Emory School of Law
Emory Legal Scholarship Working Paper Series
Year  Paper
Between Mandate and Market: Contract
Transition in the Shadow of the International
Order
Robert B. Ahdieh
Emory Law School, rba7@law.georgetown.edu
This working paper is hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press (bepress) and may not be commer-
cially reproduced without the permission of the copyright holder.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
Copyright
c
2005 by the author.
Between Mandate and Market: Contract
Transition in the Shadow of the International
Order
Robert B. Ahdieh
Abstract
Not unlike the average American, nations from the United States to Burkina Faso
have long relied on credit to survive. Taking various forms over the years, such
debt has most recently been financed through sovereign bonds. Like their cor-
porate cousins, sovereign bonds amount essentially to a contract obligating the
debtor to make recurring payments of principal and interest until a maturity date,
on which any remaining balance of principal comes due. Unlike corporate bond
contracts, the terms of sovereign debt contracts are set out with a firm expectation
of future debt restructuring, when the sovereign issuer?perhaps inevitably?faces
financial distress.
In the face of this premonition, contract boilerplate in sovereign debt instruments
issued in the United States long dictated the unanimous consent of bondholders to
any debt restructuring. This requirement persisted for decades, notwithstanding
widespread consensus that such unanimous action provisions increased transac-
tion costs, produced inefficient delays in debt restructuring, enhanced the moral
hazards of the sovereign debt market, and otherwise triggered collective action
failures. Yet, the sovereign debt markets have recently made an about-face, re-
placing the unanimity requirement for debt restructuring with less demanding
provisions for collective, or majority, action by creditors. Completed over the
course of just a few months in 2003, this unexpected and dramatic shift offer a
natural experiment of sorts: Why might contract boilerplate not respond to ap-
parent efficiency demands for extended periods? What might cause it to respond
eventually? In particular, what role might state action have in the evolution of
boilerplate contract terms and in contract transition generally?
In the realm of international finance, these inquiries demand urgent analysis, both
because the relevant sovereign debt contract standards continue to evolve, and be-
cause the appropriate role of national authorities and the official sector (e.g., the
International Monetary Fund) in shaping the sovereign debt restructuring regime
remains an open question: Most broadly, can the market be expected to facilitate
efficient transition in contracts with significant boilerplate elements, or is regu-
latory mandate essential to such change? Challenging this dichotomous choice
between market or mandate, this Article proffers a “third way” toward efficient
contract transition. While the market may not always produce efficient transition,
ordinary public regulation may not be the answer. Instead, this Article identifies
state action grounded in noncoercive “regulatory cues” as the mechanism of effi-
cient transition in standardized contract terms. In the face of growing reliance on
boilerplate contract terms and standard-form contracts, public intervention in the
form of regulatory cues may, paradoxically, help to facilitate meaningful choice in
contract design, and hence a true freedom of contract. The role of regulatory cues
in sovereign debt contracts, moreover, may also pressage a potential role in inter-
national regulation generally given the limits of hard power within a community
of sovereign states.
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET:
CONTRACT TRANSITION IN THE SHADOW OF THE
INTERNATIONAL ORDER
Robert B. Ahdieh*
I
NTRODUCTION ................................................................................................693
I. THE SLOW AND SUDDEN EVOLUTION OF SOVEREIGN
DEBT CONTRACTS ................................................................................697
A. Unanimous and Collective Action in Sovereign
Debt Restructuring .......................................................................
698
B. Holdout Creditors and the Bumpy Road to
Debt Restructuring .......................................................................
702
1. An International Bankruptcy Regime?...................................705
2. Institutional Versus Contractual Remedies
to the Restructuring Dilemma ................................................
707
II. A NETWORK THEORY OF SOVEREIGN DEBT CONTRACTING ................710
A. Toward a Network Conception of Sovereign
Debt Contracting..........................................................................
710
B. Network Effects, Stasis, and Change in
Sovereign Debt Contracting.........................................................
721
III. COORDINATION GAMES, FOCAL POINTS, AND A CUEING
THEORY OF SOVEREIGN DEBT TRANSITION .........................................728
A. A Game Theoretic Account of Sovereign
Debt Contracting..........................................................................
729
B. Regulatory Cues in Sovereign Debt Contract Transition.............736
1. Regulatory Cues of Creditor States
and the Official Sector ...........................................................
736
2. Emerging Market Regulatory Cues........................................740
C. The Nature and Role of Regulatory Cues.....................................743
* Associate Professor of Law, Emory University School of Law. A.B., Princeton University; J.D., Yale
University. Thanks to Mitu Gulati for inviting me to participate in Georgetown University’s Conference on
Sovereign Debt Restructuring: The View from the Legal Academy, and for his generous assistance in
educating me in the complexities of sovereign debt. For their guidance on earlier drafts of this Article, I am
grateful to Ralph Brubaker, Lee Buchheit, Bill Buzbee, Bill Carney, Steve Choi, Michael Gibson, Allen Kamp,
Bill Klein, Peter Linzer, Marc Miller, Ashok Mody, James Nehf, Robert Schapiro, and David Slawson. Thank
you also to my research assistants, for their indefatigable labors.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
692 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
1. Cues and Coercion in Sovereign Debt Contracting
...............
743
2. Regulatory Cues as Sources of Information...........................748
3. The Shifting Role of Regulatory Cues in Sovereign
Debt Contracting....................................................................
749
IV. REGULATORY CUES IN THE INTERNATIONAL
FINANCIAL ARCHITECTURE..................................................................751
A. Between Mandate and Market: Cueing Transition
in Sovereign Debt Contract Transition ........................................
751
B. The Continuing Role of Regulatory Cues in Sovereign
Debt Contract Transition .............................................................
756
C. Convergence and Fragmentation in Sovereign
Debt Contracting..........................................................................
758
CONCLUSION....................................................................................................760
* * *
A
BSTRACT
Not unlike the average American, nations from the United States to
Burkina Faso have long relied on credit to survive. Taking various
forms over the years, such debt has most recently been financed
through sovereign bonds. Like their corporate cousins, sovereign
bonds amount essentially to a contract obligating the debtor to make
recurring payments of principal and interest until a maturity date, on
which any remaining balance of principal comes due. Unlike
corporate bond contracts, the terms of sovereign debt contracts are
set out with a firm expectation of future debt restructuring, when the
sovereign issuerperhaps inevitablyfaces financial distress.
In the face of this premonition, contract boilerplate in sovereign debt
instruments issued in the United States long dictated the unanimous
consent of bondholders to any debt restructuring. This requirement
persisted for decades, notwithstanding widespread consensus that
such unanimous action provisions increased transaction costs,
produced inefficient delays in debt restructuring, enhanced the moral
hazards of the sovereign debt market, and otherwise triggered
collective action failures. Yet, the sovereign debt markets have
recently made an about-face, replacing the unanimity requirement for
debt restructuring with less demanding provisions for collective, or
majority, action by creditors. Completed over the course of just a
few months in 2003, this unexpected and dramatic shift offer a
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 693
natural experiment of sorts: Why might contract boilerplate not
respond to apparent efficiency demands for extended periods? What
might cause it to respond eventually? In particular, what role might
state action have in the evolution of boilerplate contract terms and in
contract transition generally?
In the realm of international finance, these inquiries demand urgent
analysis, both because the relevant sovereign debt contract standards
continue to evolve, and because the appropriate role of national
authorities and the official sector (e.g., the International Monetary
Fund) in shaping the sovereign debt restructuring regime remains an
open question: Most broadly, can the market be expected to facilitate
efficient transition in contracts with significant boilerplate elements,
or is regulatory mandate essential to such change? Challenging this
dichotomous choice between market or mandate, this Article proffers
a “third way” toward efficient contract transition. While the market
may not always produce efficient transition, ordinary public
regulation may not be the answer. Instead, this Article identifies
state action grounded in noncoercive “regulatory cues” as the
mechanism of efficient transition in standardized contract terms. In
the face of growing reliance on boilerplate contract terms and
standard-form contracts, public intervention in the form of regulatory
cues may, paradoxically, help to facilitate meaningful choice in
contract design, and hence a true freedom of contract. The role of
regulatory cues in sovereign debt contracts, moreover, may also
pressage a potential role in international regulation generally given
the limits of hard power within a community of sovereign states.
