unit of additional export is unlikely
to foster the same type of endogenous demand for intermediate inputs as
one unit of additional domestic consumption. Typically, in least advanced
countries, the multiplier effect through endogenous demand is low because
traditional producers use little intermediate inputs (labor intensive pro-
duction technologies) while most of the intermediate inputs required for
non- traditional exports will be satisfied by imports. This aggregation bias
has important implications when measuring trade in value- added and will
be discussed more in detail.
3.2.1 Vertical specialization
Hummels et al. (2001) define vertical- specialization trade as “the value
of imported intermediates embodied in a country’s exports”, or import
content of exports. VS measures the value of imports that is required to
produce one unit of exports. Intuitively (as we shall see, the issue is a bit
more complex), the domestic value- added embodied in exports (VAE)
is the difference between gross exports and VS. An additional defini-
tion is VS1, the value of exports that are embodied in a second country’s
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 313
export goods: “This occurs when the country exports goods that are
used as inputs into another country’s production of export goods.” The
first attempt at measuring vertical specialization was based on national
input– output matrices and was not subject to the above- mentioned
endogeneity issue. Daudin et al. (2006, 2011) and Johnson and Noguera
(2012) develop further those concepts to an international IO framework.
A subset of VS1 can actually return to the country in which the intermedi-
ate has been originally produced, that is, this country re- imports domestic
value- added in final goods (VS1*). Johnson and Noguera (2012) follow
similar lines and describe shipments from country i to j of final and inter-
mediate goods (embodied in country j in consumption) as “absorbed” (the
absorption state of the Markov chain described earlier in this chapter).
Shipments of country A to B which return back to country A are called
“reflected”. Shipments from A to B that are processed in country B and
afterwards sent to a third country C are called “re- directed”.
At this stage, and discounting the reflected part of exports, we can
define two types of domestic VA exports: for final demand ( fd) and for
intermediate (imd):
VAE
(
fd
)
:v*
(
I
2
A
)
2
1
*e
fd
and
VAE
(
imd
)
:v*
(
I
2
A
)
2
1
*e
imd
with
e
fd
1 e
imd
5 e
As we shall see,
VAE
(
imd
)
should be further refined in order to avoid
double counting and have a complete mapping of trade in value- added.
3.2.2 Full decomposition of gross exports
Koopman et al. (2012) develop a full decomposition of exports along
these concepts, and build a consistent accounting framework that allows
them to measure a country’s gross exports according to its various value-
added components. The net domestic value added content of exports is
composed of the following four elements (Figure 9.6):
(i) and (ii) The domestic value- added embodied either in final or inter-
mediate goods/services and directly absorbed and consumed
by the importing country. Those represent a strict bilateral
trade pattern, as in the traditional Ricardian model.
(iii) The domestic value- added contained in intermediates exported
to a country and re- exported to a third country as part of
a sale of goods or services. This represents a one- to- many
314 Asia and global production networks
country transfer of value- added, when the embodied content of
exported goods/services crosses borders more than once. This
component would not have existed in the absence of global
manufacturing, and is the source of trade creation from a trade
in tasks perspective (Baldwin and Robert- Nicoud, 2010).
(iv) The domestic value- added of exported goods/services which is
sent back to the country of value- added origin. Such a value-
added round- trip corresponds to the reected case in Johnson
and Noguera (2012).
The foreign value- added content of exports is similar to the VS index
and corresponds to the value- added of inputs that was imported in order to
produce intermediate or final goods/services to be exported. To avoid double
counting and maintain the identity in trade balance measured in gross or in
VA term, the domestic value- added sent back to its country of origin, or
reflected, should not be included in the estimate of value- added exports.
The identification of “double counting” is a complex “accounting
cum modelling” issue. From an accounting perspective, it has to do with
trade in intermediates that are embodied in other intermediate or final
goods/services, but not absorbed abroad. The issue is also conceptual.
When moving from a national to an international IO matrix, the part
Gross exports
Domestic value added content
(DC)
Foreign value added content
(FC)
Exported in final
goods and
services
(1)
Exported in
intermediates
to a first partner
country which
re-exports it to third
countries
(3)
Exported in
intermediates and
returned back to the
country of VA origin
(4)
Exported in
intermediates
(goods
and services)
(2)
Domestic value
added
in direct exports
(1) + (2)
Domestic value
added in
redirected exports
(3)
(5) FC embodied in
exported intermediates
(6) FC embodied in
exported final goods
and services
Double counting. VA
imported back by the
country of origin:
(a) in final goods and
services
(b) embodied in
intermediates
(c) pure double counting
(5b) Double counting in
intermediates flows
Source: Adapted from Koopman et al. (2012).
Figure 9.6 Decomposition of gross exports into their value added
components
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 315
of exports corresponding to intermediate inputs sent to industries in
other countries for further processing are not included in final demand
anymore. They are now endogenous to the global production process.
The proper treatment of the endogenous portion of exports has been
the source of some intense discussion in the expert community, as the
limitations mentioned in Oosterhaven and Stelder (2002) apply in some
cases (forecasting and simulation based on IIO models). Koopman et
al. (2012) solve the accounting issue by distinguishing two occurrences:
imported inputs used by a country to produce goods/services for export
but already counted as domestic value- added amount by another country;
domestic value- added content that returns home as imports but already
included in the value- added of the country itself. The duplicated elements
must be excluded from value- added exports to exclude double counting.
Double counting may, nevertheless, provide useful information on vertical
specialization (Box 9.4).
Table 9.3 presents a selection of results showing the decomposition of
gross exports for Asia- Pacific countries based on the OECD- WTO Trade
in Value Added Database (TiVA).
16
The average of the sampled countries
indicates the foreign content of gross exports (similar to the VS criteria)
increased from 24 percent to 32 percent between 1995 and 2008, showing
a greater integration of the countries in GVC trade. Ranked on the VS
criteria, Singapore is the most reliant on imported inputs for producing
her exports, Australia –with a rich natural resources endowment – being
at the other extreme of the sample. Interestingly, the PRC, far from being
the downstream final assembly point for consumer goods, is exporting a
high proportion of intermediate goods (see the column VA exported to
third country). VA returning home is quantitatively marginal, but it is a
good qualitative indicator of the back- and- forth trade typical of GVCs.
The PRC ranked first on this indicator for 2008, showing a huge increase
from 1995. The US is second (those indicators are computed on the basis
of all reporters, and the US value is clearly influenced by the close trade
relationship with Canada and Mexico).
3.2.3 The demand- side absorption approach
The previous approach entails complex calculation in order to avoid
double counting. The WIOD project turned the tables and looked at trade
flows from the final demand perspective. Reflecting a methodology previ-
ously used in environment economics to measure the CO
2
content imbed-
ded in consumption and track its domestic and foreign origin, Stehrer
(2012) measures the value- added of one country directly and indirectly
contained in final demand of another country. The final demand approach
has the advantage of looking at the issue from the exogenous side of the
316 Asia and global production networks
BOX 9.4 DOUBLE COUNTING: ISSUE OR
BLESSING?
One of the first motivations for measuring trade in value- added
was to eliminate double counting. Because the value of interme-
diate inputs is double- counted each time the product into which
the parts are embodied crosses a border, the sum of all customs
registers will over- estimate the actual economic content of physi-
cal trade flows. This bias is eliminated by accounting only the net
value aggregated at each step of the international value chain,
exactly in the same way national accountants discard the value of
intermediate transactions in the computation of the gross domes-
tic product. The new IMF Balance of Payments Manual (BPM6)
and the last revision of the UN System of National Accounts
(SNA, 2008) goes further and recommends that one ignore trade
in intermediates when no change of ownership takes place, as
it is often the case in GVCs, and record only the manufacturing
fees.
Yet, information on intermediate trade remains crucial for
understanding how supply chains actually work. With the excep-
tion of the last step of the production network, all GVC trade is in
intermediates. WTO (2013a) estimates that intermediates repre-
sent about 54 percent of global merchandise trade, excluding oil;
in the OECD countries, they represent 56 percent and 73 percent
of trade flows in goods and services, respectively (Miroudot et
al., 2009). Knowing the composition, origin and destination of the
flows of intermediate goods and services is key for understanding
the architecture and topological properties of regional and inter-
national value chains.
Koopman et al. (2012) provide a detailed structural analysis of
the trade in intermediate flows, identifying six categories of transac-
tions, two of them being “pure” double- counting. Their estimates of
double counting are particularly high for countries closely involved
in value chains. The PRC normal exports (products exported by
national firms) have a 3 percent incidence of such double counting
while processing trade exports (firms operating in export process-
ing zones) have a 10 percent incidence. The largest double count-
ing in their paper is found for Singapore with 22 percent. Malaysia
trade records 14 percent double counting while Indonesia, a
natural resources- based economy, has only 7 percent.
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 317
trade in value- added equation, avoiding endogeneity issues. The author
goes further and proposes that this should be the proper measure of trade
in value- added;
17
in an earlier paper of WIOD (Los et al., 2012), the two
concepts were called the “direct trade flow (DTF)” perspective (cor-
responding to the decomposition of exports and value- added in trade)
and the “global value chain (GVC)” perspective (for the foreign content
in a unit of consumption). This battle of denominations was closed by
Koopman et al. (2012) and Meng et al. (2012) who show that, properly
measured, the two approaches (gross exports decomposition and final
demand) lead to similar aggregated results.
Contrary to the previous approaches, which are supply- based and
focus on exports (irrespective of their use by the importing country), the
absorption approach relates to the demand side and estimates a country’s
value- added induced by its partners’ final demand. When analyzing trade
in value- added from the final demand side, the main building block is the
measure of value- added used by an economy to satisfy its final demand
but created in foreign countries. Foreign value- added can either come
directly from one partner country or may have been indirectly transferred
through several partner countries belonging to a same production chain.
Symmetrically (a trade statistician would say, using mirror statistics), the
exports of a country are defined as the domestic value- added exported
to satisfy the final demand from other countries (this corresponds to the
VAX definition of Johnson and Noguera, 2012).
3.2.4 Complementarity of the two approaches
At global level, the total trade measured from the supply side (exports)
and the (final) demand side give the same results. Meng et al. (2012) show
in a two country accounting framework that the demand- side approach
can be expressed through two types of exports of value- added: the first
component represents country value- added embodied in exports of final
goods and the second one is composed from VA embodied in trade in
Thus, double counting is well correlated with the “vertical spe-
cialization” index (VS). We see in Figure 9.8 that the incidence
of double counting may also help in identifying linear GVCs
(“snakes”) from hub- and- spoke ones (“spiders”). In other words,
far from being a nuisance because of double counting, trade in
intermediates provides very valuable information on the industrial
logic behind global production networks.
318
Table 9.3 Decomposition of gross exports of goods and services into their value- added components, 1995 and 2008 (%
of total gross exports)
Foreign value added
content (vertical
specialization)
Domestic value added (VA) content of gross exports
VA directly absorbed by
importer
a
VA exported to
third countries
b
VA sent back to country
of origin
b
Total
1995 2008 1995 2008 1995 2008 1995 2008 1995 2008
Singapore 46.7 53.1 39.2 25.5 13.8 21.1 0.3 0.3 53.3 46.9
Taipei,China 35.8 47.8 50.4 23.1 13.6 28.6 0.2 0.5 64.2 52.2
Republic of Korea 23.7 43.4 62.0 31.1 14.2 25.0 0.1 0.5 76.3 56.6
Philippines 30.9 41.7 52.4 27.0 16.6 31.1 0.0 0.2 69.1 58.3
Viet Nam 24.4 39.8 62.9 43.6 12.6 16.5 0.0 0.1 75.6 60.2
Malaysia 40.3 38.1 44.3 31.9 15.2 29.6 0.3 0.4 59.7 61.9
Thailand 29.8 37.8 58.1 43.4 12.0 18.7 0.1 0.2 70.2 62.2
Cambodia 26.0 36.1 56.3 59.1 17.8 4.8 0.0 0.0 74.0 63.9
People’s Republic of China 11.9 33.3 74.1 51.2 13.9 14.4 0.1 1.1 88.1 66.7
Hong Kong, China 40.6 29.1 48.0 41.8 11.3 29.1 0.1 0.1 59.4 70.9
India 9.6 23.7 76.1 53.8 14.2 22.3 0.0 0.1 90.4 76.3
New Zealand 17.4 21.4 69.3 59.0 13.3 19.5 0.0 0.0 82.6 78.6
Japan 6.8 19.4 70.5 49.5 22.4 30.7 0.2 0.4 93.2 80.6
Indonesia 14.7 17.4 66.4 50.7 18.8 31.8 0.1 0.1 85.3 82.6
United States 8.4 14.6 66.6 55.0 24.5 29.7 0.5 0.7 91.6 85.4
Australia 11.8 13.9 66.3 50.8 21.8 35.1 0.1 0.2 88.2 86.1
Notes:
PRC 5 People’s Republic of China.
a. One border crossing only.
b. Multiple border crossings.
Source: Based on OECD- WTO TiVA database.
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 319
intermediate goods and services. Degain et al. (2012) verify the result
applying both methods to the WIOD table 2007.
From a practitioner’s perspective, the actual “GVC”, or “trade in tasks”
perspective is perhaps better captured by the supply- side approach of export
decomposition. This opinion stems from the network approach presented
earlier in this chapter. Consider a simple example of a system of four coun-
tries (Figure 9.7). In the situation without fragmentation of production, all
value- added is produced in the same country of origin. Here, for example
(panel a), Japan (J) exports $100 of computers to US (U). In a distributed
production network (panel b), J retains the production of key components
(value of $50), outsources to Thailand (T) the production of hard disks
($20) and creates an affiliate in the PRC (C) that manufactures non- key
components and does the assembly (value- added of $30). The final product
is then shipped to U where it is consumed. The demand- side approach will
decompose U’s final demand according to C, J and T respective contribu-
tions, even when no trade took place between U and J or between U and T.
This has the advantage of showing how J and T’s productive activities
are influenced by U’s demand; something a traditional macroeconomic
model based on gross trade would have difficulties to track. From a trade
100
50
20
50
30
50
b) Value chaina) No fragmentation
20
100
100
100
C
C
J
J
U
U
T
Flow and value
of physical trade
Flow and value
of VA trade (demand-side)
T
Source: Elaborated by the author.
Figure 9.7 Imputed versus observed trade flows in value- added
320 Asia and global production networks
perspective, nevertheless, this creates two issues. One is that trade flows
between J and C and between T and C disappear from the measure though
they actually took place, while virtual ones are created (U and J, U and T)
that did not occur in reality. In other words, the demand approach creates
virtual bilateral flows that may not possibly exist in reality (due to physical
or political impediments, for example).
The other argument is analytical. Focusing on demand- side only may
blur our understanding of comparative advantages in trade in tasks and
bias the results of some classical indicators such as gravity models. Losing
the role of C as an intermediate step between T and U has implications
when it comes to understanding comparative advantages in a trade in
tasks environment. In a GVC T’s specialization is complementary with C
and both T and C are competitive with respect to J and U (from a compar-
ative advantage point of view) in their respective specializations. But there
is no certainty that T individually would have a comparative advantage in
the absence of C. For example, if Japan decides that computers sold to the
US will be assembled in Mexico instead of the PRC, the hard disks used
may come from Mexico or other places closer than Thailand. In other
words, it is possible that for T, international competitiveness is conditional
to supplying assembly lines in C.
From the topological perspective presented previously, this means
that not all connections in the network are possible or have independent
probabilities. Instead, the path trees of connections in GVC networks are
usually Bayesian: connection probabilities at each node are path depend-
ent and influenced by origin or ultimate destination. Translating probabil-
ities into “distances” or “trade resistances”, as in a gravity model where
the probability of observing a high value of trade between two countries
is inversely proportional to the distance separating them, we can say that
the resistance to trade between T and U is higher for direct flows than
triangular ones through C.
d
(
T,U
)
.
d
(
T,C
)
1
d
(
C,U
)
Thus, “distances” in trade in tasks do not define a metric from a topologi-
cal point of view.