INTRODUCTION
This is more about sending a signal to the international markets than
it is about reducing our borrowing costs.
Mexican Finance Ministry official,
introducing collective action term in
new sovereign debt contracts
1
In the corner of every room in which the terms of sovereign debt contracts
are negotiated and considered sits the 800-pound gorilla of potential debt
restructuring. The sovereign bond contractby which nation-states receive an
influx of investment for national growth and development, in exchange for a
1
Mexico Pioneers Plan to Ease Debt, FIN. TIMES INVESTOR, Feb. 24, 2003.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
694 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
stream of principal and interest payments
is one designed with a strong
premonition of breach. Yet the international financial order lacks any effective
cage for its gorilla. Nation-states go bankrupt, but this does not force them and
their creditors into bankruptcy court
an institution alien to the international
financial architecture. It leads them back to the negotiating table.
Contract terms have consequently been relied on to define the ways and
means of sovereign debt restructuring and default. Sovereign bond contracts
issued under New York law
the most typical choice of law, especially among
emerging market debtors, those most susceptible to default
have long
incorporated boilerplate language permitting restructuring of the bond, but
only with the bondholders’ unanimous consent. Yet this stricture has proven to
be a high barrier to debt restructuring. Most importantly, a unanimity
requirement opens the door to abuse by holdout creditors, who can, and often
do, insist on inflated side payments to accede to a restructuring plan already
agreed to by most other creditors.
2
Notwithstanding such holdout problems
and other collective action difficulties, however, little has changed in the
conventions of debt contracting for decades. Even the increased pressure for
change triggered by a series of emerging market financial crises in the late
1990s seemed to provoke little response from the market.
Against this backdrop of longstanding stasis, few observers of the
sovereign debt markets in early 2003 would have predicted any shift away
from unanimous action provisions in the near future. Yet over the course of
only a few months in the middle of 2003, this conventional wisdom was
disproved. By the end of the year, the longstanding norm of unanimous action
for debt restructuring had been all but abandoned. In a complete inversion of
the status quo, once-familiar unanimous action provisions have become the
exception in sovereign debt contracts, while collective action clauses
permitting restructuring by a qualified majority of bondholders are the
expected norm.
3
One might reasonably expect contract normsalong with other social
normsto be products of evolutionary patterns of adjustment and reform.
Decentralized in their origins, and diffuse in their operation, the drafting
conventions behind contract boilerplate and standardized contracts seem
2
Corporate and other domestic debtors effectively avoid holdout problems through the bankruptcy
regime and its automatic stay, cramdown, and other mechanisms, by which holdout creditors can be pressed
into agreement.
3
See infra Part I.B.2.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 695
unlikely candidates for rapid and revolutionary change. Many have
consequently puzzled over the recent shift in sovereign debt contract
conventions. As Mitu Gulati and David Skeel have queried: “What does this
sudden move from a point of unwillingness to try even minimal change to one
of everyday experimentation tell us about the dynamics of the underlying
system? . . . [W]hat produces movement out of the status quo[?]”
4
Alongside
these questions one might add another: Why was the move so sudden?
Here, I attempt to respond to these inquiries with an eye to the evolution of
standardized contract terms generally. Can such terms be expected to evolve
naturally with changing conditions, or might their transition require regulatory
mandate? Most observers fall in one of two camps: In one camp sit those who
assert that efficient contract norms emerge naturally by way of the market,
while in the opposing camp are those who insist such norms must be dictated
by command regulation. This Article suggests an unconventional possibility,
between these conventional bounds. Standardized contract terms may not
evolve efficiently, and yet traditional regulation, with its characteristic
coercion, may not be the appropriate remedy. Drawing on the microeconomics
of network externalities, as well as a relatively unexplored corner of game
theory, I offer an explanation of the seemingly incongruous patterns of
longstanding stasis and abrupt change in sovereign debt contract terms, and
propose a narrowly confined, yet essential and perhaps ongoing, regulatory
role in the evolution of contract boilerplate.
5
4
See G. Mitu Gulati & David A. Skeel, Jr., International Financial Architecture: Has the Financial
World Arrived at a Collective Action Clause Consensus? 6 (June 20, 2003) (unpublished manuscript, on file
with author).
5
Distinct applications of the network theory and coordination game analysis of transition that I explore
in sovereign debt contracting herein can be found in Robert B. Ahdieh, Making Markets: Network Effects and
the Role of Law in the Creation of Strong Securities Markets, 76 S. CAL. L. REV. 277 (2003) [hereinafter
Ahdieh, Making Markets] (outlining network analysis of securities market transition) and Robert B. Ahdieh,
Law’s Signal: A Cueing Theory of Law in Market Transition, 77 S. C
AL. L. REV. 101 (2004) [hereinafter
Ahdieh, Law’s Signal] (developing regulatory cueing theory of law’s role in coordinating transition in network
industries).
In this issue of the Emory Law Journal, Steve Choi and Mitu Gulati offer the results of an empirical
analysis of the presence of network effects in sovereign debt contracting. See Stephen Choi & G. Mitu Gulati,
Innovation in Boilerplate Contracts: An Empirical Examination of Sovereign Bonds, 53 E
MORY L.J. 929
(2004). Supplementing their analysis, this Article considers the possible sources of network effects in
sovereign debt contracting, and their implications. Further, it attempts to theorize what might trigger transition
in network environments, including sovereign debt contracting. Yet, it does not assert any firm conclusion on
the strength of network effects in sovereign debt contracts. Rather, it outlines why network effects might be
predicted in sovereign debt contracts, and suggests the consistency of recent developments in sovereign debt
contracting with the presence of such effects.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
696 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
The dramatic proposal of the International Monetary Fund to create a
bankruptcy court-like Sovereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism (SDRM) and
even more limited suggestions that the IMF or United States mandate the
standardization of sovereign debt contracts
6
are therefore challenged by the
present analysis. The Article also questions, however, the contractual
approach that is posited as the alternative. Rather than a dichotomous choice
between creation of the IMF’s SDRM, or debtors’ voluntary, spontaneous
adoption of standardized (and presumably efficient) collective action clauses,
as the appropriate means to move away from unanimous action provisions and
other inefficient contract terms,
7
I develop and explore a gray area in the
middle. Specifically, I describe a noncoercive “cueing” function for law in
facilitating contractual change, and suggest that the recent shift in sovereign
debt contract terms was driven by just cues. This analysis offers lessons not
only for efficient transition in sovereign debt contract boilerplate, but also for
the role of the state in contract change generally, including in corporate and
real estate contracts, among others.
Part I describes the historical choice between unanimous action and
collective action clauses in sovereign debt contracts, the IMF’s proposal to
create an SDRM to deal with the inefficiencies of unanimous action clauses,
and the recent shift of the market to collective action contract provisions. Part
II develops a conception of sovereign debt contracting as characterized by
network effectsphenomena by which the individual benefits of a particular
good or service, as in the paradigmatic networks of telephone communication
and computer operating systems, grow as the same or compatible goods or
services are purchased by other consumers. Further, Part II suggests how
network effects in sovereign debt contracting can explain not only the
longstanding resistance of the sovereign debt markets to collective action
clauses, but also their abrupt and wholesale adoption of just such clauses over
the course of a few months in 2003.
Part III picks up where the network story leaves off, drawing on a relatively
unfamiliar corner of game theory to explain what might have triggered the
recent shift of the sovereign debt markets from stasis to change.
6
Proposals favoring IMF or U.S. dictation of standardized debt contract terms have arisen largely in the
aftermath of the shift from unanimous action requirements to majoritarian collective action clauses. See infra
notes 277-79 and accompanying text.
7
See William W. Bratton & G. Mitu Gulati, Sovereign Debt Reform and the Best Interest of Creditors,
57 V
AND. L. REV. (forthcoming 2004) (describing alternative arrangements for efficient sovereign debt
restructuring).
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 697
Characterizing sovereign debt contracting as a “coordination game” of sorts, I
identify a role for regulatory cues in transition among the Nash equilibria
embedded in such games. After suggesting some of the possible cues in the
sovereign debt markets’ transition to collective action provisions, I use these
examples to explore the nature of regulatory cues as a distinct mode of state
action. Finally, in Part IV, I consider the ongoing role of regulatory cues in
sovereign debt contract transition, including the inevitable limits of that role. I
conclude by noting the broader implications of cueing forms of regulation for
standardized contracts generally, and perhaps for the growing effort to
introduce transnational regulatory norms and standards from international
finance to antitrust and securities law.
I. T
HE SLOW AND SUDDEN EVOLUTION OF SOVEREIGN DEBT CONTRACTS
Recent challenges to the international regime of sovereign debt
restructuring and dramatic changes in the conventions of sovereign debt
contracting have occurred against the backdrop of longstanding competition
among alternative standards for the restructuring of such debt. The market in
sovereign debt has thus long been characterized by two distinct norms for the
alteration of basic financial terms of sovereign debt contracts.
The majority of sovereign debt contracts, particularly those of emerging
markets, are issued under New York law. With few exceptions, these contracts
have long included unanimous action clauses (UACs) requiring unanimity for
any changes to their basic terms. As a consequence, they erected a significant
barrier to efficient debt restructuring.
8
Most basically, such inefficiency rests
on the substantial collective action obstacles that UACs place on the return of
sovereign debtors to financial health and stability, and to the financial markets
themselves.
9
Under UACs, holdout creditors may resist participation in any
agreed restructuring, absent substantial side payments outside any collective
agreement.
10
This has the potential to delay restructuring, if not to deter the
participation necessary for it to occur at all.
11
In slightly different terms, such
8
See G. Mitu Gulati & Kenneth N. Klee, Sovereign Piracy, 56 BUS. LAW. 635, 642-43 (2001); Steven
L. Schwarcz, Sovereign Debt Restructuring: A Bankruptcy Reorganization Approach, 85 C
ORNELL L. REV.
956, 960-61 (2000).
9
See Marcel Kahan, Rethinking Corporate Bonds: The Trade-Off Between Individual and Collective
Rights, 77 N.Y.U. L. R
EV. 1040, 1054 (2002); Schwarcz, supra note 8, at 960-61, 980.
10
See Kahan, supra note 9, at 1055-56; Schwarcz, supra note 8, at 961.
11
See Schwarcz, supra note 8, at 961.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
698 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
holdouts inevitably increase transaction costs and reduce predictability in
sovereign debt restructuring.
12
Given the latter possibilities, unanimous action requirements may also
increase the moral hazards of sovereign debt. By delaying, if not preventing,
efficient sovereign debt restructuring, UACs increase the prospect of official
sector bailouts. These, in turn, produce the moral hazard of looser restraints on
both lending and borrowing practices, and attendant efficiency losses.
13
To avoid this parade of horribles, collective action clauses (CACs)
the
norm in sovereign debt contracts issued under English law
permit
restructuring by a qualified majority of bondholders. Collective action
provisions have been widely favored by academics and policymakers alike.
Yet their enthusiasm was to little avail. Until early 2003, the market in
sovereign debt continued to be characterized by a dominant preference for
UACs. By the end of the year, however, the tide had turned. UACs had
become largely a historical artifact. Notwithstanding the long resistance to
change, collective action is now the norm in nearly every newly negotiated
sovereign debt contract.
A. Unanimous and Collective Action in Sovereign Debt Restructuring
Since the late nineteenth century, majority voting provisions have been the
norm in sovereign bonds issued under English law, which include a significant
minority of all sovereign bonds.
14
So-called majority action clauses (MACs)
have allowed a supermajority of bondholders to alter the basic financial terms
of the relevant bond issue, including restructuring payments, adjusting interest
rates, and reducing principal.
15
By contrast, sovereign bonds issued under New
12
See Celeste Boeri, How to Solve Argentina’s Debt Crisis: Will the IMF’s Plan Work?, 4 CHI. J. INTL
L. 245, 248 (2003); Lee C. Buchheit & G. Mitu Gulati, Sovereign Bonds and the Collective Will, 51 EMORY
L.J. 1317, 1351 (2002).
13
See Schwarcz, supra note 8, at 961-62, 1004 n.279.
14
Unanimous action provisions have also been the norm in debt issued by Russia. See Nouriel Roubini
& Brad Setser, Improving the Sovereign Debt Restructuring Process: Problems in Restructuring, Proposed
Solutions, and a Roadmap for Reform 13 (Mar. 9, 2003) (unpublished manuscript, on file with author); see
also B
ARRY EICHENGREEN ET AL., CRISIS RESOLUTION: NEXT STEPS 35 nn.47-48 (IMF Working Paper No.
03/196) (forthcoming in B
ROOKINGS TRADE F.).
15
Under the broader rubric of “collective action clauses,” other opportunities for collective action by
creditors, besides majority restructuring, have also been included or proposed in sovereign bond issues.
“Collective representation clauses,” for example, establish a creditor committee or other representative
arrangement for bondholders. “Majority enforcement clauses(or “initiation clauses”) mandate that twenty-
five percent of bondholders approve any acceleration of debt, but allow fifty percent of bondholders to rescind
any such acceleration. Such acceleration provisions, notably, were included in New York law bonds as well.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 699
York law, which constitute the majority of sovereign debt issuances,
16
particularly by emerging markets,
17
have traditionally not permitted majority
See
Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12, at 1335. “Engagement clauses” dictated early and regular interaction of
the sovereign debtor with its bondholders, and outlined the overall process of restructuring. See Press Release,
Under Secretary of Treasury John B. Taylor, Using Clauses to Reform the Process for Sovereign Debt
Workouts: Progress and Next Steps (Dec. 5, 2002) [hereinafter Taylor, Using Clauses],
available at
http://www.ustreas.gov/press/releases/po3672.htm; Press Release, Under Secretary of Treasury John B.
Taylor, Sovereign Debt Restructuring: A U.S. Perspective (Apr. 2, 2002) [hereinafter Taylor, Sovereign Debt
Restructuring], available at http://www.ustreas.gov/press/releases/po2056.htm. Some engagement clauses,
furthermore, also provide for the appointment of a trustee.
See Barry Eichengreen & Ashoka Mody, Is
Aggregation a Problem for Sovereign Debt Restructuring 2 (Jan. 2003) (unpublished manuscript, on file with
author). Finally, a standard provision in nearly every bond contract provides for a majority (or supermajority)
of bondholders to amend the nonfinancial terms of the bond.
Various authors have characterized these collective action provisions in a variety of ways. On the
provisions for collective action in English MACs, see Andrew Yianni, Resolution of Sovereign Financial
Crises—Evolution of the Private Sector Restructuring Process, FIN. STABILITY REV., June 1999, at 78. More
generally, on the various types of CACs, see Barry Eichengreen,
Restructuring Sovereign Debt, J. E
CON.
P
ERSP., Fall 2003, at 83-84, and Eichengreen & Mody, supra, at 2. See also Jack Boorman, Alternative
Approaches to Sovereign Debt Restructuring, 23 C
ATO J. 59, 65 (2003) (suggesting alternative characterization
of various CACs); Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7 (same); Arturo C. Porzecanski, A Critique of Sovereign
Bankruptcy Initiatives, B
US. ECON., Jan. 2003, at 39, 40. On the U.S. Department of the Treasury’s
conception of the various CACs, see Taylor, Using Clauses, supra, and Taylor, Sovereign Debt Restructuring,
supra. Finally, to a similar extent, Nouriel Roubini and Brad Setser have described four potential
configurations of the various contract provisions for sovereign debt restructuring: (1) The use of New York
law documentation, which requires the unanimous consent of all creditors to change “key financial terms”
(defined as payment dates and amounts), is the first possibility. All other terms would be subject to
amendment by one-half to two-thirds of bondholders. Some New York law bonds, furthermore, require the
support of twenty-five percent of bondholders to initiate litigation. (2) The second configuration involves the
adoption of English law documentation, which allows seventy-five percent of bondholders present at any
meeting at which there is quorum to amend any terms. Litigation limitations are also common in English law
bonds. (3) Another option, the draft clauses prepared by the G-10, would adopt the English law convention,
with additional provisions to encourage the use of trustees and thereby facilitate communication. (4) Finally,
the Group of Six, comprised of major creditors, has also drafted proposed terms, which would allow
amendment of a broader set of “financial terms” by eighty-five percent of bondholders, so long as no more
than ten percent of bondholders object. Other terms can be amended by seventy-five percent of bondholders,
with the exception of terms concerning the ability of creditors to sue, which would not be subject to
amendment. Finally, the debtor would have to meet additional disclosure requirements and would be liable for
the expenses of a creditor committee. See Roubini & Setser, supra note 14, at 8-9; see also Buchheit & Gulati,
supra note 12, at 1329.