18
From a gravity model perspective, it means that some direct connec-
tions from suppliers to customers are “longer” (costlier) than indirect
ones. Taking the US perspective in Figure 9.7, it may be cheaper to
import a hard- disk drive made in Thailand and imbedded in a computer
assembled in the PRC than importing it directly from nearby Mexico. But
as soon as the assembly point is not the PRC, Mexico’s hard disks may
become competitive. The choice of sourcing components is not determined
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 321
by the location of the final consumer, but depends on the cost of doing
business with each of the intermediate nodes.
As trade analysts are interested in understanding these costs and their
determinants (comparative advantage, competitiveness, trade policy, etc.),
they are more attentive to tracking the exports side, and its successive
steps, rather than simply identifying the foreign origin of domestic final
demand. It is therefore important to be able to keep track of all inter-
mediate steps and assign correctly the gross and net flows in the global
production network, even if it results in additional data compilation and
processing costs. Obviously, this is particularly relevant when supply
chains are of the “linear” or “snake” type (various successive intermedi-
ate suppliers aggregating value- added to a good) rather than the “star”
or “spider” type (a GVC organized as a hub and spikes, with various
suppliers sending separately their inputs for final assembly).
19
Comparing the bilateral flows of trade in value- added obtained from
the export side and the demand side, as well as physical flows, may provide
additional information on the topological structure of the GVC. The
amount of double counting is higher in a snake configuration, as shown
in Figure 9.8. In panel (a), C plays the role of a hub, a “spider” type, and
the amount of double counting (the difference between the sum of physical
flows and their VA content) is $70 ($170 of physical exports minus $100
of value- added). In panel (b), J exports first to T and the resulting good in
process is re- exported to C for further processing before its sale to U (in a
“snake” configuration, all operations are successive), then the amount of
double counting is $120 ($220 minus $100).
A series of other indicators can be calculated from the IIO trade in
value- added methodology. To cite a few:
Bilateral balance of trade: comparison of value- added versus gross
terms- based bilateral trade balances.
Sectoral contributions to value- added exports, showing the direct
and indirect contribution of each sector of the economy to the
exports of one given sector. This is particularly important in the case
of services, as they contribute to some 50 percent of “manufacture
exports” in industrialized countries.
Global value chain participation index; length of GVCs as measured
by APL (see Box 9.5).
Global value chain position index (relative length of upstream
versus the downstream part of the chain), as in De Backer and
Miroudot (2012).
Relative comparative advantage (RCA) based on gross and value-
added exports (incorporated in the OECD- WTO TiVA database).
322 Asia and global production networks
The list of possible indicators is much larger: on the basis of the interna-
tional input–output matrices such as WIOD or OECD- WTO’s TiVA that
form today’s backbone of trade in value- added indicators, it is possible to
adapt most traditional input–output connectedness indicators. The 2013
version of the OECD- WTO TiVA database displays up to 39 indicators
provided for 34 OECD countries and 23 non- OECD economies. Carlos-
Lopes et al. (2008) offer a list of 12 of such indicators, some of them dating
from the earliest years of input–output analysis. Miller and Blair (2009)
is an example of a classic textbook on input–output analysis that can be
revisited with a “trade in value- added mind”.
To provide an example of how TiVA revisits traditional indicators and
provides new insights, Figure 9.9 shows revealed comparative advantage
(RCA), comparing on a 45° diagram gross and value- added indicators for
machinery and transport equipment, one of the sectors most influenced
by GVCs. Countries very active in the downstream part of the value chain
(closest to final demand) have much higher RCA in gross values than in
value- added, and fall below the 45° line. This is the case of the PRC and
India in Asia, or Mexico in the Americas. On the contrary, countries will
100
50
50
70
50
30
50
b. Snake value chaina. Spider value chain
20
20
50
30
100
100
50
20
C
C
J
J
U
U
T
Flow and value
of physical trade
Flow and value
of VA trade (demand-side)
T
Source: Elaborated by the author.
Figure 9.8 Global value chains: snake and spider configurations
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 323
rank higher on the value- added indicator when firms are more upstream
(R&D, production of components). This is the case of Japan, Republic of
Korea and Taipei,China in Asia, or the US in the Americas. Indonesia’s
relative situation in gross or value- added terms does not change much,
which may be explained, either by a relatively low degree of GVC par-
ticipation and/or a balanced mix of upstream and downstream exporting
firms.
3.2.5 Limitations of the trade in value- added approach
The statistical limitations can be defined in two broad categories: data
gaps and aggregation bias. The value- added approach suffers from all
the shortcomings that afflict compiling intermediate trade flow statistics.
Those flows are critical in “gluing” together the various industries and
countries that are modelled in the IIO, but their estimation remains too
often a guesswork exercise where statisticians have to ponder the relative
merits of diverging sources and impute missing data. This is particularly
true for trade in intermediate services. An additional challenge is the
attribution of flows by sector of origin and sectors of destination (a “one
to many” relationship). Identifying the sector of origin is a relatively
easy task for good producing sectors, using the International Standard
Industrial Classification (ISIC) and the SITC correspondence tables, but
more of an issue for trade in services.
20
Sectors of destinations are allocated
Taipei,China
Republic of Korea
Mexico
Japan
People's Republic of
China
United States
Germany
Poland
France
Sweden
India
United Kingdom
Canada
Romania
Turkey
Italy
Denmark
Brazil
Netherlands
Indonesia
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
1.2
1.4
1.6
1.8
2
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8
RCA indicator value added statistics
RCA indicator, gross trade statistics
Source: Based on OECD- WTO TiVA database.
Figure 9.9 Revealed comparative advantage in machinery and transport
equipment (gross versus value added, 2007)
324 Asia and global production networks
BOX 9.5 LENGTH, STRENGTH OF SUPPLY
CHAINS AND RELATIVE POSITIONS OF
TRADE PARTNERS
The conventional input–output approach to supply chains focuses
principally on measuring the strength of interconnectedness,
based on the traditional demand- pull impact derived from techni-
cal coefficients. For trade analysts, the “length” of linkages also
becomes important for mapping the geometry of supply chains.
Length is most often estimated using the concept of average
propagation length (APL) developed in Dietzenbacher et al.
(2005).
a
It is defined as:
APL
j2 i
5 1*
a
ij
(
l
ij
2 d
ij
)
1 2*
[
A
2
]
ij
(
l
ij
2 d
ij
)
1 3*
[
A
3
]
ij
(
l
ij
2 d
ij
)
1
c
where l
ij
is Leontief inverse coefficients,[IA]
−1
, d
ij
is a Kronecker
delta product which is d
ij
51 if i5j and d
ij
50 otherwise.
APL is the weighted average of the number of production
stages, where an impact from industry j goes through until it ulti-
mately reaches industry i, using the strength of an impact at each
stage as a weight. APL was applied at the international level in
Dietzenbacher and Romero (2007) for major European countries
and by Inomata (2008) for Asia. Building on the APL methodol-
ogy, Escaith and Inomata (2013) develop a graph showing the
evolution of the length and upstreamness of regional supply
chains in Asia- Pacific between 1985 and 2005.
Most economies have moved towards the northeast corner of
the graph, indicating that the length of their supply chains link-
ages increased between 1985 and 2005. The PRC, in particular,
shows a large increase in the length of the supply chains in which
it participates (considering both its domestic supply chains and
the overseas production networks). The exceptions to the trend
are the US and Taipei,China, while Japan did not change much.
The northwest- southeast diagonal distinguishes the relative posi-
tion of each economy within the regional supply chains, as deter-
mined by the ratio of forward and backward APL. The US and
Japan, the most advanced economies in the Asia- Pacific region,
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 325
are located in the upstream position. The USA moved down-
ward during the period and swapped its position with Republic of
Korea. The PRC stays in the downstream segment of the regional
supply chains, which reflects the country’s position as a “final
assembler” of the regional products.
Note:
a
Using a different method developed by Fally (2011), De Backer and
Miroudot (2012) develop an index of “distance to final demand” for OECD.
People’s Rep. of
China
1985
PRC 2005
Indonesia
Japan
Rep. of
Korea
Malaysia
Taipei,China
Philippines
Singapore
Thailand
United States
2.7
2.9
3.1
3.3
3.5
3.7
3.9
2.7 2.9 3.1 3.3 3.5 3.7 3.9
Forward APL
Backward APL
Upstreamness
Downstreamness
Longer supply chains
Shorter supply chains
20051985
Source: Escaith and Inomata (2013).
Figure 9.10 Change of relative positions in the regional supply
chains, 1985–2005
326 Asia and global production networks
on the basis of the import coefficients of SUT tables and some proportion-
ality assumption with respect to the countries of origin. In other words, if
the agricultural sector’s consumption of imported chemicals represents 10
percent of the country’s imports for this particular input, then 10 percent
of all bilateral import flows of chemical inputs will be allocated to the
agricultural sector. This “proportionality” assumption may not reflect the
actual origin when the quality of intermediate products required is very
different across the importing sectors, and that countries of origin special-
ize in particular qualities. Moreover, additional proportional imputations
may be required when the SUT are not detailed enough by products, or
simply not available.
Once flows of intermediates are allocated by sectors, the resulting IIO
needs to be balanced, which raises complex issues of compatibilities. Some
data conflicts can be solved using a priori inferences. For example, the
multi- regional Eora tables, based on a mix of hard data and algorithmic
imputations, are built by giving prominence to national input- output
tables, followed by the UN Statistical Division series of national accounts
and COMTRADE data.
21
Giving priority to national accounts (as is
usually the case in order to satisfy balancing conditions) means that there
are many occurrences where trade data are misrepresented. Even if prec-
edence rules are established, many imputations rely ultimately on some
value judgment. Timmer (2012) provides a detailed review of the numer-
ous steps that eventually lead to the construction of the IIO table produced
by the WIOD project. OECD (2013) discusses how the national input–
output tables behind the TiVA database have been harmonized and linked
together TiVA; Degain et al. (2013) compare three of the main databases
used so far in the literature (GTAP, OECD- WTO’s TiVA and WIOD).
Diachronic comparison of time series of IIO indicators also confronts
the issue of price variations, in particular the impact of exchange rate.
This complicates the chronological analysis of trade in VA indicators.
WIOD provides chained time- series of its IIO tables that allow computing
indicators in last- year’s prices. For long term comparison Diakantoni and
Escaith (2012) delineate a heuristic method to identify where exchange
rate adjustments are taking place.
22
Most analytical issues are related to aggregation. I mentioned two of
them: firm heterogeneity and product differentiation. An aggregation bias
is created when very different firms (and very different underlying GVCs)
are aggregated together into a single sector. In developing countries’ pro-
duction technologies the use of imported inputs may differ widely between
firms producing for exports and firms producing only for the domestic
market. This is well documented in the case of the PRC and Mexico, as we
shall see in the next section.
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 327
BOX 9.6 TOPOLOGICAL LIMITATIONS OF
INTERNATIONAL INPUT–OUTPUT
MATRICES
Despite their analytical advantages, international input–output
matrices have topological limitations from a GVC perspective,
most if not all of them due to aggregation biases and short-
comings in the underlying formal statistical properties (i.e., from
a probabilistic point of view). For example, APL computes the
average length using [a
ij
] as probabilities for transiting from i to
j Input–output matrices define a Markovian process where the
transaction probabilities depend only on the current position of
the node [i] (a sector in a given country), but not on the manner
a node gathered its inputs from other markets. We saw that in
a GVC, suppliers are not undifferentiated as assumed, and the
choice of suppliers may itself be conditioned by the market of final
destination. High quality suppliers will be preferred if the market of
final destination is of high income. From a statistical perspective,
transition probabilities along the supply chain are not independ-
ent (Markovian), but conditioned by the market of final destination
(Bayesian). A Markovian representation of the global network is
only the expected value of the realization of a large number of
mutually independent Bayesian trees. This is perfectly acceptable
when APL is used for descriptive (ex post) reasons, but may be
subject to serious aggregation bias if it is used to forecast or simu-
late the strength and length of a country/sector specific (supply or
demand) shock. The “cascading” effect of a Markovian process
will spread and dilute the shock, while a Bayesian approach
would have called for a more concentrated effect.
The issue is better described through a simple example. A
textile factory in Morocco imports cotton to produce fabric that
is then cut and sown according to the specification of a Spanish
fashion designer and exported. The shirts exported to the Italian
market use long fiber cotton imported from Egypt, and T- shirts for
the Portuguese tourism market use cotton imported from Mali.
Due to the Spanish designer’s price and quality constraints, the
two types of cotton are not substitutable. If a supply shock affects
agriculture in Egypt, only the shirt production will be affected; sim-
ilarly, if demand for T- shirts increases only Malian producers will
benefit from the surge in fabric production. Yet an input–output
328 Asia and global production networks
Product differentiation (quality, specifications) is a more complex issue
and may actually reduce the possibility of sourcing inputs from all pos-
sible trade partners. This is particularly true when intermediate products
are GVC specific. To take an example, sand is processed into silicon chips,
which are assembled according to specific references. While sand and chips
are both intermediate inputs, they respond to different market logics. Sand
is a commodity: as long as it satisfies some physical specifications, its
origin is not really important. Computer chips are much more specific
and a chip made by a company according to very precise specifications
required by the customer (e.g., a computer firm) may not be substitutable
by other apparently similar products. The market powers associated with
those two intermediate goods are very different.
23
Implications, either in terms of the topological properties of the under-
lying network (Bayesian versus Markovian approaches) or in terms of
economic analysis and market power, are very different when inputs
are commodities or process- specific (see Box 9.6). While international
matrix will not be able to differentiate between those two differ-
entiated value- chains and will aggregate them into a single set
of coefficients. If the sales of the Moroccan factory split equally
between Italy and Portugal, a 100 percent increase in demand
for T- shirts exported to Portugal will translate, equivocally, to a
50 percent increase in Egyptian cotton (upward bias in measuring
the strength of the demand shock) and a 50 percent increase in
Malian cotton (downward bias, respectively).
Similarly, in an input–output perspective, the strength of back-
wards dependence at different stages (nodes) tends to decline
as the “distance”, as measured by the number of production
steps (nodes), increases. Yet, this property is not consistent with
the micro- economic and supply chain management views of the
trade. In our previous example, the trade path is strictly deter-
mined by the market destination: if the final node of the graph is
Italy (alt. Portugal), then the initial node is Egypt (alt. Mali). The
path between nodes is not independent of initial or final states.
From a topological perspective, the GVC network is closer to a
Bayesian process than the Markovian setting that is implied by a
usual input–output matrix. The local probability distribution asso-
ciated with a given node is not independent of the final node (if the
GVC is demand- driven), or of some particular intermediate node
in the network (if the GVC is producer driven).
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 329
input–output matrices can be differentiated to capture firm heterogeneity
within a same industry (using a business register, as in the next section),
they are not well equipped to deal with the heterogeneity in intermedi-
ate goods in a same product classification. As we saw previously in the
chapter on mapping intermediate trade, these aspects have to be analyzed
using the graph and network analysis tools on traditional trade statistics,
after applying ad- hoc filters to discriminate products according to their
specificity.
3.3 Linking Trade and Business Statistics
Input–output data, despite their great systemic value, are too aggregated to
capture the business reality behind trade in global value chains. Sturgeon
(2013) presents a state- of- the- art discussion on firm- level data require-
ments and data compilation strategies based on EUROSTAT experience.
Some developing countries involved in GVCs have also developed appro-
priate statistical tools, be they large emerging economies such as the PRC
or Mexico, or smaller countries such as Costa Rica. Obtaining firm- level
data on global value chains requires dedicated surveys, something official
statisticians look at with caution, considering the implementation cost,
as well as the statistical fatigue of responding firms. Fortunately, there
are cost- effective approaches at gathering relevant information without
increasing the statistical burden on responding firms.
Data already collected by national administrations are able to provide a
detailed view of the trade activity generated by each firm. Administrative
registers gather a lot of information on firms’ activities, their corporate
structure, their labor force and productive characteristics. By linking those
administrative data with customs statistics, it is therefore possible to cross-
check several existing databases and build very detailed maps of trade
activity by firm characteristics. EUROSTAT has spearheaded a project
called “Trade by Enterprise Characteristics” to understand the specific
profiles of firms that actively engage into trade. This institutional initiative
mirrors other initiatives from academia that burgeoned in response to the
new “new” trade theory, which had a clear focus on empirical issues and
micro- data. For example, Bernard et al. (2005) look at US data to provide
an ID card of firms according to their trading activity. More recently, the
Chinese Academy of Sciences (2013) has released detailed information on
export activity by type of firms.
These “trade by enterprise characteristics” (TEC) are so far restricted
to national or custom union areas, because one needs to use a single iden-
tification for the firm across all administrative registers. In addition, con-
fidentiality aspects constrain their dissemination. A second best solution
330 Asia and global production networks
is provided by disaggregating sectorial IIO by firm characteristics. De la
Cruz et al. (2011) undertake such an exercise on Mexico; Tang et al. (2013)
combine IO tables and firm census data to disaggregate Chinese GVC
trade by firm size and type of ownership.
4. CONCLUSION: SEARCHING FOR AN
INTEGRATING FRAMEWORK
Up to very recently, trade statistics were considered as a mature field by
the profession; this sleeping beauty has recently awakened to transform
herself into a vibrant teenager, curious to explore new areas, but yet
unsure of the best avenues. While global production networks have been
prevalent since the mid- 1980s, the interest in this new form of globaliza-
tion had remained largely circumscribed to the academic circle. The finan-
cial crisis of 2008–2009 and the resulting great trade collapse determined
a new demand from policy makers for adequate statistical information
regarding this phenomenon. The interest comes from various corners of
policy making; from trade policy with the “Made in the World Initiative”
launched by the WTO to the global governance and development objec-
tives expressed by the G- 20, the United Nations and regional institutions
such as the ADB.
The objective of the present chapter was to tentatively map what we
needed to know, while recognizing that there remain plenty of known
unknowns and unknown unknowns. The starting point was to address
the measurement issues by looking at the analytical and policy questions.
Transactions between firms operating from different countries create
new interdependencies between the national economies, with economic,
financial, social and environmental dimensions. Statisticians have risen
to the measurement challenge by making the best use of existing data.
Using traditional trade statistics in innovative ways allows mapping more
finely the World Trade Network, highlighting the specificities of trade in
intermediate goods and the inter- industry linkages connecting produc-
tion networks. Linking intermediary trade flows with national accounts
data to construct international input–output tables and measuring the
value- added content of trade were part of this effort.
We have so far only scraped the surface of the issue. The available sta-
tistics that the global trade in value- added databases provide today are
estimates at macro- sectoral level. Having this information is already a
great step in the right direction and helped in demonstrating that under-
standing the economic relevance of trade in today’s globalized economy
required new instruments and new methodologies. The results so far help
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 331
in understanding the big picture, resizing the relative weight of services
and manufactures and the real size of bilateral trade imbalances. Trade in
value- added also helps understanding the complex relationships between
trade in tasks and job creation.
The existing databases on trade in value- added still suffer from serious
shortcomings. While they bring very valuable information on the relation-
ship between international trade and economic development, existing
databases developed on official data (AIO, OECD- WTO, WIOD) still
need to cover many more developing and least developed countries, an
effort hampered by data restrictions. So far, the incorporation of most
developing countries in international IO tables results from the use of
non- official estimates (GTAP) or algorithmic imputations (Eora) that
may ignore the actual specificities of these countries. Extending the cover-
age of developing and least developed countries using official data should
therefore be a priority.
From an analytical perspective, the indicators obtained so far suffer
from sizable aggregation biases. These impair their use if one wishes to
go beyond descriptive and exploratory statistics and look into causality
factors and confirmatory analysis, using the sophisticated econometric
models favored by the modern (new “new”) trade theory. The new statisti-
cal frontier lies in the development of micro- databases to fully capture the
heterogeneity of firms that are active in these global value chains and com-
plements the trade data with information on firm characteristics, includ-
ing the financial and corporate dimensions. The compilation of business
data for international trade analysis calls for a revision of the existing
classifications, in particular a better understanding of what are the “tasks”
or “business functions” that are subject to outsourcing and eventually
determine “trade in value- added”.
The momentum created by this renewed interest was strong enough
for calling the attention of the highest supra- national governing body,
the United Nations Statistical Conference, which is in charge of setting
international standards that are then applied by official statisticians.
24
Without prejudging of the future developments in this field of statistics,
trends point toward integrating micro- economic data, including business
registers, labor and financial information, using the national accounts as
the organizing and integrating framework. The relevant data would be
interrelated into a “satellite account” of the external sector, linked to the
national accounts as far as residents are concerned, but also interlinked
with other trading partners. A good example of such a statistical frame-
work is provided by the satellite accounts for tourism, a branch of trade in
services with complex interactions between many different economic and
social actors.
332 Asia and global production networks
Installing such accounts in the routine of national statistical institutes
will be challenging for most developing countries, as it is very demand-
ing in terms of the quality of administrative data and dedicated business
surveys. It is nevertheless in these countries that the need for developing
such an information system is the greatest, considering the relevance
between global value chains, trade and development. On the other hand,
the difficulty of the task should not be overstated, because most trade
activity in developing countries is concentrated in a few firms, greatly
simplifying the data compilation.
NOTES
* I thank G. Daudin, B. Ferrarini, D. Hummels and anonymous editors for their com-
ments on preliminary drafts. I also recognize the contribution of my colleagues at
WTO, IDE- JETRO, OECD, UN, USITC, WIOD and the other researchers with whom
I worked on “trade in value- added” in the past few years. I learned a lot from them,
but most probably not enough to avoid errors and omissions in this chapter. Those, as
well as any opinions expressed here, remain mine and do not reflect any position of the
WTO or its members.
1. Other economists contest the claim for paradigm shift and show that comparative
advantages in trade in tasks can be analyzed through available mainstream models
(Baldwin and Robert- Nicoud, 2010).
2. TiVA, launched by OECD and WTO in January 2013, builds on a series of works by
IDE- JETRO, US- ITC and the WIOD project.
3. Vitali et al. (2011) present an analysis of intra- firm transaction within a large corpo-
ration, illustrating how graph and network theories can help in mapping a hierarchy
across these relationships.
4. As pointed out by Feenstra (2004), recent work in trade economics has been more
empirical than theoretical, and about accounting for global trade flows rather than
about testing hypotheses related to trade.
5. National accounts would prefer to say compensation of employees and operating
surplus (or labor and capital compensations) and net indirect taxes, after subsidies.
6. Final goods are purchased for consumption or investment purposes. In practice, the
boundaries are not clear. Gross investment includes changes in inventories, while final
demand in national accounts covers total exports (of final and intermediate goods).
International IO accountants separate exports of intermediate products from final
demand, but the treatment of inventories remains an empirical issue.
7. See, for a relatively nontechnical example, Hansen et al. (2011); Goyal (2007) develops
a more formal approach of the economic theory of networks.
8. V. Leontief, as early as 1950s, had already identified the potential of IO models for
trade analysis. In 1953, Leontief published ‘Domestic production and foreign trade;
the American capital position re- examined,’ resulting in the famed Leontief paradox.
Later, he promoted the construction of international IO matrices to model economic
interdependencies.
9. Some countries, such as the US, record imports free alongside board (FAB) or free on
board (FOB), but this remains exceptional and most countries favor a cost, insurance
and freight (cif) recording for customs purposes, as it increases the statistical basis on
which tax duties are levied.
10. It is usual, in the social network literature, to call these indicators “metrics” albeit, from
a strict mathematical perspective, they seldom define a true metrical space.
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 333
11. See, for example, Hansen et al. (2011) for a non- technical presentation of the main
indicators used in this section.
12. The present section draws heavily on work done at OECD and WTO in co- operation
with IDE- JETRO and USITC; see OECD- WTO (2012) and Degain et al. (2012) for the
main technical conclusions of this research program.
13. Compensation of employees and operating surplus are primary factor income, and net
indirect taxes after subsidies affect market pricing.
14. An introduction on international input–output can be found in the ‘Explanatory Notes’
of Inomata and Uchida (2009).
15. OECD- WTO (2012).
16. For more detailed review of TiVA indicators, see Ahmad (2013) and OECD (2013).
17. At more or less the same time, and independently of this debate, Sancho (2012) also
criticized the use of input–output multipliers on gross output. Yet this criticism is not
relevant when looking at ex- post data, as is usually done when measuring trade in
value- added, because all endogenous effects have taken place.
18. Many researchers refer to trade in VA as a “new metric”. Actually, trade in VA does not
fulfill any of the necessary conditions for defining a metric space. Not even d (U, U) =0
is verified, as we may have reflexive trade (exported VA returning home, as in Table 9.3).
19. See Goyal (2007) for a review of the network economics implications, and Baldwin and
Venables (2010) for a trade perspective.
20. OECD has been developing a Bilateral Trade Database by industry and end- use cat-
egory, where values and quantities of imports and exports are compiled according to
product classifications and by partner countries. A similar Bilateral Trade in Services
database, using detailed EBOPS data and the total services bilateral trade data is in
prospect.
21. Eora is a project to estimate international input–output tables in order to assist envi-
ronmental research, in particular footprint assessments of international trade; differing
from WIOD or OECD- WTO TiVA, which use only official data, the aim of Eora is
to cover as many countries as possible, relying on a mix of hard data and algorithmic
procedures (Kanemoto et al., 2011).
22. Based on economic assumptions (the law of one- price and long- term adjustment of
exchange rates to their purchasing parity), the heuristic is only indicative. Applied on
Asian IIOs, the authors show that exchange rate corrections induced by the Asian crisis
of 1997 had strong medium- term impact for the calculation of the indicators.
23. The aggregation bias relates not only to heterogeneity of quality within alternative
sources, but may also reflect the monopolistic nature of GVCs: the sourcing inputs may
be predetermined in an actual GVC, privileging intra- firm transactions (see Milberg
and Winkler, 2013).
24. A report of the Statistical Commission (UNSC, 2013) provides a comprehensive review
of the work undertaken so far at international level, and it proposes the development of
an overreaching framework for ensuring consistency in methodology, data compilation
and data dissemination.
REFERENCES
Ahmad, N. (2013),‘Estimating trade in value- added: why and how?’, in D. Elms
and P. Low (eds), Global Value Chains in a Changing World, Fung Global
Institute, Nanyang Technological University, and World Trade Organization.
Baldwin, R. (2006), ‘Globalisation: the great unbundling (s)’, paper contribution
to the project Globalisation Challenges for Europe and Finland, Economic
Council of Finland.
Baldwin, R. and F. Robert- Nicoud (2010), ‘Trade- in- goods and trade- in- tasks: an
334 Asia and global production networks
integrating framework’, NBER Working Paper No. 15882, Cambridge, MA:
National Bureau of Economic Research.
Baldwin, R. and A. Venables (2010), ‘Relocating the value chain: offshoring
and agglomeration in the global economy’, NBER Working Paper No. 16611,
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Bernard, A.B., J.B. Jensen and P.K. Schott (2005),‘Importers, exporters,
and multinationals: a portrait of firms in the US that trade goods’, NBER
Working Paper No. 11404, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Carlos- Lopes, J., J. Dias and J. Ferreira do Amaral (2008), ‘Assessing economic
complexity in some OECD countries with input–output based measures’,
International Conference on Policy Modelling, Berlin.
Chinese Academy of Sciences (2013), ‘Interim report on global value chains and
the value- added estimates in China’s trade’, June.
Coe, N., P. Dicken and M. Hess (2008), ‘Global production networks: realizing the
potential’, Journal of Economic Geography, 8, 271–295.
Daudin, G., P. Monperrus- Veroni, Ch. Rifflart and D. Schweisguth (2006), ‘Le
commerce extérieur en valeur ajoutée’, Revue de l’OFCE 98, 129–165.
Daudin, G., Ch. Rifflart and D. Schweisguth (2011), ‘Who produces for whom in
the world economy?’, Canadian Journal of Economics, 44, 1403–1437.
De Backer, K. and S. Miroudot (2012), ‘Mapping global value chains’, WIOD
Conference “Causes and Consequences of Globalization”, Groningen, The
Netherlands, 24–26 April.
De La Cruz, J., R. Koopman, Z. Wang and S.- J. Wei (2011), ‘Estimating foreign
value- added in Mexico’s manufacturing exports’, U.S. International Trade
Commission, Office of Economics Working Paper No. 2011–04A.
Degain, Ch., H. Escaith and A. Maurer (2012), ‘Comparison of methodolo-
gies to estimate trade in value- added terms’, WTO- MIWI, draft note, mimeo,
September.
Degain, Ch., L. Jones, Z. Wang and L. Xin (2013), ‘The similarities and differences
among the three major global inter- country input–output databases and their
implications for trade in value- added estimates’, 16th GTAP Conference on
Global Economic Analysis, June.
Diakantoni, A. and H. Escaith (2012), ‘Reassessing effective protection rates in
a trade in tasks perspective: evolution of trade policy in factory Asia’, WTO
Working Paper ERSD 2012–11.
Dietzenbacher, E. and I. Romero (2007), ‘Production chains in an interre-
gional framework: identification by means of average propagation lengths’,
International Regional Science Review, 30, 362.
Dietzenbacher, E., I. Romero and N.S. Bosma (2005), ‘Using average propagation
lengths to identify production chains in the Andalusian economy’, Estudios de
Economia Aplicada, 23, 405–422.
Elms, D. and P. Low (eds) (2013), Global Value Chains in a Changing World,
Fung Global Institute, Nanyang Technological University, and World Trade
Organization.
Escaith, H. and F. Gonguet (2011), ‘International supply chains as real transmis-
sion channels of financial shocks’, Journal of Financial Transformation, 31,
83–97.
Escaith, H. and S. Inomata (2013),‘Geometry of global value chains in East Asia:
the role of industrial networks and trade policies’, in D. Elms and P. Low (eds),
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 335
Global Value Chains in a Changing World, Fung Global Institute, Nanyang
Technological University, and World Trade Organization.
Ethier, W.J (1979), ‘Internationally decreasing costs and world trade’, Journal of
International Economics, 9, 1–24.
Fally, T. (2011), ‘On the fragmentation of production in the US’, presentation,
University of Colorado- Boulder, July.
Feenstra, R. (2004), Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence, Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
Feenstra R.C. and G.H. Hanson (1996), ‘Globalisation, outsourcing and wage
inequality’, American Economic Review, 86, 240–245.
Ferrarini, B. (2011), ‘Mapping vertical trade’, ADB Working Paper Series 263,
Manila: Asian Development Bank.
Flores, M. and M. Vaillant (2011), ‘Global value chains and export sophistication
in Latin America’, Inter- American Development Bank- Integration and Trade
Journal, 32, 15–35.
Foster, N., R. Stehrer, M. Timmer and G. de Vries (2012), ‘Offshoring and the
skill structure of labour demand’, World Input–Output Database Working
Paper Nr. 6.
Geoffrion A. and R. Powers (1995), ’20 Years of strategic distribution system
design: an evolutionary perspective’, Interfaces, 25, 105–127.