16
See Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7. Thus, the sovereign debt market is primarily divided between
English and New York law bonds. See id. at 30; Eichengreen, supra note 15, at 84, 85 tbl.2 (noting that at the
end of 2001, seventy percent of international sovereign bonds outstanding were issued under New York or
German law); Richard Portes, The Role of Institutions for Collective Action, in M
ANAGING FINANCIAL AND
CORPORATE DISTRESS: LESSONS FROM ASIA 64 (Charles Adams et al. eds., 2000); see also EICHENGREEN ET
AL., supra note 14, at 3 nn.2-3, 35 n.47; Eichengreen & Mody, supra note 15, at 8; Porzecanski, supra note 15,
at 39, 40 n.4; Roubini & Setser, supra note 14, at 13 n.9; Taylor, Using Clauses, supra note 15.
17
See Ashoka Mody, What Is an Emerging Market? (Apr. 2004) (unpublished manuscript, on file with
author).
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
700 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
action, but instead required unanimous action for changes to the basic financial
terms.
18
The divergence between London and New York restructuring provisions
can be traced back to corporate bond issuances in England and the United
States in the late nineteenth century. In the early 1800s, corporate bonds in
England and elsewhere included no provision for collective decisionmaking.
19
Rather, alteration of payment terms could only be accomplished with the
unanimous consent of bondholders.
20
Yet this requirement led to the forced
liquidation of many borrowers that faced merely a liquidity, rather than
solvency, crisis.
21
In addition, it allowed holdout creditors to threaten
liquidation, in order to secure side payments at the expense of other creditors.
22
To overcome these difficulties, in 1879, Francis Beaufort Palmer, an English
barrister, introduced the possibility of majority action clauses in corporate
bond issues.
23
Such clauses would permit a supermajority of creditors to
approve a deferment or change in payment terms, which would then be binding
on all creditors.
24
Such clauses quickly caught on, and remain a standard
feature of both corporate and sovereign bonds issued under English law. For
the minority of sovereign debtors that issue their debt under English law,
including even a few developing country debtors, who generally issue under
New York law, majority action is therefore available to overcome collective
action obstacles to debt restructuring.
In the United States, by contrast, MACs were not widely introduced in the
late 1800s, for at least three reasons.
25
First, issuers and investors worried that
bonds containing MACs would not qualify as negotiable instruments and
would therefore lack marketability.
26
Second, in the late nineteenth century,
when MACs were coming into fashion in England, the majority of U.S. bonds
were being issued to foreign investors who, it was feared, might hesitate to buy
18
The same was long true of bonds issued under German law, see Taylor, Using Clauses, supra note 15,
and Japanese law, see Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7.
19
See Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12, at 1324.
20
See id.
21
Such borrowers could well have been saved by a short deferment or reduction in payments. See id.
22
See id.
23
See id. at 1325; see also EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 32.
24
See Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12, at 1324.
25
Other reasons might also be offered for the absence of MACs in New York law bonds. See Bratton &
Gulati, supra note 7; see also David A. Skeel, Jr., Can Majority Voting Provisions Do It All?, 52 E
MORY L.J.
417 (2003).
26
See Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12, at 1326 (noting negotiable instruments law requirement that
bonds contain “an unconditional promise or order to pay a sum certain in money”).
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 701
bonds that could be altered by majority vote.
27
Finally, due to a wave of
mergers in the 1800s, the corporate structure of most U.S. railroads
the
primary issuer of corporate bonds
was extremely complex, with the number
of different classes of bonds too great for MACs to be effective.
28
In lieu of MACs, the United States employed a variety of other methods to
assist financially distressed debtors and avoid holdout creditor problems.
Around 1848, debtors and creditors turned to equity receiverships, by which a
court appointed a receiver for borrowers nearing default, in conjunction with
whom the debtor and its creditors negotiated a reorganization plan.
29
Most
commonly, such plans involved selling the debtor’s assets to a new company
organized by creditors of the old company.
30
Potential holdout creditors
generally agreed to these plans for lack of any viable alternative.
31
The use of equity receiverships, however, began to decline after creation of
the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) in 1934. One of the
SEC’s first acts was to prepare a report that concluded that equity receiverships
were unfair to investors.
32
Yet the SEC did not have a taste for MACs either.
It feared that corporate insiders who owned equity in financially distressed
borrowers would buy up a majority of MAC bonds,
33
and then vote to defer
payment or change the terms of those bonds. The equity owners would
thereby invert “the normal priorities in a corporate bankruptcy by which a
company’s debt holders are paid off before the equity holders.”
34
Thus, instead of promoting MACs as a substitute for equity receiverships,
Congress added section 77B to the U.S. Bankruptcy Act in 1934. A precursor
to Chapter 11, section 77B provided for debt reorganization under the
supervision of a bankruptcy court. With the knowledge that debtors could now
avoid liquidation, by relying on section 77B,
35
Congress went further, to enact
section 316(b) of the Trust Indenture Act (TIA).
36
This section essentially
precluded the introduction of MACs in corporate bond instruments, by
27
See Skeel, supra note 25, at 420.
28
See id. at 420-21.
29
See Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12, at 1327.
30
See id.
31
See id.
32
See SEC. AND EXCH. COMMN, REPORT ON THE STUDY AND INVESTIGATION OF THE WORK, ACTIVITIES,
P
ERSONNEL AND FUNCTIONS OF PROTECTIVE AND REORGANIZATION COMMITTEES 10-60 (1937-1940).
33
See Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12, at 1328.
34
Id.
35
See id. at 1329.
36
Trust Indenture Act of 1939, ch. 411, 53 Stat. 1172 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 77 (2000)).
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
702 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
“prohibit[ing] any reduction in the amount due under a publicly issued
corporate bond without the consent of each affected bondholder.”
37
U.S.
corporate bonds therefore became unanimous action bonds, by definition.
38
The TIA’s bar on collective action, however, did not speak to sovereign
bond issuances. Nonetheless, nearly all sovereign debt issued under New York
law came to exclude MACs as well. Among other explanations for this
pattern, it has been suggested that drafting inertia in the large law firm practice
groups often responsible for drafting both types of debt contracts
a path
dependence of form contracts
may be behind this pattern.
39
The network
theory of sovereign debt contracting offered herein might also be important.
40
Regardless of the particular cause, unanimous action requirements came to
dominate sovereign debt contracts to nearly the same extent they did corporate
debt. Given emerging markets’ preference for New York law, meanwhile,
UACs emerged as the dominant norm in sovereign debt contracts as a whole.
B. Holdout Creditors and the Bumpy Road to Debt Restructuring
As noted above, unanimous action requirements give rise to significant
collective action problems in sovereign debt restructuring.
41
In essence,
unanimous action provisions require a difficult and time-consuming, if not
impossible, effort to secure the agreement of every creditor, in order for a
restructuring plan to proceed.
42
UACs thus enable a dissenting, holdout
creditor to sue for full repayment, and thus delay restructuring until the debtor
or other creditors pay a premium to secure the holdout’s agreement.
43
The
possibility of this result, of course, may deter creditors as a whole from
consenting to a restructuring plan, preventing the return of the sovereign debtor
37
Id. It bears noting that the English regime does not rely exclusively on MACs to facilitate corporate
restructuring, but now has its own bankruptcy process. Even if all relevant bonds of a given corporation
include MACs, other debts of the corporation necessarily require some form of bankruptcy regime.