Gereffi, G. and T. Sturgeon (2013),‘Global value chain- oriented industrial policy:
the role of emerging economies’, in D. Elms and P. Low (eds), Global Value
Chains in a Changing World, Fung Global Institute, Nanyang Technological
University, and World Trade Organization.
Goyal, S. (2007), Connections: An Introduction to the Economics of Networks,
Princeton University Press.
Grossman, G.M. and E. Rossi- Hansberg (2006), ‘Trading tasks: A simple theory
of offshoring’, NBER Working Paper No. 12721, Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Hansen, D., B. Shneiderman and M. Smith (2011), Analyzing Social Media Networks
with NodeXL: Insights from a Connected World, Elsevier.
Hatzichronoglou, T. (1997), ‘Revision of the high- technology sector and product
classification’, OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers, No.
1997/02.
Hidalgo, C., B. Klinger, R. Hausmann and A. László Barabási (2007), ‘The
product space conditions the development of nations’, Science, 317, 482–487.
Hummels, D., Jun Ishii and Kei- Mu Yi (2001), ‘The nature and growth of
vertical specialization in world trade’, Journal of International Economics, 54,
75–96.
Inomata, S. (2008), ‘Average propagation lengths: a new concept of the “distance”
between industries, with an application to the Asia- Pacific region’, Sangyo-
Renkan, 16–1 (in Japanese), Japan: Pan- Pacific Association of Input–Output
Studies.
Inomata, S. (2011), ‘Explanatory notes’, in S. Inomata (ed.), Asia Beyond the
Global Economic Crisis: The Transmission Mechanism of Financial Shocks,
Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar, in association
with IDE- JETRO.
Inomata, S. and Y. Uchida (2009), ‘Asia beyond the crisis: visions from interna-
tional input–output analyses’, IDE Spot Survey No. 31.
Johnson, R.C. and G. Noguera (2012), ‘Accounting for intermediates: production
336 Asia and global production networks
sharing and trade in value added’, Journal of International Economics, 86,
224–236.
Kanemoto, K., M. Lenzen, A. Geschke and D. Moran (2011), ‘Building Eora:
a global multi- region input output model at high country and sector’, 19th
International Input- Output Conference.
Koopman, R., W. Powers, Z. Wang and S.- J. Wei (2012), ‘Tracing value- added
and double counting in gross exports’, NBER Working Paper No. 18579,
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Koopmans, T.C. (1947), ‘Measurement without theory’, Review of Economics and
Statistics, 29, 161–172.
Krugman, P.R. (1979), ‘Increasing returns, monopolistic competition, and inter-
national trade’, Journal of International Economics, 9, 469–479.
Lall, S., J. Weiss and J. Zhang (2005), ‘The “sophistication” of exports: a new
measure of product characteristics’, Queen Elizabeth House Working Paper
Series 123, Oxford University.
Lanz, R., S. Miroudot and H.K. Nordås (2011), ‘Trade in tasks’, OECD Trade
Policy Working Papers, No. 117.Leontief, W. (1953), ‘Domestic production and
foreign trade; the American capital position re- examined’, Proceedings of the
American Philosophical Society, 97 (4), 28 September, 332–349.
Los, B., E. Dietzenbacher, R. Stehrer, M.P. Timmer and G. de Vries (2012), ‘Trade
performance in internationally fragmented production networks: concepts and
measures”, World Input–Output Database Working Paper Nr. 11.
Maurer, A. and Ch. Degain (2010), ‘Globalization and trade flows: what you see is
not what you get!’, WTO Staff Working Paper No. 2010–12.
Melitz, M. (2003), ‘The impact of trade on intra- industry reallocations and aggre-
gate industry productivity’, Econometrica, 71, 1695–1725.
Meng, B., Y. Fang and N. Yamano (2012), ‘Measuring global value chains and
regional economic integration: an international input–output approach’, IDE
Discussion Paper 362.
Milberg, W. and D. Winkler (2013), Outsourcing Economics: Global Value Chains
in Capitalist Development, Cambridge University Press.
Miller, R. and P. Blair (2009), Input–Output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions
(second edition), Cambridge University Press.
Miroudot, S., R. Lanz and A. Ragoussis (2009), ‘Trade in intermediate goods and
services’, OECD Trade Policy Papers 93.
Ng, F., and A. Yeats (1999), ‘Production sharing in East Asia: who does what for
whom, and why?’, Policy Research Working Paper Series 2197, Washington,
DC: The World Bank.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co- operation and Development) (2005),
Handbook on Economic Globalization Indicators, Paris.
OECD (2011), ISIC REV. 3 Technology Intensity Definition: Classification of
Manufacturing Industries into Categories Based on R&D Intensities, Paris.
OECD (2013), Interconnected Economies: Benefitting from Global Value Chains,
Paris.
OECD- World Trade Organization (WTO) (2012), ‘Note on measuring trade in
value added’, e- document (WTO- MIWI website).
Oosterhaven, J. and D. Stelder (2002), ‘Net multipliers avoid exaggerating
impacts: with a biregional illustration for the Dutch transportation sector’,
Journal of Regional Science, 42, 533–543.
Oxley, L., P. Walker, D. Thorns and H. Wang (2008). ‘The knowledge economy/
Mapping global value chains and measuring trade in tasks 337
society: the latest example of “measurement without theory”?’, The Journal of
Philosophical Economics, 2, 20–54.
Park, A., G. Nayyar and P. Low (2013), ‘Supply chains perspective and issues: a
literature review’, Fung Global Institute and World Trade Organization.
Porter, M.E. (1985), Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining Superior
Performance, The Free Press: New York.
Rauch, J.E. (1999), ‘Networks versus markets in international trade’, Journal of
International Economics, 48, 7–35.
Rifflart, Ch. and D. Schweisguth (2013), ‘Draft report on new measures of interna-
tional trade’, in European Framework for Measuring Progress, e- Frame.
Sancho, F. (2012), ‘Some conceptual difficulties regarding net multipliers’, Depart-
ment of Economics Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, mimeo.
Stehrer, R. (2012), ‘Trade in value added and the value added of trade’, World
Input–Output Working Paper No 8.
Sturgeon, T. (2013), ‘Global value chains and economic globalization: towards a
new measurement framework’, EUROSTAT.
Sturgeon, T. and O. Memedovic (2010), ‘Mapping global value chains: intermedi-
ate goods trade and structural change in the world economy’, UNIDO Working
Paper 05, Vienna: UNIDO.
Tang, K.K. and A. Wagner (2010), ‘Measuring globalization using weighted network
indexes’, paper presented at the 31st General Conference of the International
Association for Research in Income and Wealth, St. Gallen, Switzerland, August.
Tang, H., F. Wang and Z. Wang (2013), ‘The domestic segment of global supply
chain in China under state capitalism’, paper presented at the International
Conference on Global Value Chains and Structural Adjustments, Tsinghua
University, Beijing, June.
Timmer, M. (2012), ‘The World Input–Output Database: contents, sources and
methods’, World Input–Output Database Working Paper Number 10.
UNCTAD (2013), World Investment Report 2013: Global Value Chains: Investment
and Trade for Development, Geneva.
UNSC (2013), International Trade Statistics: Report to the Secretary General,
United Nations Statistical Commission, 44th session.
Vitali, S., J.B. Glattfelder and S. Battiston (2011), ‘The network of global corpo-
rate control’, PLoS ONE 6(10).
World Trade Organization (WTO) (2013a), World Trade Report 2013: Factors
Shaping the Future of World Trade, Geneva.
WTO (2013b), International Trade Statistics, annual statistical yearbook, Geneva.
WTO (2008), World Trade Report 2008: Trade in a Globalizing World, Geneva.
WTO and IDE- JETRO (2011), Trade Patterns and Global Value Chains in East
Asia: From Trade in Goods to Trade in Tasks, Geneva and Tokyo.
WTR (World Trade Report) (2013), Factors Shaping The World Trade, Geneva:
World Trade Organization.
Yeats, A. (2001), ‘Just how big is global production sharing?’, in S. Arndt and
H. Kierzkowski (eds), Fragmentation: New Production Patterns in the World
Economy, New York: Oxford University Press.
338
10. The development and future of
Factory Asia*
Richard Baldwin and Rikard Forslid
1. INTRODUCTION
Like a gigantic, impossibly complex but wonderfully efficient factory,
East Asia churns out a vast array of manufactured goods with
world- beating price- quality ratios. But this is not a series of national
efforts. Manufacturing processes that used to be performed in single fac-
tories (mostly in Japan and Republic of Korea) have been fractionalized
and dispersed across the region creating what Baldwin (2006) called
‘Factory Asia’.
This chapter looks at the underlying interconnected processes that
have led to the development of Factory Asia namely the fractionali-
zation of the manufacturing process into stages and the dispersion of
these stages around Asia. It does so by developing the TOSP (tasks,
occupations, stages, products) framework that was informally intro-
duced in Baldwin (2012). The TOSP framework views the production
of goods as the performance of a range of tasks that are organized into
occupations (collection of tasks) and stages (collections of occupations).
Typically offshoring occurs at the level of stages rather than tasks or
occupation.
This framework is then used to examine the likely effects of improv-
ing information and communication technology (ICT) on the future
of Factory Asia. Two dimensions are distinguished: fractionalization
of the production process (slicing up the value chain), and their spatial
dispersion (offshoring stages).
A key premise of this chapter is that it is a trap to think of Factory Asia
from the perspective of traditional trade theory. It is tempting to think of
the fractionalization as simply a further step in the century’s long march
from autarky to free trade. After all, the fast lane of Factory Asia involves
the offshoring of low- skill intensive stage to nations that are abundant
in low- skill labor while knowledge- intensive stages remain in nations
that are well endowed with knowledge workers. A natural, but incorrect,
The development and future of Factory Asia 339
way to think of this is as nations’ shifting resources to their comparative
advantage sectors.
As this misthinking is pervasive, the rest of the introduction is devoted
to contrast the old globalization paradigm which views the process as
driven by the steady lowering of trade costs – with an alternative narrative
that views globalization as two processes rather than one.
1.1 Globalization as Two Unbundlings
Globalization is often viewed as linear – a progressive integration of
national economies driven by lower technical and manmade trade costs. In
trade economists’ jargon, globalization is basically the move from autarky
to free trade done slowly. The sharp trends in Figure 10.1 suggest that this
is a mistake.
Globalization was associated with an agglomeration of economic activ-
ity in what used to be called the industrialized nations. From 1820 to 1988,
the G7’s share of global output rose from 22 percent to 67 percent. Since
then, the share has plummeted and is now back to the level it first attained
in 1900. About the same time, the world saw a massive shift in manufac-
turing activity from G7 nations to a handful of developing nations that
1820,
22%
1988,
67%
2010,
50%
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
1820
1839
1858
1877
1896
1915
1934
1953
1972
1991
2010
G7 nations' share of global GDP,
1820–2010
1990,
65%
G7,
47%
3%
PRC,
19%
5%
6 risers,
9%
RoW
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
1970
1974
1978
1982
1986
1990
1994
1998
2002
2006
2010
G7 nations' share of global
manufacturing, 1970–2010
Note: 6 risers = Republic of Korea, India, Indonesia, Thailand, Turkey, and Poland; G7
= Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, United Kingdom and United States of America;
PRC = People’s Republic of China; RoW = rest of the world.
Source: Authors’ elaboration of data from unstats.un.org and Maddison’s database.
Figure 10.1 Globalization: one process or two?
340 Asia and global production networks
have come to be called Emerging Economies. In the two decades from
1970 to 1990, the G7’s manufacturing share dropped from 71 percent to
65 percent. The subsequent two decades saw it plummet to 50 percent. The
share shifts, however, were not generalized. Only seven nations saw their
share of manufacturing rise by more than one- half of one percentage point
(the People’s Republic of China (PRC), the Republic of Korea, India,
Indonesia, Thailand, Turkey and Poland). Plainly we are in a new phase of
globalization – a phase that is distinct from earlier phases. There are many
names for this new globalization paradigm – the global value chain (GVC)
revolution, fragmentation, trade in tasks, etc.
On the back of this prima facie evidence, it would seem we need two
processes to explain globalization’s main outlines, not one. Falling trade
cost will not cover it. In a 2006 paper for the Finnish Prime Minister’s
office, Baldwin (2006) characterizes this as globalization’s two great
unbundlings. The first unbundling – up to the mid or late 1980s is the tra-
ditional, linear process driven by lower trade costs. The second unbundling
was driven by better information and communication technology. The
first unbundling allowed consumption and production to be separated by
great distances but production stages remained bundled in factories and
industrial districts. The ICT revolution sparked the second unbundling by
unbundling the factories. Improved ICT made it economical for stages of
production formerly performed in a rich- nation factory to be unbundled
and dispersed to low- wage nations.
The development of Factory Asia was one of the first manifestations of
the second unbundling, although a similar development occurred in North
America and Europe.
2. FACTS: THE DEVELOPMENT OF FACTORY ASIA
We use here the Trade in Value- Added (TiVA) database, which contains
the value- added in goods and services of a county’s export (and import).
The joint OECD–WTO Trade in Value- Added (TiVA) project traces the
value- added by each industry and country in the production chain, and
allocates the value- added to these source industries and countries.
One of the most striking features of Factory Asia is the very rapid
growth of exports from emerging East Asian economies measured in
either gross or value- added (VA) terms. By ‘gross exports’ we mean the
standard, customs- based numbers. By value- added exports, we mean the
domestic value- added contained in a nation’s gross exports. The difference
is that the value- added figures net out the foreign value- added embedded
in gross exports. For example, if Mexico exports a car that contains a US
The development and future of Factory Asia 341
engine, the gross export is the value of the whole car; the value- added
export is just the value that was added in Mexico.
As Figure 10.2 shows, the growth has been quite uneven. In general,
emerging markets have seen higher growth with the PRC, Cambodia, and
Viet Nam showing spectacular growth (although from very low bases in
the latter two cases).
For comparison, we include the export growth figures for the G7 and a
handful of emerging markets that are known to be active in outsourcing and
GVCs. A point we will explore more below is that there seems to be a con-
nection between the magnitude of the growth and the size of the gap between
gross and value- added exports (a rough measure of supply- chain trade).
The commonality of emerging markets’ rapid export growth hides an
important distinction. Some of these nations – like Brazil and the Russian
Federation achieve high export growth on the back of the booming
demand for commodities. Others are doing it via manufactured goods.
0% 500% 1000%
East Asians
JPN
TAP
HKG
PHI
KOR
MAL
INO
THA
SIN
BRU
CAM
PRC
VIE
G7 nations
FRA
ITA
CAN
USA
UKG
GER
0% 500% 1000%
Other EMs in GVCs
POR
SVN
MEX
TUR
CZE
HUN
POL
SVK
ROU
Primary exporters
ZAF
AUS
CHL
NOR
BRU
RUS
BRA
SAU
Gross export growth
VA export growth
Gross export growth
VA export growth
Notes:
EM = emerging market; G7 = Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, United Kingdom
and United States of America; GVC = global value chain.
Country codes are listed in Appendix Table 10A.1.
Source: TiVA database with authors’ calculations.
Figure 10.2 Total export growth, 1995–2009, various nations, gross and
value- added
342 Asia and global production networks
To provide hints as to the sources of the growth, Figure 10.3 shows the
growth decomposition by broad sector focusing on primary exports,
light manufactured exports, heavy manufactured exports, and service
exports. The left panel shows a wide diversity among East Southeast Asian
(EA) nations. Some nations – such as Brunei Darussalam, Viet Nam, and
Cambodia have seen their natural resource based exports account for sub-
stantial fractions of their total export growth. For most, however, the key
driver was manufactured exports. Only in three economies (Hong Kong,
China; Singapore and Japan) have service exports played a large role in
VA export growth.
The role of commodity exports has been smaller in the emerging
markets involved in Factory North America (Mexico), and Factory
Europe (Poland, Turkey, etc.). The commonality is that manufacturing
exports account for the lion’s share of the growth often two- thirds or
more.
–40%
–20%
0%
20%
40%
60%
80%
100%
PHI
TAP
HKG
KOR
SIN
JPN
PRC
THA
INO
MAL
CAM
VIE
BRU
Value-added export growth
composition, East Asia
Primary
Light manufacturing
Heavy manufacturing
Services
Primary
Light manufacturing
Heavy manufacturing
Services
–40%
–20%
0%
20%
40%
60%
80%
100%
CZE
POL
SVN
HUN
SVK
POL
TUR
ROU
MEX
Value-added export growth
composition, other emerging
markets in global value chains
Note: Country codes are listed in Appendix Table 10A.1.
Source: TiVA database with authors’ calculations.
Figure 10.3 Decomposition of value- added export growth by broad sector,
1995–2009
The development and future of Factory Asia 343
2.1 Connection to Supply- chain Trade
A property of fast growers that rely on manufacturers is that they seem to
be linking- up to global supply chains to a much larger extent. This section
presents prima facie evidence that this link is indeed important for many
of the East Asian nations.
The measure of supply- chain trade involvement we use is the share of
re- exported intermediates (REI), that is, imported intermediates that are
re- exported either as parts and components, or embedded in final goods.
Our aim is to explore the connection between increases in this measure
of supply chain trade (SCT) and increases in the domestic value- added
contained in exports. In both cases, we look at the percentage increase
from 1995 to 2009 (which is the full span of the TiVA database). The first
look at the raw data is not encouraging. Figure 10.4 shows the scatter plot
of the change in 57 nations’ SCT measure in 18 different sectors against
the same nations’ growth of domestic value- added in exports in the same
sectors. The overall correlation is unclear.
The second unbundling logic, however, suggests that the correlation
should differ greatly for ‘headquarters (HQ) economies’ and ‘factories
economies’ as well as across sectors (since production unbundling has
–500%
0%
500%
1000%
1500%
2000%
2500%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
Growth in domestic value added in exports
Re-exported intermediates as a % of total intermediate imports
Re-exported intermediates as a % of total intermediate
imports versus growth in domestic value-added in exports
Source: TiVA database with authors’ calculations.
Figure 10.4 Growth in supply- chain participation and domestic value-
added in exports
344 Asia and global production networks
not happened equally in all sectors). Once we separate the East Asia
nations from the others, a positive relationship looks much more plausi-
ble. Indeed, Figure 10.5 shows that a positive link seems to hold for other
nations involved in supply- chain trade (those in Factory North America
and Factory Europe). The link is completely missing for G5 nations, the
headquarters economies, and is driven by outliers in the large economies
outside of Asia for other emerging markets.
When we look at sectors – pooling across of nations – the positive asso-
ciation is clear in some sectors but not in others (Figure 10.6). It is par-
ticularly clear in the machinery sectors, electrical and optical equipment,
transportation equipment, and machinery and equipment not elsewhere
classified (nec).
The last cut of the data highlights the growth correlation between
supply- chain participation and VA export growth by country group and by
sector (Figure 10.7). Here a couple of points stand out. First, the PRC and
Viet Nam are frequently outliers with big positive growth in both meas-
ures. Second, East Asian nations seem to systematically have more positive
links between the two measures than the other nations. This, however, is
less true in the classic outsourcing sectors such as textiles and machinery of
various sorts. Indeed in transportation, the correlation of the East Asian
nations and other factory economies (Other SCTers) is not at all clear.
2.2 Evolution of Factory Asia
Data for the early days of Factory Asia are difficult to come by. One
rough indicator that does reach back to the 1960s is a simple intra- industry
trade index (IIT) (Brülhart 2009). The idea here is that two- way trade in
similar products that is either North- South, or South- South is likely to be
largely supply- chain trade, i.e. two- way trade in parts and components.
Plainly this is a crude measure, but it is transparent, widely understood
and available for most nations going back to the early 1960s.
Figure 10.8 shows the paths of Japan’s and the Republic of Korea’s
IIT with each of seven Association of Southeast Asian Nation (ASEAN)
economies. The first salient point is that Japan’s exchange with the other
Asian nations has been growing since the 1960s. In the early days, much
of this was in microelectronics (Grunwald and Flamm, 1985). Japan’s IIT
with three of the big ASEAN economies Malaysia, Thailand and the
Philippines – took off at about the same time, i.e. mid- to late- 1980s. The
sharp rise in IIT with Indonesia and Viet Nam came a decade later. For
Indonesia (which is still a big commodity exporter), the rise was much
less marked than for the others. Lao People’s Democratic Republic and
Cambodia have not really joined the Japanese supply chains according
The development and future of Factory Asia 345
–500%
0%
500%
1000%
1500%
2000%
2500%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
Value added export growth
Re-exported intermediates as a
% of total intermediate imports
East Asian nations
–500%
0%
500%
1000%
1500%
2000%
2500%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
Value added export growth
Re-exported intermediates as a
% of total intermediate imports
Other emerging markets
–500%
0%
500%
1000%
1500%
2000%
2500%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
Value added export growth
Re-exported intermediates as a
% of total intermediate imports
Group of 5
–500%
0%
500%
1000%
1500%
2000%
2500%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
Value added export growth
Re-exported intermediates as a
% of total intermediate imports
Other factory economies
Note: East Asian nations = China, People’s Rep. of, Indonesia, Korea, Rep. of, Malaysia,
Philippines, Taipei,China, Thailand and Viet Nam; Group of 5 = France, Germany, Japan,
United Kingdom and United States of America; other factory economies = Hungary,
Mexico, Poland, Slovakia and Turkey; other emerging markets = Brazil, Canada, India,
South Africa and Russian Federation.
Source: TiVA database with authors’calculations.
Figure 10.5 Supply chain participation and value- added exports, by
nation groups
346 Asia and global production networks
VIE
PHI
PRC
INO
KOR
THA
MAL
TAP
USA
GER
FRA
UKG
JPN
TUR
SVK
POL
HUN
MEX
IND
BRA
ZAF
RUS
CAN
–200%
800%
1800%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
REI growth
VA export growth
01T05: Agriculture, hunting, forestry
and fishing
VIE
PHI
PRC
INO
KOR
THA
MAL
TAP
USA
GER
FRA
UKG
JPN
TUR
SVK
POL
HUN
MEX
IND
BRA
ZAF
RUS
CAN
–200%
300%
800%
1300%
1800%
2300%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
REI growth
VA export growth
10T14: Mining and quarrying
VIE
PHI PRC
INO
KOR
THA
MAL
TAP
USA
GER
UKG
JPN
TUR
SVK
POL
HUN
MEX
IND
BRA
ZAF
RUS
CAN
–200%
800%
1800%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
REI growth
VA export growth
15T16: Food products, beverages
and tobacco
VIE
PHI
PRC
INO
KOR
THA
MALTAP
USA
GER
FRA
UKG
JPN
TUR
SVK
POL
HUN
MEX
IND
BRA
ZAF
RUS
CAN
–200%
800%
1800%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
REI growth
VA export growth
17T19: Textiles, textile products,
leather and footwear
VIE
PHI
PRC
INO
KOR
THA
MAL
TAP
USA
GER
FRA
UKG
JPN
TUR
SVK
POL
HUN
MEX
IND
BRA
ZAF
RUS
CAN
–200%
800%
1800%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
REI growth
VA export growth
20T22: Wood, paper, paper
products, printing and publishing
VIE
PHI
PRC
INO
KOR
THA
MAL
TAP
USA
GERFRA
UKG
JPN
TUR
SVK
POL
HUN
MEX
IND
BRA
ZAF
RUS
CAN
–200%
800%
1800%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
REI growth
VA export growth
23T26: Chemicals and non–metallic
mineral products
VIE
PHI
PRC
INO
KOR
THA
MAL
TAP
USA
GER
FRA
UKG
JPN
TUR
SVK
POL
HUN
MEX
IND
BRA
ZAF
RUS
CAN
–200%
800%
1800%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
REI growth
VA export growth
27T28: Basic metals and fabricated
metal products
VIE
PHI
PRC
INO
KOR
THA
MAL
TAP
USA
GER
FRA
UKG
JPN
TUR
SVK
POL
HUN
MEX
IND
BRA
ZAF
RUS
CAN
–200%
300%
800%
1300%
1800%
2300%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
REI growth
VA export growth
29: Machinery and equipment, nec
VIE
PHI
PRC
INO
KOR
THA
MAL
TAP
USA
GER
FRA
UKG
JPN
TUR
SVK
POL
HUN
MEX
IND
BRA
ZAF
RUS
CAN
–200%
800%
1800%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
REI growth
VA export growth
30T33: Electrical and optical
equipment
VIE
PHI
PRC
INO
KOR
THA
MAL
TAP
USA
GER
FRA
UKG
JPN
TUR
SVK
POL
HUN
MEX
IND
BRA
ZAF
RUS
CAN
–200%
300%
800%
1300%
1800%
2300%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
REI growth
VA export growth
34T35: Transport equipment
Notes:
Country codes are listed in Appendix Table 10A.1.
nec = not elsewhere classified; REI = re- exported intermediates; VA = value- added.
Source: TiVA database with authors’ calculations.
Figure 10.6 Supply chain participation and value- added exports, by all
nation groups by sectors
The development and future of Factory Asia 347
VIE
PRC
INO
THA
MAL
KOR
TAP
PHI
–200%
300%
800%
1300%
1800%
2300%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
REI growth
VA export growth
34T35: Transport equipment
VIE
PRC
INO
THA
MAL
KOR
TAPPHI
–200%
300%
800%
1300%
1800%
2300%
–50% 0% 50% 100% 150%
REI growth
VA export growth
17T19: Textiles, leather and footwear
VIE
PRC INO
THA
MAL
KOR
TAP
PHI
–200%
300%
800%
1300%
1800%
2300%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300% 400% 500%
REI growth
VA export growth
15T16: Food products, beverages and
tobacco
VIE
PRC
INO
THA
MAL
KOR
TAP
PHI
–200%
300%
800%
1300%
1800%
2300%
–50% 0% 50% 100% 150% 200%
REI growth
VA export growth
20T22: Wood, paper, printing and publishing
VIE
PRC
INO
THA
MAL
KOR
TAP
PHI
–200%
300%
800%
1300%
1800%
2300%
–50% 0% 50% 100% 150%
REI growth
VA export growth
23T26: Chemicals and non–metallic
mineral products
VIE
PRC
INO
THA
MAL
KOR
TAP
PHI
–200%
300%
800%
1300%
1800%
2300%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
REI growth
VA export growth
27T28: Basic metals and fabricated
metal products
VIE
PRC
INO
THA
MAL
KOR
TAP
PHI
–200%
300%
800%
1300%
1800%
2300%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300%
REI growth
VA export growth
29: Machinery and equipment, nec
VIE
PRC
INO
THA
MAL
KOR
TAP
PHI
–200%
300%
800%
1300%
1800%
2300%
–100% 0% 100% 200% 300% 400%
REI growth
VA export growth
30T33: Electrical and optical equipment
East Asia Other factory economies
Group of 5 Other emerging markets
Notes:
nec = not elsewhere classified; REI = re- exported intermediates; VA = value- added.
Follows country codes list in Appendix Table 10A.1.
Source: TiVA database with authors’ calculations.
Figure 10.7 Supply chain participation and value- added export growth, by
sector and country group
348 Asia and global production networks
0%
5%
10%
15%
20%
25%
30%
35%
40%
45%
50%
1962
1966
1970
1974
1978
1982
1986
1990
1994
1998
2002
2006
2010
Japan’s bilateral intra-industry
trade with ASEAN
0%
5%
10%
15%
20%
25%
30%
35%
40%
45%
50%
1962
1966
1970
1974
1978
1982
1986
1990
1994
1998
2002
2006
2010
Republic of Korea’s bilateral
intra-industry trade with ASEAN
INO
CAM
LAO
MAL
PHI
THA
VIE
INO
CAM
LAO
MAL
PHI
THA
VIE
Note: Country codes are listed in Appendix Table 10A.1.
Source: Author’s calculations on COMTRADE data.
Figure 10.8 Japan’s and the Republic of Korea’s bilateral intra- industry
trade with ASEAN, 1962–2012
0%
5%
10%
15%
20%
25%
30%
35%
40%
45%
50%
PRC's bilateral intra-industry
trade with ASEAN
INO
CAM
LAO
MAL
PHI
THA
VIE
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
ASEAN's bilateral intra-
industry trade with ASEAN
INO
CAM
LAO
MAL
PHI
THA
VIE
1962
1966
1970
1974
1978
1982
1986
1990
1994
1998
2002
2006
2010
1962
1966
1970
1974
1978
1982
1986
1990
1994
1998
2002
2006
2010
Note: Country codes are listed in Appendix Table 10A.1.
Source: Author’s calculations on COMTRADE data.
Figure 10.9 PRC’s and each ASEAN’s bilateral intra- industry trade with
ASEAN, 1962–2012
The development and future of Factory Asia 349
to this indicator. For the Republic of Korea, the timing is similar but the
engagement with ASEAN economies is muted compared to Japan.
Figure 10.9 shows the IIT proxy for Factory Asia participation for
the PRC with each of seven ASEAN economies and for each ASEAN
with the others. What we see is that PRC’s bilateral IIT with Thailand
and Malaysia jumped in the mid- 1980s, but it did not start until the early
1990s with Indonesia and the Philippines. The IIT measure slopes up from
the later 1990s for Viet Nam but does not really take off until the early
2000s. Cambodia’s IIT with PRC has taken off only in the 2010s. As for
the ASEANs among themselves, we see a similar timing. The ‘big four’
ASEANs, Thailand, Malaysia, Indonesia and the Philippines, see their
IIT scores jump in the mid- 1980s. Viet Nam’s jump is delayed till the late
1990s with a significant acceleration in the 2000s.
More direct evidence comes from the IDE- JETRO international input–
output table. This shows the country of origin of imported manufactured
goods purchased by the manufacturing sector of each East Asian economy.
Table 10.1 has three panels corresponding to the shape of Factory Asia in
1985, 1990 and 2000.
The top panel shows the situation in 1985 when Factory Asia was very
simple. With the exception of Singapore, East Asian nations sourced their
imported manufactured inputs from Japan and the rest of the world all
the rows are dominated by zeros except those of Japan and the rest of the
world (mainly the US and Europe). By 1990 (second panel), it was more
complex: ‘Triangle trade’ still dominated the picture with the low- wage
nations (first five columns) buying inputs from Japan and the rest of the
world but providing no inputs in return. Now, however, Japan is not the
only headquarters economy. Taipei,China, the Republic of Korea, and
Hong Kong, China experienced their own hollowing- out phases and new
triangle trade appears. This new triangle trade involves the shipment of
parts from the new HQ economies to the ‘factory economies’ (the PRC
and the advanced ASEANs, Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines and
Thailand). This can be seen from the emergence of new non- zero entries in
the rows for Taipei,China, the Republic of Korea and Singapore.
By 2000, Factory Asia was really complex. Firms based in the ‘factory
economies’ began to source parts from other factory economies rather
than from the HQ economy alone. In particular, Thailand, Malaysia and
the PRC became important suppliers of parts to other ‘factory econo-
mies’ including each other. In short, the input–output matrix went from
simple triangle trade to a much more complex situation where the ‘factory
economies’ were both makers and buyers of parts and components.