38
Until the adoption of the TIA in 1939, MACs were relatively rare in the United States, but not unheard
of. See Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7. See generally Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12. Thus, the sharp
divergence between New York and English law debt restructuring provisions is of recent provenance. See
Portes, supra note 16, at 68 n.43.
39
Cf. Marcel Kahan & Michael Klausner, Standardization and Innovation in Corporation Contracting
(Or “The Economics of Boilerplate”), 83 V
A. L. REV. 713, 718 (1997); Michael Klausner, Corporations,
Corporate Law, and Networks of Contracts, 81 V
A. L. REV. 757, 762, 785 n.89 (1995).
40
See infra Part II.B.
41
See supra notes 8-13 and accompanying text.
42
See Felix Salmon, Bond Investors Feel the Pinch, EUROMONEY, Nov. 2002, at 90.
43
See Lee C. Buchheit, Majority Action Clauses May Help Resolve Debt Crisis, INTL FIN. L. REV., Aug.
1998, at 13.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 703
to financial health and stability.
44
In the case of corporate debt, this strategic
dynamic is readily curtailed. The bankruptcy system, with its automatic stay
and other restructuing provisions, obviates holdout creditor problems in
corporate restructuring. In the international financial order, however, no
bankruptcy regime is available as a fall back. Nor are creditors likely to find
significant assets to attach.
45
Consequently, holdout creditor and other
collective action obstacles are far greater barriers to sovereign debt
restructuring than corporate restructuring.
46
Until the 1990s, however, holdout creditors remained a limited concern
even in sovereign debt restructuring, because notwithstanding the prior use of
bonds in sovereign finance,
47
the primary source of emerging market financing
by the 1980s was syndicated bank loans.
48
Sovereign debt creditors were
primarily repeat player banks with concentrated holdings. Expectations of
future encounters, and resulting reputational constraints, reduced the incentive
to hold out for more favorable restructuring terms.
49
Following the emerging
44
See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 939; Christopher C. Wheeler & Amir Attaran, Declawing the
Vulture Funds: Rehabilitation of a Comity Defense in Sovereign Debt Litigation, 39 S
TAN. J. INTL L. 253,
259-60 (2003).
45
See Schwarcz, supra note 8, at 960 n.16. The political dimensions of sovereign financial distress also
distinguish it from domestic corporate bankruptcy.
46
The nearly universal application of the TIA’s bar on majority action to sovereign debt contracts,
not withstanding its formal inapplicability, is particularly puzzling in this light. See supra notes 36-40 and
accompanying text.
47
See Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12, at 1334-35.
48
See Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7; Eichengreen, supra note 15, at 81; Barry Eichengreen & Richard
Portes, Debt Restructuring With and Without the IMF 15, 17 (Feb. 2000) (unpublished manuscript, on file
with author).
49
See Benjamin Klein & Keith Leffler, The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual
Performance, 89 J. P
OL. ECON. 615 (1981). Sovereign debt restructuring can be modeled as a standard-form
Prisoner’s Dilemma game among creditors. In this familiar dynamic, a creditor will secure a higher payoff if
he, and he alone, defects from an agreed restructuring plan by demanding, for example, a side payment for his
participation. If all creditors act on this common incentive, however, the ultimate payoff to each creditor is
lower than if none had defected from the original agreement. In sovereign debt contracting, the latter would
occur if the sovereign debtor simply declined to restructure, or pay, as Argentina essentially has in recent
years.
One way to avoid defection in Prisoner’s Dilemma games, however, is through repeat plays. See
R
OBERT AXELROD, THE EVOLUTION OF COOPERATION 10-11 (1984); Richard L. Revesz, Congressional
Influence on Judicial Behavior? An Empirical Examination of Challenges to Agency Action in the D.C.
Circuit, 76 N.Y.U. L. R
EV. 1100, 1111 (2001). In essence, if a given participant knows that he will participate
in the game successively, the return on any single defection, even if successfully executed (i.e., even if other
players do not respond by altering their strategy), is dwarfed by the losses that follow from the relevant
player’s subsequent inability to secure agreement with its counterparts. In repeat Prisoner’s Dilemma games,
defection ceases to be a productive strategy. For this reason, a sovereign debt market financed by a handful of
large banks—as distinct from the present financing of sovereign debt by an innumerable, anonymous, and
constantly changing collection of small, individual bondholders—was less susceptible to holdout problems.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
704 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
market debt crises of the 1980s, however, banks largely pulled out of emerging
market finance and the sovereign debt markets turned back to bonds.
50
Yet
bonds aggravate holdout creditor problems, and creditor coordination problems
generally, because of the dispersion of bond debt among a wide universe of
small, anonymous players, who are less likely to be subject to repeat player
constraints.
51
This dynamic is further aggravated by the tradable nature of the
relevant bonds.
52
The holders of a given sovereign bond issue are not only
numerous and difficult to identify; they are constantly changing.
53
Citing the consequent inefficiencies of unanimous action requirements, a
growing array of academics and practitioners, developed countries, and official
sector institutions, including the IMF, began to press for the abandonment of
UACs in New York law bonds. The G-10 highlighted this need with its call
for the replacement of UACs with CACs in 1996.
54
Encouragement from other
international and national bodies, as well as individual attorneys, economists,
and others, quickly followed.
55
Yet the market exhibited little receptivity to
change. While English law bonds, as well as those of certain other
jurisdictions, continued to include MACs, New York law bonds, encompassing
the largest share of the sovereign debt market, continued to be issued with
UACs, rather than CACs. UAC bonds were particularly preferred by emerging
market debtors, moreover, for whom the choice of restructuring terms was
Other collective action problems, including an inability to communicate effectively, were also of diminished
importance.
50
See Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7.
51
See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 939; Ronald J. Silverman & Mark W. Deveno, Distressed
Sov ereign Debt: A Creditor’s Perspective, 11 A
M. BANK. INST. L. REV. 179, 179-80, 183-84 (2003); Wheeler
& Attaran, supra note 44, at 253 n.2; see also James A. Dorn, International Financial Crises: What Role for
Government?, 23 C
ATO J. 1, 3 (2003); Eichengreen & Portes, supra note 48, at 21-22; Portes, supra note 16, at
63 (noting increased complexity of sovereign debt compositions following shift from bank to bond financing,
given increased number of interested parties who are less susceptible to central bank pressure).
52
See Silverman & Deveno, supra note 51, at 183-84. See generally Wheeler & Attaran, supra note 44,
at 253.
53
Yakov Amihud, Kenneth Garbade, and Marcel Kahan have described this dynamic as the dispersion
and fluidity of bondholders. See Yakov Amihud et al., A New Governance Structure for Corporate Bonds, 51
S
TAN. L. REV. 447, 450 (1999).
54
See Boorman, supra note 15, at 65; Anna Gelpern, How Collective Action Is Changing Sovereign
Debt, I
NTL FIN. L. REV., May 2003, at 19; Portes, supra note 16, at 66, 69-70 (describing G-7’s
encouragement of CACs); Barry Eichengreen, Crisis Resolution: Why We Need a Krueger-Like Process to
Obtain a Taylor-Like Result 10 (Apr. 29, 2002) (unpublished manuscript, on file with author) [hereinafter
Eichengreen, Crisis Resolution]; see also Barry Eichengreen, Is Greater Private-Sector Burden Sharing
Impossible?, in R
EFORMING THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY AND FINANCIAL SYSTEM 10 (Peter Kenen &
Alexander Swoboda eds., 2000).
55
See Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12, at 1358; Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 973; Gulati & Skeel,
supra note 4, at 1-2.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 705
most important. No amount of pressure seemed to have any impact on this
pattern.
1. An International Bankruptcy Regime?
In November 2001, in the wake of the dramatic collapse of the Argentine
economy and ensuing social chaos, Anne Krueger, Deputy Managing Director
of the IMF, proposed a radical restructuring of the international financial
architecture by introducing a bankruptcy regime for sovereign states.