This rise of the PRC position in the Matrix between 1990 and 2000 is
especially noteworthy. At the beginning of the decade, it neither bought
350
Table 10.1 Widening and deepening of the Asian manufacturing matrix, 1985, 1990, 2000 (%)
PRC Indonesia Malaysia Philippines Thailand Singapore Taipei,China Republic of
Korea
Japan
1985
Indonesia 8
Malaysia 16
Philippines 0
Thailand 0
PRC 2 14
Taipei,China 3
Republic of Korea
Singapore 3 7
Japan 3 12 14 4 9 12 7 8
Rest of the world 15 19 19 14 11 10 16 8
1990
Indonesia
Malaysia 5
Philippines
Thailand
PRC 3
Taipei,China 3 4 3 3
Republic of Korea 2 2
Singapore 7 2 3
Japan 8 10 8 14 18 10 8
Rest of the world 8 23 20 21 22 44 17 13 5
351
2000
Indonesia 2
Malaysia 3 4 12 2
Philippines
Thailand 4 3 3
PRC 2 3 4 5 2
Taipei,China 5 5 3 3
Republic of Korea 2 3 4 8 3 4 4
Singapore 13 6 4
Japan 2 7 15 20 16 19 14 7
Rest of the world 4 16 20 20 17 38 15 11 4
Notes:
PRC 5 People’s Republic of China.
Percentage share of manufactured inputs bought by column nation’s manufacturing sector from the row nation; numbers less than 2% are zeroed
out; own- nation purchases are also zeroed out.
The columns would sum to 100% if we had included each nation’s supply of inputs to its own manufactured sector (a number that is often greater
than 50%) and if we had not zeroed out the low numbers (less than 2%).
Source: IDE- JETRO, Asian input–output matrix (7 sectors) for 1985, 1990 and 2000; see, for example, www.ide.go.jp/English/Publish /Books/
Sds/082.html.
352 Asia and global production networks
nor sold much manufactured inputs in East Asia. By the end of the decade,
we see many entries for the Chinese column (which shows its purchase
pattern) and the Chinese row (which shows which nations depend a lot on
inputs from the PRC). The flourishing of intra- ASEAN trade is also clear
from the comparison of 1990 and 2000.
The message of Table 10.1 is clear. By 2000, the competitiveness of
manufacturing firms in East Asia depended in a serious way on the
smooth functioning of regional trade. A disruption of trade between, say,
Malaysia and the PRC, could cause serious problems for Japanese and
Korean firms trying to sell in the US.
3. ECONOMICS OF SUPPLY- CHAIN UNBUNDLING
Globalization’s second unbundling shifted the locus of globalization from
sectors to stages of production. This requires an analytic focus on supply
chains. The economics of this change is best looked at by decomposing it
into two phenomena: fractionalization and dispersion.
Fractionalization concerns the unbundling of supply chains into
finer stages of production.
Dispersion concerns the geographic unbundling of stages.
The two are linked in so far as the organization of stages may be crafted
with dispersion, i.e. offshoring, in mind. This section considers them in
turn and their interlinks.
3.1 Supply Chain Unbundling: The Functional Dimension
A prime assumption behind our conceptualization of Factory Asia is that
the ICT revolution triggered the second unbundling and this resulted in
Factory Asia. The main avenue of investigation is thus to understand how
ICT improvements fostered production unbundling. Here we start with
fractionalization, putting off issues of dispersion (offshoring) temporarily.
To this end, it is useful to view a firm’s supply chain at four levels of
aggregation (Figure 10.10):
1. Tasks: This is the list of everything that must get done to produce
value for the corporation; the list includes all pre- fabrication and
post- fabrication services.
2. Occupations: One natural intermediate aggregation of tasks is an
‘occupation’ – the group of tasks performed by an individual worker.
The development and future of Factory Asia 353
3. Stages: Stages are defined as a collection of occupations that are
performed in close proximity due to the need for face- to- face interac-
tion, fragility of the partially processed goods, etc. This is a critical
level of aggregation since supply chain internationalization typically
involves the offshoring of stages rather than individual occupations or
individual tasks.
4. Products: The product is the supply chain’s output broadly viewed.
3.1.1 Optimal tasks per occupation and occupations per stage
With this aggregation scheme in mind, consider the economics of the
optimal:
1. Tasks per occupation; and
2. Occupations per stage.
Adam Smith illustrated the first issue with an example an 18th- century
pin factory where making a pin involved twelve distinct ‘tasks’, or what
Smith called ‘operations’. The full list of tasks/operations was: drawing
out the wire, straightening the wire, cutting the wire, sharpening the pointy
end, grinding the top end, making the pinhead (which itself involves three
distinct tasks/operations), attaching the pinhead, whitening the completed
pin, and putting the pins into the packaging.
Smith reported that pin factory managers had workers specialize in
particular tasks. Workers did not make pins; they performed particular
The TOSP Framework
Tasks:
Stages:
Product:
Occupations:
Occupation
Product
Stage
Stage
A
B C D E F G H I J K L
Occupation Occupation Occupation Occupation
Source: Authors’ illustration.
Figure 10.10 Tasks, occupations, stages and products – the TOSP
framework
354 Asia and global production networks
sets of tasks. This allowed each worker to get really good at his or her
assigned task. The downside of splitting up tasks is the difficulty of coor-
dinating the whole process. This is the fundamental trade- off we focus
on – the benefit of specialization versus the cost of coordination. Our key
trade- off differs fundamentally from Costinot (2009) and Bloom et al.
(2009); see Box 10.1.
BOX 10.1 RELATED THEORETICAL
FRAMEWORKS IN THE LITERATURE
The Costinot (2009) model looks at optimal ‘team size’ (akin to
our stages) that turns on a very different trade- off, namely spe-
cialization versus risk. Big teams allow workers to specialize in
particular tasks and this lowers average time cost. Big teams,
however, are assumed to be riskier.
Specifically, the model assumes an exogenous probability that
each worker will fail to complete the assigned task. To avoid risk
pooling which would obviate all the analysis and results the
paper adopts a series of strong assumptions. First no worker can
help any other; a failure in any task is a failure in all tasks, so more
workers mean more failure. Second, there can be no inventory that
would smooth over task- level failures. Third, the firm cannot reduce
the probability of failure with managers a la Garicano (2000).
While specialization- versus- risk is the fundamental trade- off
in the model, the paper discusses this trade- off as if it were a
specialization- versus- transaction- costs trade- off.
a
That is, the
discussion simply asserts that the failure- risk is due to contracting
problems, and then it simply asserts that contracting problems are
transaction costs.
Bloom et al. (2009) also model the team size choice based on a
trade- off that is quite different to ours. Drawing on the seminal work
by Garicano (2000), they focus on firm hierarchy, where production
requires problems to be solved and hierarchy is a way of econo-
mizing on workers’ problem- solving- training. Their core trade- off
is between spending more to train workers to solve problems by
themselves, and spending more on managers who are not directly
productive but who have the knowledge to solve all problems.
Note:
a
The independent and identically distributed nature of the risk is adopted
for technical reasons, namely to convexify outcomes in a way that allows the
authors to work in a general setting.
The development and future of Factory Asia 355
Fractionalization and improved communication technology versus informa-
tion technology Since we are addressing the history and future of Factory
Asia, we focus on how ICT developments alter fractionalization. Here the
important point is that ICT affects the optimal division of labor via two
channels, as Bloom et al. (2009) have stressed.
First, communication and organizational technologies call them
coordination technologies (CT) for short lower the marginal cost
of coordination. Intuitively, better CT will make it easier to slice up
production processes into more stages, and will make it easier to dis-
perse stages internationally. Thus CT will tend to foster the current
trends in Asia toward more vertical specialization, more offshoring,
more foreign direct investment and more intra- industry trade.
Second, information technology (IT) lowers the marginal benefit
to specialization; think of how robots make it easier for individual
workers to master more tasks without loss of efficiency.
3D printing is the extreme where IT allows a single worker to
perform all tasks simply by operating one machine. For example
Japanese industry is a leading user of industrial robots. Without
these machines far more stages of production would have been
offshored to low- skill abundant neighbors.
Plainly, CT and IT cut in opposite directions. Better CT favors greater
fractionalization by making it cheaper; better IT discourages it by making
it less necessary.
1
To explain and explore these effects in greater detail and
with greater precision of thought, we present a one- line sketch model of
optimal fractionalization.
3.1.2 Functional unbundling: a basic model
To crystalize thinking about our specialization- versus- coordination
trade-off, this subsection provides a simple model that allows us to be
more precise about the basic trade- off between specialization gains versus
coordination costs, as well as the very different effects that better CT and
IT have on supply chain fractionalization. We work in a partial equilib-
rium setting since when firms make these choices, they are likely to ignore
the impact of their decisions on labor and product markets. Likewise, we
initially work in a closed economy to separate the organization issues from
the offshoring issues. Even though they are ultimately linked, intuition is
served by first dealing with them separately.
One factor, one- tier organization Consider a firm with a constant-
returns- to- scale process whereby producing a good requires performance
356 Asia and global production networks
of a given list of tasks. To be concrete, view this as a continuum of tasks
that we arbitrarily list along the range from zero to unity. The tasks are
performed using homogenous labor and there is, in the simplest model,
only one organizational choice the number of occupations into which the
tasks are organized. Stages are left out of the analysis for the time being.
The problem is to assign tasks to occupations optimally. In principle
this assignment would involve a matching of task- types to worker- types.
Even with homogenous workers the assignment problem could be complex
if the degree of task- level efficiency depended upon the group of tasks
assigned per worker. For example, it would be reasonable to assume that
a worker would gain more efficiency by specializing in related tasks – say,
painting tasks or welding tasks. In such a case, it would be natural to
define the occupation by the nature of tasks assigned to it (e.g. painters,
welders, etc.). While this degree of resolution is desirable, making progress
would require seemingly arbitrary specificity concerning the efficiency
effects of task specialization.
To keep the analysis streamlined and transparent, we assume that
the tasks, as well as the workers, are homogenous. With this simplifica-
tion, all occupations are symmetric and the only choice is the range of
tasks assigned to a typical worker. That is, each worker’s ‘occupation’
is defined by his/her range of assigned tasks and all occupations will be
identical.
The gains from specialization are modeled as a link between the amount
of labor per task and the range of tasks per occupation. Specifically, the
labor input coefficient increases with the range of tasks performed by a
single worker. There are many ways of micro- founding such an outcome
but to keep things focused on essentials we simply assume the hours per
tasks rises with the range of tasks per worker. What we have in mind is
some sort of learning curve.
From the production- cost perspective, the least efficient arrangement is
to have each worker doing every task. The most efficient is to have each
worker specialized in only one task. The least cost for an organization with
a given number of occupations will be to assign an equal range of tasks to
each occupation; occupations are symmetric in equilibrium. Specifically, if
there are n
o
occupations, a range of
1/n
o
tasks is assigned to each occupation.
Greater specialization, however, engenders greater coordination costs
among occupations. A worker specializing in a range of tasks that is
one- n
o
th
of all tasks must coordinate with (n
o
1) other occupations. For
simplicity, the between- occupation coordination costs are all identical
and given by the parameter as
c
o
(chi is a mnemonic for coordination).
Ignoring within- occupation coordination, the number of coordination-
pairs is
n
o
(
n
o
2
1
)
/2.
The development and future of Factory Asia 357
More formally, the organizational cost- minimization problem is:
min
{
n
o
}
w
l
a
[
n
o
;a
]
1w
l
c
o
n
o
a
n
o
2 1
2
b
; ar
[
#
]
, 0 (10.1)
Here w is the wage; the function
a
[
#
;a
]
captures the efficiency- inducing
effect of specialization. That is, the per- task labor input coefficient a
falls as the number of occupations goes up (the range of tasks per work
is
1/n
o
with no symmetric occupations, so a higher n
o
is associated with
greater specialization of workers). Here ‘a’ – a mnemonic for automation
parameterizes the impact of IT on the efficiency- specialization effect;
ar
n
o
; a
]
indicates the first derivative with respect to n
o
as usual.
The first- order condition is:
0 5 ar
[
n
o
;a
]
n
o
1 c
o
a
n
o
2
1
2
b
(10.2)
The second order condition holds if
ar
[
#
;a
]
is decreasing (i.e. the second
derivative is positive) which is true if there are diminishing returns to
specialization – an assumption we maintain throughout.
a'[n;]
Number of
stages/occupations
euros
(n – 1/2)
1
n
1
n
3
n
2
a'[n;"]
"(n – 1/2)
Source: Authors’ illustration.
Figure 10.11 Functional unbundling: stages and occupations in symmetric
case
358 Asia and global production networks
The solution is illustrated in Figure 10.11. The marginal benefit of
increased specialization (i.e. more occupations) is shown
a
[
n
o
;a
]
while
the marginal coordination cost is rising with the number of occupations
as shown. The optimal specialization is n
1
as shown. This illustrates the
specialization- coordination trade- off that is central to our thinking on
functional fragmentation.
With this framework, it is straightforward to illustrate the distinct
impact of IT and CT. Improved IT makes it easier for one worker to
master many tasks without loss of efficiency this is why
ar
[
n
o
;a
]
is
downward sloped. Improved IT, which is parameterized as a rise in a
(automation) to a, shifts down the marginal benefit of specialization.
In other words, the marginal benefit of additional specialization is lower,
when a is higher. With the higher a”, the optimal number of occupations
is n
2
rather than n
1
.
Improved CT (communications), by contrast, makes it easier to coordi-
nate occupations; this shows up as a reduction
c
to
cs .
The result is a lower
marginal cost of increasing the number of occupations; graphically this
shows up as a shift down in c
(
n
2
1/2
)
.
The resulting optimal number of
occupations is therefore n
3
rather than n
1
.
One factor, two- tier organization It is straightforward to introduce addi-
tional levels of organizational hierarchy. We do this by assuming that
occupations can be organized into ‘stages’ as a means of economizing on
coordination costs. The occupation- level coordination costs remain as
before, but we assume that workers only face this for an occupation inside
their own stage. The new element is the cost of coordinating among stages.
For simplicity, we assume that all stages are symmetric from this perspec-
tive. Specifically, if all occupations are broken up into n
s
stages, each stage
will have to coordinate with n
s
(n
s
1) /2 other stages. The modified cost
minimization problem then becomes:
min
{
n
o
,n
s
}
w
l
a
[
n
o
n
s
;a
]
1 w
l
a
c
o
n
o
a
n
o
2 1
2
bb
1 c
s
n
s
n
s
2
1
2
(10.3)
Note that the range of tasks per symmetric occupation is now 1/n
o
n
s
, so
the argument of
a
[
#
;a
]
is n
o
n
s
, and the coordination cost parameter for
stage- coordination is denoted as
c
s
.
The first- order conditions are:
0 5 ar
[
n
o
n
s
;a
]
n
s
1 c
o
a
n
o
2
1
2
b
, 0 5 ar
[
n
o
n
s
;a
]
n
o
1 c
s
a
n
s
2
1
2
b
(10.4)
The development and future of Factory Asia 359
The simplest solution occurs when the
c
’s are equal so the solution involves
an equal number of stages and occupations. In this case, Figure 10.11
continues to characterize the basic trade- off between coordination and
specialization – as well as the role of CT and IT. More complex combina-
tions of parameters would yield a different number of occupations and
stages.
With a basic framework in place for the fractionalization of production
processes, we turn to the issue of spatial dispersion.
3.2 Geographical Unbundling: Balancing Dispersion and Agglomeration
Forces
If it were not for offshoring, fractionalization would be purely a matter of
industrial organization. To put it in an international dimension we now
turn to location decisions. The touchstone principle is that firms seek to
put each stage in the lowest cost location.
In reality, places differ along many dimensions that matter for the loca-
tion. The World Economic Forum’s competitiveness index, for example,
has 110 different measures. Our goal here, however, is to illustrate the
first order trade- off that has influenced the development of Factory Asia.
What we focus on is factor costs – for example, low versus high wage – as
the gain from offshoring. The cost of offshoring is the downside.
The cost calculation involves a trade- off between direct factor costs and
‘separation’ costs.
The direct costs include wages, capital costs and implicit or explicit
subsidies.
The separation costs should be broadly interpreted to include both
transmission and transportation costs, increased risk and increased
face- to- face managerial time.
The location decision may also be influenced by local spillovers of various
types. In some sectors and stages, say fashion clothing, proximity between
designers and consumers may be critical. In others, product development
stages may be made cheaper, faster and more effective by co- location
with certain fabrication stages. Yet other stages and sectors are marked
by strong technological spillovers that make clustering of producers the
natural outcome.
360 Asia and global production networks
3.2.1 Production efficiency versus coordination costs
The first aspect of spatial unbundling turns on a trade- off that is closely
aligned with the functional unbundling discussed above. Offshoring a
particular stage can save on production costs but raise coordination costs.
To crystalize the fundamental economic logic, we adopt a simple setting
with two nations high- tech North and low- wage South and stages
that vary continuously in their technology intensity. We work with a
‘spider- like’ production process (Baldwin and Venables 2013) whereby the
engineering of the production process implies no particular sequencing of
stages. Each stage produces a ‘part’ and the parts get assembled into the
good in the final stage called ‘assembly’. This permits us to order the stages
in analytically convenient ways.
Specifically, the stages exogenously defined in this section are
arranged in order of increasing tech- intensity, i.e. in order of increasing
North comparative advantage. This means that the high- tech North tends
to have a comparative advantage in ‘high’ stages (those with indices near
unity) while low- wage South has a comparative advantage in ‘low’ stages.
More specifically, the per- stage production cost is w
n
a
ni
in North and
is w
s
a
si
in South, where a
ni
and a
si
are the North and South unit labor
input coefficient for stage i and the w’s are the national wages. Since there
are only two locations, relative cost is all that matters, so we normalize
North’s w
n
a
ni
to unity for all stages.
2
Recalling that we have arranged
stages such that North’s comparative advantage is greatest in stages with
high indices, South’s cost per stage starts below North’s (i.e. below unity)
and rises steadily to a number above unity.
A particularly simple case is illustrated in Figure 10.12 where w
s
a
si
rises
linearly with the sophistication of the stage; b is the slope of this relation-
ship, i.e. w
s
a
si
5 b9i where iindexes the stages and i ranges from 0 to
1. Plainly South is the low cost producer in stages from zero to 1/b9 and
North is the low cost producer in the rest. It is convenient to think of as b
the strength of North’s comparative advantage in stages, since as b rises
more stages are most cheaply produced in the North.
To study the offshoring solution, the first anchor point is the cost-
minimizing outcome when coordination costs are zero. As mentioned, the
answer is that the lower tech stages are placed in South namely, stages
from 0 to 1/b with the rest in North. Separating stages, however, has impli-
cations for coordination costs. The nature of these costs matters greatly.
Products with complex coordination demands We begin with a case where
coordination demands are complex, in the sense that every stage needs
to coordinate with every other stage. An illustration of this is given in
Table10.2, which is drawn for the six- stage case where stages 1 to 2 are
The development and future of Factory Asia 361
undertaken in South and the rest in North. The table allows for different
coordination costs for coordination of stages within North,
c
n
,
within
South,
c
s
,
and ‘international’,
c
I
.
To keep the expressions simple and to sharpen the intuition, we start
with the simple example where within- nation coordination costs are zero,
i.e.
c
n
5
c
s
5 0 but
c
I
. 0, so total coordination costs are:
w
n
c
I
n
s
(1 − n
s
)
euros
Stages
0 11/2
·n
s
·(1 – n
s
)
euros
1
0
1/2
1
w
n
a
n
= 1
w
s
a
si
= 2·i
'·i
"·i
1/' 1/"
Stages
Note: Here North is offshoring stages to South.
Source: Authors’ illustration.
Figure 10.12 Comparative advantage, coordinate cost and optimal
unbundling
362 Asia and global production networks
where w
n
, n
s
, and n
n
are the North wage and number of stages in South
and North respectively. We assume that international coordination costs
involve North labor, and have assumed that the mass of stages equals
unity. Here coordination cost varies with the range of stages offshored to
South according to a parabola.
It is important to note that this convexity means that coordination
costs act as an agglomeration force. That is to say, the coordinate- cost-
minimizing solution is to keep all stages bundled together. Coordination
costs are maximized when stages are split evenly between North and South.
Production cost considerations, by contrast, act as a dispersion force. The
optimal unbundling and offshoring of stages from North to South involves
the usual balancing of dispersion and agglomeration forces.
More formally, taking coordination and production costs together
(assuming the linear example, i.e. w
s
a
si
5 b
i
where 0 , b , 1), total costs
as a function of the range of stages in South, (0, n
s
), are:
{
b
n
2
s
/2
1
1
2
n
s
}
1
{
c
I
n
s
(
1
2
n
s
) }
This is a quadratic function whose second derivative is negative if and only
if coordination costs are not too high relative to the strength of North’s
comparative advantage, specifically
c , b/2.
We assume this regularity
condition so that the first order conditions indicate cost minimizing rather
than cost maximizing solutions.
The first order condition with respect to the range of stages placed in
South, n
s
, is:
{
b
n
s
2
1
}
1
{
c
I
(
1
2
2n
s
) }
5
0
Solving the first order condition with respect to the range of stages placed
in South, we have:
Table 10.2 Coordination- cost matrix: complex good case
Stage 1 Stage 2 Stage 3 Stage 4 Stage 5 Stage 6
Stage 1
c
s
Stage 2
c
s
c
s
Stage 3
c
I
c
I
c
n
Stage 4
c
I
c
I
c
n
c
n
Stage 5
c
I
c
I
c
n
c
n
c
n
Stage 6
c
I
c
I
c
n
c
n
c
n
c
n
Note: This table discretizes the continuum of parts for the sake of illustration.
The development and future of Factory Asia 363
n 5
1
2
c
I
b 2
2
c
I
This spatial unbundling setting presents some unusual features.
First, it is subject to threshold behavior, with the threshold at
c
I
. b/2.
The reason for this is simple. The solution is the cost- maximizing solution
for
c
I
. b/2
but the cost- minimizing solution for
c
I
, b/2.
Thus:
If coordination costs are high relative to North’s comparative advan-
tage (as measured by b), then we have a corner solution, i.e. all stages are
clustered in one nation.
3
Which nation it is depends upon North’s comparative advantage.
4
Production is cheaper in the North if and only if b . 2; otherwise the
cluster is in South.
For coordination costs lower than the clustering threshold (i.e.
c
I
, b/2
),
stages will be dispersed internationally according to 0.
Thus a continuous reduction in coordination costs starting from a
very high level would have a discontinuous effect on offshoring at the
threshold.
A second unusual feature is that cheaper coordination may lead to
more or less production in South. The sign of the impact of
c
I
on n
s
switches at b 5 2. If South has a strong comparative advantage, in the
sense that more than half the stages would be produced there based solely
on production cost considerations (e.g. b as in Figure 10.12), then con-
siderations of communication costs will lead to ‘too much’ production in
the South. The point is that even though Southern production costs are
higher, the fact that more than half the stages are there already means
that sending more stages lowers coordination costs. In this case, lower
communication costs will lead to less offshoring to South. By contrast, if
b is high, say b in Figure 10.12, then lower
c
I
will increase the offshoring
to South.
One particularly intuitive case is when North has a strong comparative
advantage in parts, e.g. b in the diagram, so more than half the parts are
produced in North. In this case, coordination cost considerations tend
to reduce the amount of offshoring from the North to the South. As
coordination costs fall, the range of stages placed in the South rises.
To summarize, even in the simplest framework that allows a trade- off
between efficiency and coordination costs, the relationship between easier
communication and offshoring is far from monotonic. The convex nature
of coordination costs tends to create tipping points and comparative static
results that can flip signs according to parameters that may be hard for the
econometrician to observe.
364 Asia and global production networks
4. CONCLUDING REMARKS
This chapter looks at the underlying interconnected processes that drove
Factory Asia’s development from the mid- 1980s. We focused on two
complementary trends: fractionalization of the manufacturing process
into stages, and the dispersion of these stages around Asia. The chapter
organized the thinking by providing a formal model for the TOSP (tasks,
occupations, stages, products) framework that was informally introduced
in Baldwin (2012). The TOSP framework views the production of goods
as the performance of a range of tasks that are organized into occupations
(collection of tasks) and stages (collections of occupations). Typically
offshoring occurs at the level of stages rather than tasks or occupation.
4.1 Policy Issues
While no formal evidence- based policy recommendations can be made
based on our chapter’s contribution, a number of important themes emerge.
First, geography is an important determinant of the ease of participat-
ing in Factory Asia. Just as it is easier to set up a supply plant in or near
an industrial district, joining Factory Asia is much easier for nations that
are proximate to the headquarters economies in East Asia Japan, the
Republic of Korea, Taipei,China, Singapore, and Hong Kong, China. As
Factory Asia is not so developed, proximity to other factory economies is
also important especially proximity to the PRC, which is a massive and
highly competitive producer of industry inputs (parts and components).
5
This is nothing more than an assertion that forward and backward link-
ages matter at the regional level as well as at the national or industrial
district level.
The intuition is similarly straightforward. In the main production
unbundling sectors – electrical and mechanical machinery fractionalized
production processes involve time- sensitive and shipping- cost sensitive
elements. Being near other supply- chain traders both headquarters
and factory economies makes it easier to join Factory Asia. Another
way to put this is that ‘regional comparative advantage’ matters as
well as ‘national comparative advantage’ when it comes to joining an
international production network.
Second, size matters. Nations that have over a billion consumers (the
PRC and India) can pursue policies that smaller nations cannot. In essence
the two giants can leverage their local market as a powerful attraction
force for supply chain segments.
Third, providing assurances to tangible and intangible property rights
is likely to be an important element in attracting supply chain production.
The development and future of Factory Asia 365
As such production is necessarily networked, some firms or networks of
firms must be coordinating the process. Such firms are naturally reluctant
to expose their managerial, technical and marketing knowhow to tacit
or explicit expropriation, which would facilitate the emergence of new
competitors.
4.2 Future Research
The charts in the chapter suggest many correlations and relationships
that can and should be tested more formally using the newly devel-
oped TiVA database. Such empirical work will be critical in developing
evidence- based policy recommendations. How important are intellectual
property rights protection versus quick port clearance? How damaging is
distance to participation in international supply chains (controlling for
other factors)? How important are formal free trade agreements overall,
and particular provisions specifically (e.g. investment provisions, versus
capital mobility provisions).
A wide range of institutional measures exist in databases such as the
World Bank’s Doing Business and the World Economic Forum’s Global
Competitiveness Report, and the detailed work from the trade facilitation
literature. These are essentially right- hand side variables that have been
used to explain macro growth trends. It would be important to sort out
how these various ‘institutional or policy’ measures interact with more
fundamental determinants such as distance from headquarters economies,
distance from final goods markets, wages, etc. The key contribution of the
new value- added databases is that we now have left- hand side measures of
supply- chain participation. Moreover, the network nature of the new data
should allow us to go beyond simple nation- by- nation approaches where
a nation’s own right- hand side features are all that is allowed to affect
outcomes. This would allow us to look at regional as well as national
comparative advantage and perhaps better identify which sectors are more
likely to be successful in which nations.
Factory Asia has been deepening and widening at a historically unprec-
edented rate since the 1980s. Despite the Global Crisis, the Great Trade
Collapse and the rise of anti- globalization elements in rich nations,
Factory Asia does not seem to be leveling off. New nations like Viet Nam
seem to be joining with success. In short, the future of Factory Asia seems
bright. The key questions are: How can developing nations join, and how
can they make sure that joining leads to an ever- denser participation
in value networks? Those are questions that economists would be well
advised to tackle.
366 Asia and global production networks
NOTES
* This chapter was written for the ADB’s project ‘The Future of Factory Asia’. Our con-
tribution draws heavily on the authors’ earlier works; it is intended to inform policy and
help direct future research.
1. This insight – which is due to Bloom et al. (2009) – has recently received some empirical
support from Lanz et al. (2011). They find that offshoring of business services comple-
ments manufacturing activities, in the sense that increased import penetration in business
services is associated with a shift in local task content from information and communica-
tion related tasks toward tasks related to handling machinery and equipment. Offshoring
of other services complements local information- intensive tasks in that it shifts local task
composition towards ICT- related tasks.
2. As wages are exogenous here, we could do this by choosing North labor as numeraire
and choosing units for all stages since that a
ni
5 1 for all i.
3. Note that b measures North’s comparative advantage in the sense that the range of stages
where North is the low cost producer ranges from
1/b
to unity, so this expands as b rises.
4. Total cost with all stages in the South and North, respectively, will be
b /2
and 1.
5. It is a quirk of language, but remarkable that one can get from ‘supply chain’ to ‘supply
China’ by moving just one letter!
REFERENCES
Baldwin, R. (2006),‘Globalisation: the great unbundling (s)’, paper contribution
to the project Globalisation Challenges for Europe and Finland, Economic
Council of Finland.
Baldwin, R. –(2012),‘Global supply chains: why they emerged, why they matter,
and where they are going’, Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion
Papers No. 9103.
Baldwin, R., and A.J. Venables (2013), ‘Spiders and snakes: offshoring and
agglomeration in the global economy’, Journal of International Economics, 90,
245–254.
Bloom, N., L. Garicano, R. Sadun, and J. Van Reenen (2009),‘The distinct effects
of information technology and communication technology on firm organiza-
tion’, NBER Working Papers No. 14975, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Brülhart, M. (2009), ‘An account of global intra- industry trade, 1962–2006’, The
World Economy, 32, 401–459.
Costinot, A. (2009),‘On the origins of comparative advantage’, Journal of
International Economics, 77, 255–264.
Costinot, A., L. Oldenski, and J. Rauch (2011),‘Adaptation and the boundary of
multinational firms’, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 93, 298–308.
Garicano, L. (2000),‘Hierarchies and the organization of knowledge in produc-
tion’, Journal of Political Economy, 108, 874–904.
Grunwald, J., and K. Flamm (1985), The Global Factory: Foreign Assembly in
International Trade, Brookings Institution Press.
Lanz, R., S. Miroudot, and H.K. Nordås (2011), ‘Trade in tasks’, OECD
Trade Policy Papers No 117, OECD Publishing, available at: http://dx.doi.
org/10.1787/5kg6v2hkvmmw- en.
The development and future of Factory Asia 367
APPENDIX 10A.1
Table 10A.1 Country codes
Country name Country code
Australia AUS
Brazil BRA
Brunei Darussalam BRU
Cambodia CAM
Canada CAN
Chile CHL
Czech Republic CZE
France FRA
Germany GER
Hong Kong, China HKG
Hungary HUN
Indonesia INO
Italy ITA
Japan JPN
Korea, Republic of KOR
Malaysia MAL
Mexico MEX
Norway NOR
People’s Republic of China PRC
Philippines PHI
Poland POL
Portugal POR
Romania ROU
Russia RUS
Saudi Arabia SAU
Singapore SIN
Slovakia SVK
Slovenia SVN
South Africa ZAF
Taipei,China TAP
Thailand THA
Turkey TUR
United Kingdom UKG
United States USA
Viet Nam VIE
Source: Authors’ listing.