Specifically, she proposed the creation of a Sovereign Debt Restructuring
Mechanism under the auspices of the IMF, charged with facilitating efficient
debt restructuring and thereby minimizing the need for the massive debt
bailouts that had littered the 1990s.
56
As originally outlined, the IMF’s SDRM
plan was based on Chapter 11 of the U.S. Bankruptcy Code, and sought to
define a binding set of rules that would allow crisis-stricken countries to work
out their debts in an orderly fashion.
57
It also granted the IMF extensive new
powers and placed decisionmaking authority squarely with the IMF,
58
drawing
strong attacks.
59
The plan was consequently modified, with the IMF proposing
a “twin track approach” to sovereign debt restructuring in 2002.
60
This revised
proposal incorporated both a “contractual approach,” encouraging the use of
CACs in bond issuances, and a “statutory approach,” which called for an
56
See Boorman, supra note 15, at 62; Eichengreen & Mody, supra note 15, at 3; Gulati & Skeel, supra
note 4, at 3; see also Battling Over the Bankrupt, E
CONOMIST, Oct. 5, 2002; Jennifer Galloway, What CACs
Lack, L
ATINFINANCE, Dec. 2003, at 24.
57
See Susanne Soederberg, The International Dimensions of the Argentine Default: The Case of the
Sov ereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism, 28 C
AN. J. LATIN AM. & CARIBBEAN STUD. 97, 115 (2003). The
country in crisis would be able to halt debt payments as it negotiated debt restructuring with private sector
lenders, under the auspices of a new international judicial body. During such negotiations, the IMF would
protect the debtor country from litigation. Ultimately, the conditions of repayment would be determined by a
supermajority vote of the creditors. The terms would then be binding on all creditors and the debtor country.
See id. The voting process would be overseen by the IMF, which would also adjudicate any disputes that
arose. See generally Paul Blustein, Bankruptcy System for Nations Fails to Draw Support, W
ASH. POST, Apr.
2, 2003, at A14.
58
See Soederberg, supra note 57, at 115.
59
See id. The U.S. Treasury’s criticism was driven at least in part by the fierce opposition to the SDRM
on Wall Street, where bankers warned that capital flows to emerging markets would dry up if creditor rights
were infringed. See Blustein, supra note 57. Emerging market governments likewise resisted the SDRM out
of fear of losing access to cheap foreign funds. See id. Investors, finally, believed that the SDRM would
submerge their interests to junior creditor status, causing the IMF to be repaid first, and in full, ahead of
bondholders and other private sector creditors. See Felix Salmon, SDRM Finds Few Friends in the Market,
E
UROMONEY, Nov. 1, 2002, at 94.
60
See Porzecanski, supra note 15, at 40.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
706 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
SDRM, but with greater creditor control and no new powers for the IMF.
61
In
particular, the new plan eliminated the IMF’s control over any temporary
suspension of payments and the precise restructuring of the debt.
62
The revised SDRM would thus permit a supermajority of creditors to
approve a debt restructuring agreement with the debtor country, either in
anticipation of or after default.
63
Minority creditors would be bound by this
restructuring agreement, thereby avoiding holdouts.
64
A supermajority of
creditors could also vote to stay any litigation while the restructuring
negotiations were proceeding in order to protect the sovereign’s assets from
deleterious legal action.
65
To facilitate ongoing economic activity, the creditors
could also vote to give seniority to new private financing.
66
More
controversially, the SDRM would provide a dispute resolution forum, akin to
an international bankruptcy court, to administer creditor claims and resolve
disputes between debtors and creditors.
67
This dispute resolution forum would
have exclusive jurisdiction and its decisions would be legally binding on all
IMF member nations.
68
The SDRM proposal was seen by its proponents as having several
advantages over CACs as a solution to the shortcomings of UACs, even
assuming the market’s longstanding resistance to CACs could actually be
overcome. First, upon ratification of the SDRM, its provisions would be
immediately applicable to all sovereign debt, including previously issued
bonds.
69
Thus, the SDRM would universalize the treatment of sovereign debt.
70
By contrast, because of their contractual nature, CACs would only apply to
those future bonds in which they were included. To achieve greater
universality, sovereign debtors would have to agree to exchange existing bonds
with UACs for new CAC bonds, potentially at great cost and only after an
extended delay. Additionally, while CACs permit restructuring of a single
debt instrument, they do not effectively facilitate coordination among creditors
61
See Boeri, supra note 12, at 246; Battling Over the Bankrupt, supra note 56. On the revised proposal,
see Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7.
62
See Soederberg, supra note 57, at 117.
63
See Boorman, supra note 15, at 62.
64
See id.
65
See id.
66
See id.
67
See Boeri, supra note 12, at 248.
68
See id. The SDRM would be created by amending the IMF’s Articles of Agreement, by a two-thirds
vote of IMF shares. See id. at 247.
69
See Boorman, supra note 15, at 62; Gelpern, supra note 54, at 20.
70
See Salmon, supra note 59, at 94.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 707
holding distinct debt instruments.
71
The SDRM, on the other hand, could serve
to coordinate restructuring more generally.
72
Finally, proponents of the SDRM
argued that its bankruptcy tribunal would help promote good faith among
creditors and between creditors and debtors, an essential need that might be
more difficult to accomplish by way of a contractual approach.
73
Yet there were also strong criticisms of the SDRM proposal. Perhaps most
broadly, the SDRM was seen by many as a significant invasion of national
sovereignty, well beyond existingand already controversial
forms of IMF
conditionality. To similar effect, the SDRM was criticized as a gross
interference in the contractual autonomy of sovereign debtors and their
creditors. In essence, an SDRM would rewrite bond contracts after the fact,
notwithstanding the parties’ indisputable awareness of the substantial potential
for financial crises, and their decision not to address that potential
prospectively, by contract. Following directly from the latter, the SDRM’s
diminishment of creditor rights was unsurprisingly objected to by creditors.
However, it was also a concern for debtor states, which feared an increased
cost of capital, if not exclusion from the international debt markets, if an
SDRM were introduced.
74
Institutional concerns were also voiced. In
particular, given that the IMF is a party to the relevant sovereign credit
relationship, as a creditor, a preference for IMF interests might be expected in
any SDRM-driven restructuring. Unless complete independence from the IMF
could be assured, private creditor interests might therefore be especially
jeopardized under an SDRM. Finally, particularly given the foregoing array of
risks and the substantial costs of an SDRM, many questioned whether such a
regime was even necessary.
75
2. Institutional Versus Contractual Remedies to the Restructuring Dilemma
With the IMF’s SDRM proposal in November 2001, the battle between
institutional change and contractual change in the evolution of the sovereign
debt regime was joined. To one side stood those who continued to encourage
the replacement of UACs with CACs as the appropriate, and fully adequate,
remedy to the collective action problems of the existing UAC regime. Most
71
See Boorman, supra note 15, at 62.
72
See id.; Gelpern, supra note 54, at 20.
73
See Gelpern, supra note 54, at 20; see also infra notes 302-10 and accompanying text.
74
See Hal S. Scott, A Bankruptcy Forum for Sovereign Debtors?, 37 INTL LAW. 103, 103 (2003).
75
On the criticisms of the SDRM, see Eichengreen, Crisis Resolution, supra note 54, at 18-20. See also
supra note 59.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
708 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
prominently, this group included the United States, most private creditor
representatives and institutions, and even a number of emerging market
debtors. On the other side were those, including the leadership of the IMF and
a substantial part of its membership, that favored adoption of an SDRM of one
sort or another.
76
At least at the outset, the United States and several other G-7
members resisted any alternative to the contractual approach of CACs.
77
At the
IMF’s 2002 annual meeting, however, the G-7 endorsed the IMF’s “twin track
approach,” including the SDRM.
78
Even the United States signaled some
receptivity to the SDRM.
79
Many saw this endorsement as purely strategic, however, serving to signal
to emerging market debtors and private sector lenders that if they resisted the
United States’s preferred approach of CACs for too long, things might prove
much worse.
80
This assessment arguably gains credence from the IMF’s
ensuing decision, made at the April 2003 meeting of the International
Monetary and Financial Committees, to prioritize the contractual approach and
put the SDRM proposal on hold.
81
Rather than finalize an SDRM proposal at
the meeting, as was intended, the IMF instead abandoned it in favor of the
contractual approach.
82
Yet this decision was not entirely surprising, given the much more dramatic
announcement by Mexico, only a few weeks earlier, that it was offering an
unexpected $1 billion bond issue. The latter would be issued under New York
law. Breaking with the nearly universal convention, however, Mexico
announced that the bond would include CACs.
83
The new bond contracts thus
permitted amendment of basic financial terms, including payment and timing
terms, upon approval of seventy-five percent of aggregated principal amounts
76
See Boorman, supra note 15, at 62. Generally, support for the SDRM was stronger in Europe than the
United States. See Alan Beattie, U.S. Set to Block “Sovereign Chapter 11” Proposals, F
IN. TIMES, Mar. 31,
2003, at 13; Blustein, supra note 57.
77
See Boeri, supra note 12, at 246; see also Bush Plan to Let Struggling Nations Rework Payment Terms
Backed, B
OSTON GLOBE, Apr. 10, 2002, at C7.
78
See Boeri, supra note 12, at 246-47; Felix Salmon, Market Resists Restructuring Reform,
E
UROMONEY, Oct. 1, 2002, at 18.
79
See Taylor, Using Clauses, supra note 15; see also Gulati & Skeel, supra note 4, at 3; infra Part
III.B.1.
80
See Battling Over the Bankrupt, supra note 56; Beattie, supra note 76, at 13.
81
See Rupert Cornwell, U.S. Forces IMF to Shelve Debt Default Scheme, INDEPENDENT, Apr. 11, 2003,
at 22; Dealing with Default, E
CONOMIST, May 10, 2003, at 63.
82
See EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 3.
83
See id. at 3, 9; Gelpern, supra note 54, at 19.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 709
outstanding.
84
Contrary to long-standing speculation, moreover, investors did
not impose any discount on the bonds, notwithstanding their inclusion of
CACs.
85
With Mexico’s decision, the floodgates quickly opened. Mexico issued an
additional $2.5 billion in New York law bonds in April 2003, again with
collective action provisions.
86
On April 10, 2003, Uruguay followed Mexico’s
lead, offering an exchange of its existing UAC bonds for new bonds with
CACs.
87
Uruguay’s CACs were similar to those in the Mexican issuance, but
also included a limit on future exit consents,
88
a bar on issuing new debt to
dilute a restructuring vote, and a tighter set of nonreserve amendment rules.
89
In addition, the Uruguay exchange contract included the first aggregation
voting provision, or “super-CAC,” in a bond.
90
In essence, this provision will
allow Uruguay’s creditors to amend multiple bond instruments in a single vote.
This surprising trend toward CACs in New York law bonds continued with
Brazil’s issuance of $1 billion in New York bonds containing CACs on April
29, 2003.
91
The latter represented yet a further leap forward, as Brazil was the
first speculative grade issuer to use CACs; that it did so with an eighty-five
percent threshold for restructuring, versus the seventy-five percent standard of
English law and the recent New York law bonds, was yet a further
innovation.
92
Brazil’s issuance was quickly followed by new CAC issues by
South Africa and South Korea.
93
Finally, Argentina announced that it too
would include CACs in its new debt issues.
94
By the end of 2003,
consequently, the contracting norm under New York law had come to dictate
84
See EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 3, 9.
85
See id.; see also Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 973. In point of fact, even prior to Mexico’s issue,
other sovereign debt issues under New York law had included CACs, but their small size, private placement,
or other exceptional characteristics seem to have kept them off observers’ radar screens. These included
placements by Thailand, Lebanon, Egypt, and Qatar. See E
ICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 3, 9; Bratton
& Gulati, supra note 7; see also Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 961-62.
86
See EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 3, 9.
87
See Dealing with Default, supra note 81, at 63.
88
See infra notes 243-44 and accompanying text.
89
See Gelpern, supra note 54, at 21-23.
90
See id.; Gulati & Skeel, supra note 4, at 4-5; Dealing with Default, supra note 81, at 63. On
Uruguay’s various innovations, see Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 946.
91
See Skeel, supra note 25, at 418 n.3; Dealing with Default, supra note 81, at 63.
92
See EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 3, 9. Guatemala has since also adopted an eighty-five
percent threshold. See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 981.
93
See Jacques de Larosiere, Reality Hits Debt Restructuring Debate, BANKER, Sept. 2003, at 26.
94
See Gulati & Skeel, supra note 4, at 5. Yet additional countries have since followed. See Choi &
Gulati, supra note 5, at 945, 949.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
710 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
the incorporation of collective action provisions for restructuring.
95
After
nearly a century of the persistent dichotomy of unanimous and collective
action restructuring provisions, years of unrequited pressure on New York law
issuers to shift from UACs to CACs, and every reasonable expectation that
nothing would change anytime soon, it did
overnight.
II. A NETWORK THEORY OF SOVEREIGN DEBT CONTRACTING
In the face of the long resistance of the New York law sovereign debt
market to the seeming efficiencies of collective action, and its consequently
surprising, yet rapid and wholesale, embrace of the latter in 2003, many have
puzzled over the nature and dynamics of sovereign debt contracting and legal
transition. Gulati and Skeel have described the recent shift as more in the
nature of “science” than “rational actor economics.”
96
Yet both the stasis and
change in New York law sovereign bond contract practice can be understood
from an economic perspective. It is the perspective of microeconomics,
however, rather than the more familiar macroeconomics of sovereign debt and
international finance. Specifically, the microeconomic phenomenon of
network effects suggests there should be little surprise at the otherwise
incongruous patterns of stasis and change in sovereign debt contracting.
97
A. Toward a Network Conception of Sovereign Debt Contracting
Network effects arise when the utility of a good to one user increases as
other users acquire or utilize it.
98
A telephone, for example, is only valuable to
95
See Dealing with Default, supra note 81, at 63.
96
See Gulati & Skeel, supra note 4, at 6.
97
While the analysis herein seeks to describe the broad influences of network effects in sovereign debt
contracting, it is not intended to deny the importance of individual and institutional agency in the actualization
of the network outcomes I identify. To the contrary, network effects in sovereign debt contracting are
important insofar as they alter the strategic calculus of individual debtors and creditors. Given network
effects, thus, I suggest that parties to sovereign debt contracts are more likely to affirmatively choose a
dominant standard or term, rather than an otherwise preferable, but less common, standard or term. Network
effects in sovereign debt contracting are thus not abstractions that stand behind market design; they are
concrete elements in shaping the consumption patterns of individual market participants.
98
See Mark A. Lemley & David McGowan, Legal Implications of Network Economic Effects, 86 CAL. L.
R
EV. 479, 481 (1998) (describing network markets as those “in which the value that consumers place on a
good increases as others use the good”); Howard A. Shelanski & J. Gregory Sidak, Antitrust Divestiture in
Network Industries, 68 U. C
HI. L. REV. 1, 5 (2001) (“A network externality, or ‘network effect,’ exists when
the value of a product or service increases with the breadth of demand for that product or service.”); see also
Gideon Parchomovsky, Publish or Perish, 98 MICH. L. REV. 926, 945 (2000); Larry E. Ribstein & Bruce H.
Kobayashi, Choice of Form and Network Externalities, 43 W
M. & MARY L. REV. 79, 110 (2001). I use the
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 711
me if others own receivers as well. More importantly, its value to me grows as
additional receivers are purchased and placed into service.
99
Of greatest
importance for present purposes, the presence of such network effects can
impact consumption patterns. Network effects are thus a form of positive
consumption externality. The social gain from my adoption of a given network
technology can be expected to exceed my individual gain. Consumption may
therefore be suboptimal. Additionally, given the relative importance of
network size to a given consumer, the latter will adopt a relatively “inferior”
good (i.e., one that provides fewer desired services or capacities), if it
nonetheless possesses a larger network of users than its (otherwise superior)
competitor. In the aggregate, substantial welfare inefficiencies may result.