369
aggregation bias 326, 331
Amiti, M. 211, 260
Andrade da Silva, J. 113, 123–4
antidumping, effect on exports 162–8
Antras, P. 82, 180, 187
Arkolakis, C. 260
Asian Input–Output tables
(IDE-JETRO) 66, 309
BACI database 124, 302
Baldwin, R. 179, 296, 333, 338, 340
Barrell, R. 280
Bayoumi, T. 253
BEC concordances and constructing a
GTAP-MRIO 20–23, 24–5
Belderbos, R. 151
Bems, R. 251, 273
Bergin, P.R. 170
Bernard, A.B. 329
betweenness centrality 303
bilateral trade
and real exchange rate 257
and vertical specialization 262
Blair, P. 322
Blonigen, B.A. 151
Bloom, N. 354, 355
Brandt, L. 184, 185
Burstein, A. 242, 260
business approach to international
supply chain management 296–9
business cycle synchronization 260–71
business statistics and trade data
329–30
Caliendo, L. 242
Camarero, M. 280
Campa, J.M. 281
Carare, A. 262
Carlos-Lopes, J. 322
Carrico, C. 29, 91
Cebeci, T. 210
Cernat, L. 113, 123–4
CGE model and impact of demand
shocks 84–5, 89–90
Chaney, T. 149, 151, 154
Chen, H. 255
Cheung, Y.-W. 255, 257
China
antidumping cases 162
and exchange rate stabilization
272–9
exports composition 182–5
gross exports decomposition 315
imported input diversity 191–3
intra-ASEAN trade 349
processing trade and ordinary trade
160–62
production stages 186–91
production stages and trade growth
194–202
production stages and transaction
exit 202–10
real exchange rate 253
trade developments 181–5
trade flows and real exchange rate
255–6
trade policy shocks, impact on
exports 160–68
Chinese yuan and regional currency
movements 273–6
Chinn, M. 255, 280, 281, 282
Chor, D. 180, 187
Choudri, E. 259, 260
Cole, M.T. 154
COMTRADE database 19
Costinot, A. 354
currency movements 273–6
current account rebalancing, see
rebalancing
Daudin, G. 313
Davies, R.B. 154
Index
370 Asia and global production networks
De la Cruz, J. 330
Deardorff, A.V. 170
Dées, S. 280
Defever, F. 195
deficit countries, impact of rebalancing
217, 236–40
Degain, C. 294, 319, 326
Dekle, R. 216, 218, 222, 229
demand and prices, model of world
economy 223
demand-side absorption approach to
measuring trade flows 315–17
compared with supply-side
measurement 317–23
dependent economy 215
developing countries and global value
chains 296
development policy and trade theory
294
di Giovanni, J. 242, 262, 263
Diakantoni, A. 170, 326
Dietzenbacher, E. 324
disaster data, EM-DAT database
114–15
disasters and supply chain
vulnerability 81–109
CGE model 89–90
GTAP supply chain model 4–6,
89–92
MRIO analysis 4–5, 83–4
natural disasters, see natural
disasters and global supply
chains
Singapore entrepot disruption 88–9,
102–7
dispersion 359–63
domestic value added content of
exports 312–14
Dornbusch, R. 215
double counting 301, 314–15, 316–17,
321
earthquakes
Great Tohoku, impact on Japanese
car manufacture 112
Taipei,China, impact on electrical
equipment sector 88, 92–101
Eaton, J. 218, 242
“Eigenvector Centrality” indicator
303
electrical equipment sector,
Taipei,China, impact of
earthquake 88, 92–101
electronics exports, China 182–3
EM-DAT database 114–15
entrepot disruption, Singapore, impact
on supply chain 88–9, 102–7
Eora MRIO database 69, 310, 326
equilibrium in model of world
economy 222–5
Escaith, H. 170, 294, 324, 326
Ethier, W.J. 294
Euler, Leonhard 291
EUROSTAT “Trade by Enterprise
Characteristics” project 329
exchange rate pass-through 258–60
exchange rate stabilization and
Chinese dominance 272–9
EXIOBASE database 68–9
exports
composition, China 182–5
decomposition into value-added
components 313–15, 317–23
emerging East Asian economies
340–42
impact of growth 37
impact of natural disasters 93,
112–14, 129–39
impact of Singapore entrepot
disruption 103–7
impact of tariff increase 158–68
upstreamness and stages, China 196
extensive margin, impact of
antidumping 165–8
external rebalancing, see rebalancing
Factory Asia 338–65
development of 340–52
functional supply chain unbundling
352–9
geographical supply chain
unbundling 359–63
Fally, T. 10, 180
Feenstra, R. 289, 332
Fernald, J. 280
Ferrarini, B. 301, 302
final and intermediate goods 302
financial flows 294
financial risk-transfer and natural
disaster compensation 140–41
Index 371
Finicelli, A. 247
food industry, India, impact of tariff
reduction 53, 60
foreign ownership and trade, China
181–2
Fort, T. 150
Foster, N. 310
fractionalization of supply chains
352–9
fragmentation of production process
288; see also trade in tasks;
unbundling of supply chains;
vertical specialization
Fratzscher, M. 274–6
Freund, C. 211
functional unbundling 352–9
Fung, V.K. 148
Gallaway, M.P. 94
Gangnes, B. 211
Garicano, L. 354
Gassebner, M. 113, 115, 123–4
Gaulier, G. 124, 210
GDP
GDP correlation and trade linkages
262
impact of income shocks 36–43
impact of tariff reduction on
intermediate imports 50–52
Gehlhar, M. 28
Geoffrion, A. 296–8
geographical unbundling 359–63
Gereffi, G. 296
Ghosh, A. 259
global inter-industry matrix 86–9
Global Trade Analysis Project, see
GTAP
global value chains 1–3
impact of disasters 81–109,
112–41
measuring 12–13, 287–332
models 289–99
unbundling 352–63
see also supply chain vulnerability
globalization 339–40
Goldberg, L.S. 281
Goldstein, M. 254
Gonguet, F. 294
Gopinath, G. 259
Goyal, S. 332, 333
graph theory 290–93
and global value chains 303–4
Great Tohoku earthquake and
tsunami 112
Grossman, G.M. 288, 296
GTAP database 16–17, 67, 90, 124
GTAP-ICIO database 67–8
GTAP-MRIO 16–18, 23–32
data sets 30–32
labor categories 29
GTAP-SC model 5–6, 32–5
fixed multiplier model 35–47
and impact of disasters on supply
chains 89–92
and impact of tariff reductions
47–61
and income shock 36–43
GVCs, see global value chains
Hakura, D. 259, 260
Hale, G. 211
Hansen, D. 332, 333
Hanson, G.H. 289
Head, K. 195
Hellerstein, R. 259
Helpman, E. 82
Herrendorf, B. 219
Hertel, T.W. 91, 94
Hillberry, R. 255
Hodrick–Prescott filter and business
cycles 263, 265
Huang, Y. 274
Hummels, D. 210, 255, 312
ICT and production unbundling
352–9
IDE-JETRO Asian Input–Output
Tables 66, 309
imports
China, diversity and sourcing 191–3
China, and upstreamness and stages
187–91, 196
tariff reduction, impact on GDP
47–61
impulse response to output gap shock
267–71
income flows 293–4
income shocks 36–43
impact on employment 43, 47
impact on GDP 36–7
372 Asia and global production networks
India, food industry, impact of tariff
reduction 53, 60
Inomata, S. 324
input diversity and sourcing, China
191–3
input–output analysis, see MRIO
analysis
input–output (I–O) tables
IDE-JETRO 66, 309
and measuring trade in value-added
309
OECD 66
intensive margin, impact of
antidumping 165–8
intermediate inputs
differentiating from final goods 302
and mapping trade flows 299,
300–309
and model of world economy 227
upstreamness and stages 188–91
international input–output matrices,
topological limitation 327–8
international supply chain
management 296–9
intra-industry trade with ASEAN
economies 344–9
Ito, H. 281, 282
Japan
earthquake and tsunami, impact on
trade 114
intra-industry trade with ASEAN
economies 344–9
real exchange rate 253
wearing apparel imports 26–7
Johnson, R.C. 179, 210, 251, 255, 256,
313, 314
Jones, B. 113–14, 124
Kee, H.L. 149, 193, 211
Khan, M. 254
Königsberg Bridge Problem 291
Konings, J. 170
Koopman, R. 24, 28, 67, 149, 181, 210,
280, 281, 313, 315, 316, 317
Koopmans, T.C. 289
Korea, Republic of
business cycle dynamics 265–7
intra-industry trade with ASEAN
economies 344, 348, 349
Kortum, S. 218
Kose, M.A. 260
Krugman, P.R. 294
labor
GTAP-MRIO categories 29, 91
non-tradeable sector, impact of
rebalancing 235, 236
and trade 310
labor force data 227
Lall, S. 305
Lanz, R. 366
Leiter, A.M. 82
length of supply chains and trade
partners’ positions 324–5
Leontief, V. 332
Levchenko, A. 211, 226, 242, 244, 262,
263
Li & Fung 148
Liao, S. 82
location decisions 359–63
Long, C. 211
Lopez-Gonzalez, J. 179
Los, B. 317
Lu, M. 195
Ma, A. 210
machinery and transport equipment,
revealed comparative advantage
322–3
MacKenzie, C.A. 83, 101, 109, 114
market clearing, model of world
economy 224
Martin, R. 114
Maurer, A. 294
Measuring Globalization (OECD) 262
Mehl, A. 274–6
Melitz, M.J. 149, 151
Memedovic, O. 300
Meng, B. 317
Miller, R. 322
Miroudot, S. 170
Mody, A. 262
Morrow, P.M. 184, 185
MRIO (multi-region input–output)
analysis 4–5, 16–17
and GTAP-SC analysis 32–61
and impact of demand shocks 83–9
MRIO databases 16–23; see also
GTAP-MRIO
Index 373
multiplier analysis, GTAP-SC model
35–47
natural disasters and global supply
chains 6–7, 112–41
data 114–20
impact on exports 129–39
supply chain vulnerability
measurement 122–3, 125–9
Taipei,China earthquake 88,
92–101
Neiman, B. 259
network economics 290–94
“new” new trade theory 295–6
new trade theory 294–6
Ng, E.C.Y. 262, 263
Ng, F. 301
Noguera, G. 179, 210, 313, 314
non-tradeable sector
labor share, impact of rebalancing
235, 236
total factor productivity estimation
247
Noy, I. 82
Nualsri, A. 82
Nunn, N. 187
Obstfeld, M. 216, 218, 229
OECD Input–Output tables 66
offshoring 359–63
Okuyama, Y. 83
Olken, B.A. 113–14, 124
Oosterhaven, J. 315
optimal tasks per occupation and
occupations per stage 353–5
ordinary trade and processing trade,
China 160–62
output gaps response to shock 267–71
ownership of firms, China, and trade
181–2
Oxley, L. 289
Park, A. 289–90
Parro, F. 242
People’s Republic of China (PRC), see
China
pin factory 353–4
Porter, Michael 298
Powers, R. 296–8
PRC, see China
preference non-homotheticity 219
prices, impact of Taipei,China ELE
productivity shock 101
processing trade 288–9
China 160–62, 181, 183–5
product differentiation 306–9
and value-added approach 328
product-level trade, China 181–5
input diversity and sourcing 191–3
production position 194–202
and transaction exit 202–10
upstreamness and stages 186–91
production stages, China 186–91,
194–202
and probability of transaction exit
202–10
sensitivity to trade policy shocks
160
property rights and attracting supply
chain production 364–5
proportionality method of
constructing MRIO database 20
province-level analysis, effect of
antidumping on exports 162–5
Rajan, R.S. 259
Ramanarayanan, A. 260
Rauch, J.E. 309
real exchange rate
measurement 250–54
and rebalancing 233–5
and trade flows 254–7
real GDP, see GDP
real income, impact of Taipei,China
ELE productivity shock 100–101
rebalancing 215–41
impacts on outcomes 229–40
model 218–28
rebalancing GTAP-MRIO database
25–8
revealed comparative advantage,
machinery and transport
equipment 322–3
Riaño, A. 195
Rifflart, C. 297
Rogoff, K.S. 216, 218, 229
Romero, I. 324
Rose, A. 82, 83, 85
Rossi-Hansberg, E. 288, 296
Rouzet, D. 170
374 Asia and global production networks
Salter–Swan model 215
Sancho, F. 333
Schweisguth, D. 297
sectoral aggregation, BACI and GTAP
146–7
sectoral impacts of tariff reduction on
intermediate imports 52–3
sectoral productivity estimation
226–7
services trade, mapping 301
Shih, Stan 298
Shikher, S. 242
shocks, see disasters and supply chain
vulnerability; rebalancing
Simonovska, I. 227
Singapore, entrepot disruption impact
on supply chain 88–9, 102–7
Sleuwaegen, L. 151
Smith, Adam 353–4
Smith, G. 257
socio-economic impact from trade in
value-added 310
Spencer, M. 282
spillovers and vertical specialization
262
stages, see production stages
Stehrer, R. 315
Stelder, D. 315
Sturgeon, T. 296, 300, 329
supply chain trade and domestic
value-added in exports 343–4
supply chain unbundling 352–63
supply chain vulnerability
and disasters 81–109, 112–41
measurement 113, 122–3, 125–9
supply-side measurement of trade
flows 313–15
compared with demand-side
measurement 317–23
surplus countries, impact of
rebalancing 217, 235–6, 236–40
Świeçki, T. 219
Taipei,China, business cycle dynamics
267–71
Taipei,China earthquake
impact on electrical equipment
sector 92–101
impact on supply chain 88
Tamarit, C. 280
Tang, H. 149, 193, 211, 330
tariff reduction on intermediate
imports 47–61
impact on real GDP 50–52
sectoral impacts 52–61
tariff shirking, effects on trade 148–70
team size, optimal 354
terms of trade (ToT) impact of ELE
productivity shock 99–100
textile exports, China 182–3
Thorbecke, W. 253, 257, 281
Timmer, M. 326
TiVA (trade in value added) database
66–7, 340
TOSP (tasks, occupations, stages,
products) framework 338, 352–3
ToT (terms of trade) impact of ELE
productivity shock 99–100
total factor productivity 246–7
trade
data 66–9, 124, 329–30
and environment 310
and labor 310
trade balances 228
Trade by Enterprise Characteristics
(EUROSTAT) 329
trade costs estimation 246
trade flows
mapping 300–301
and real exchange rate 254–7
trade in tasks 288–9, 295–6, 306,
319–20
trade in value-added 297–8
limitations 323–9, 331
measuring 309–29
Trade in Value-Added (TiVA)
database 66–7, 340
trade theory 294–6
tradeable sector relative technology
244–6
transaction exit and production stage,
China 202–10
Traveling Salesman Problem 291
Tsigas, M. 29, 91
Ulrich, K. 150
UN COMTRADE database 19
unbundling of supply chains 352–63
United Kingdom, impact of extreme
weather on productivity 114
Index 375
United States, tradeable sector
technology 245–6
upstreamness 186–91
Uy, T. 227
value-added 293–4, 297–8; see also
trade in value-added
value-added content of exports 312–13,
313–14
value chain restructuring, Li & Fung
148
Van Assche, A. 210
Vandenbussche, H. 170
Venables, A. 333
vertical specialization
and business cycle synchronization
260–63
and impact of tariff changes
155–60
and trade policy 150–51
and trade in value-added 312–13
Viet Nam, impact of tariff reductions
53
motor vehicle and transportation
sector 60–61
Villas-Boas, S.B. 259
Vitali, S. 332
Vogel, J. 242
volatility spillovers and vertical
specialization 262
wages, impact of external rebalancing
232, 235–6
Walmsley, T.L. 29, 91
Wang, Z. 211
Waugh, M.E. 227, 244
weather extremes, impact on UK
productivity 114
Wei, D. 83, 85
Weingarden, A. 29, 91
welfare 225
impact of rebalancing 235–6, 236–40
World Input–Output Database
(WIOD) 68, 309
world trade network and graph theory
291–3
World Trade Web (WTW) 292
Yeats, A. 300, 301
Yi, K.-M. 151, 255, 260
Yu, Z. 211
yuan and regional currency movements
273–6
Zhang, J. 226, 244
Zignano, S. 124