Scholars have argued that network effects may influence the choice of
terms in corporate contracts, including corporate bond indentures. Most
prominently, Michael Klausner and Marcel Kahan have drawn on network
economics to challenge the efficiency assumptions of corporate law’s
contractarian paradigm.
100
In essence, they argue that contracting parties will
term “network effects,” rather than “network externalities,” as the latter would seem to assume a market
failure, which may or may not arise from any given network effect. See S. J. Liebowitz & Stephen E.
Margolis, Network Externality: An Uncommon Tragedy, J. ECON. PERSP., Spring 1994, at 133, 135; see also
Lemley & McGowan, supra, at 482 n.5.
99
See Klausner, supra note 39, at 772; Lemley & McGowan, supra note 98, at 488 (noting that “owning
the only telephone or fax machine in the world would be of little benefit because it could not be used to
communicate with anyone”). On the growth in network utility with additional users, see Michael L. Katz &
Carl Shapiro, Network Externalities, Competition, and Compatibility, 75 A
M. ECON. REV. 424 (1985); Lemley
& McGowan, supra note 98, at 488–89 (“The value of the telephone or fax machine one has already purchased
increases with each additional purchaser, so long as all machines operate on the same standards and the
network infrastructure is capable of processing all member communications.”).
By contrast with the telephone, the owner of a particular tea kettle may find great utility in its water
capacity, built-in whistle, or other inherent qualities, but has relatively little interest in the number of other tea
drinkers, let alone users of their particular kettle. The utility derived from a tea kettle thus turns on its inherent
value, while that of a telephone arises from the size of its network of users. See Carmine Di Noia, Competition
and Integration Among Stock Exchanges in Europe: Network Effects, Implicit Mergers and Remote Access, 7
E
UR. FIN. MGMT. 39, 52 (2001) (“Positive network externalities (the benefit to an individual increases in the
number of others on the system) arise when a good is more valuable to a user the more users adopt the same
good or a compatible one.”); Katz & Shapiro, supra, at 424 (“[T]he utility that a given user derives from the
good depends upon the number of other users who are in the same ‘network.’”).
100
See Kahan & Klausner, supra note 39; Klausner, supra note 39; see also Lucian Arye Bebchuck,
Federalism and the Corporation: The Desirable Limits on State Competition in Corporate Law, 105 H
ARV. L.
R
EV. 1435, 1498-94 (1992); Jeffrey N. Gordon, The Mandatory Structure of Corporate Law, 89 COLUM. L.
R
EV. 1549, 1567-69 (1989). Initially, Klausner argued that network externalities might be present in corporate
contract terms. See Klausner, supra note 39, at 774-75. Together, Kahan and Klausner elaborated on this
analysis, identifying two important sources of value in standard contract terms: (1) learning benefits” that
arise when a firm adopts a contract term that has been commonly used in the past, regardless of whether firms
will continue to use it in the future, see Klausner, supra note 39, at 776 n.61, 779, and (2) “network benefits”
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
712 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
commonly elect to adopt a more widespread contract term
one whose
existing and future user base is larger
because such standardized terms offer
substantial value above and beyond the intrinsic, or inherent, value of the term,
in isolation.
101
Such network benefits of a particular corporate contract term
are analogous to the benefits of conventional network goods, such as personal
computers, which produce greater or lesser value to users depending on
whether they are used commonly or rarely.
102
An IBM-compatible personal
computer thus produces two categories of benefits. First, there are its inherent
benefits, arising from uses unrelated to the number of other individuals that use
a compatible model. The ease of typing a letter on a particular word processor,
for example, might be construed as an inherent benefit of a given computer
system.
103
A computer also offers network benefits, however, which are
dependent “on how many people own [and will own] PCs and thereby create
markets for compatible software, hardware, and repair services.” As a result,
“widespread use of a PC has a value to a user independent of the inherent value
of the product.”
104
that arise when a firm adopts a term that will be simultaneously included in other firms’ contracts and will
consequently be used in the future, see Kahan & Klausner, supra note 39, at 719-25; Klausner, supra note 39,
at 786, 788, regardless of whether it has been widely used in the past. See generally Kahan & Klausner, supra
note 39, at 718.
Although it is not the focus of this Article, a brief explanation of Klausner and Kahan’s learning
benefits is in order. Learning benefits are a component of the inherent value of a term, gained through
previous experience with it. See id.; see also Lemley & McGowan, supra note 98, at 568 (“Learning benefits
refer to the value imbued in a given term through previous experience . . . . [F]or purposes of network theory,
Klausner categorizes these as inherent rather than network benefits, reserving the latter term for those benefits
accruing through contemporaneous use of a term by other firms.”). In essence, a contract term that has been
commonly used in the past may have generated a degree of learning that is valuable to current users of that
term. See Kahan & Klausner, supra note 39, at 719. In Kahan and Klausner’s enumeration, such learning
benefits arise in at least three ways. First, the potential for error is lower, when the present formulation of a
term reflects improvements made in the past, based on implementation in a variety of circumstances, and
examination and reform by many prior users. See id. at 720-21. Second, learning benefits come in the form of
past precedents, which reduce uncertainty over interpretation of a term in the future. See id. at 722-23.
Finally, the familiarity of legal and financial professionals with a given term may reduce the costs and improve
the quality of professional advice. See id. at 723.
101
See Kahan & Klausner, supra note 39, at 730-35; Klausner, supra note 39, at 806-07.
102
See Klausner, supra note 39, at 772.
103
See id.
104
Id. at 763-64. As I describe infra, the preference for standardization in network environments is
relative, not absolute. See infra Part IV.C. Thus, even significant network effects may not produce complete
convergence, as the inherent benefits of the nondominant standard to some users, given their particular utility
preferences, may outweigh the network gains from adopting the common standard. The long coexistence of a
UAC network under New York law and a smaller MAC network under English law is therefore fully
consistent with a network analysis. See infra Part IV.C.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 713
Corporate contract terms may produce analogous network effects, because
firms that use a particular contract term
like Apple computer usersform a
“network . . . linked together by commonly used complementary products.”
105
Among other possibilities, contractual network benefits include professional
expertise, pricing knowledge, and a body of judicial precedents developed
during the time the firm incorporates the given term in its contracts.
106
As
described by Russell Korobkin:
Contract terms might become more valuable as more parties adopt
them, for example, because wider use of a term can lead to more
judicial opinions interpreting the term. More interpretations, in turn,
can benefit users of the term by reducing uncertainty over how the
term would be interpreted by a court should the user become
embroiled in litigation in the future. Widespread use of a contract
term can also create benefits for users by making lawyers and other
providers of legal services more facile in drafting, negotiating,
interpreting, and, if need be, litigating the term. Such facility can
create value to term users by increasing . . . [its] value in the capital
markets . . . . In short, widespread use of a contract term can benefit
users of the term by causing complementary goods (such as judicial
precedents or professional services) to become more available,
cheaper or both.
107
Network effects can be predicted in sovereign debt contracting as well.
Much of the study of network effects in corporate contracts, in fact, has
focused on bond indenture terms. Many of the sources of network effects in
corporate contract are thus equally likely to arise in sovereign debt contracts.
Perhaps most importantly, sovereign debt contracts are likely to be shaped by
105
See Klausner, supra note 39, at 774-89. Just as PCs are linked together by complementary software
and hardware, firms that use a common contract term are linked together by complementary goods including
relevant judicial precedents and professional services. See id. at 757-59, 782-84; Russell Korobkin, Inertia
and Preference in Contract Negotiation: The Psychological Power of Default Rules and Form Terms, 51
V
AND. L. REV. 1583, 1594-95 (1998).
106
See Kahan & Klausner, supra note 39, at 726-27.
107
Korobkin, supra note 105, at 1594-95. As suggested above, in extending a network analysis from its
technological origins to contracting practices, it is important not to overstate the network preference for
standardization. As I describe infra, in Part IV.C, the presence of network effects does not dictate complete
standardization. Rather, the inherent value of a unique term might outweigh the network benefits of the
standard term in any given case. In contracting practices, this may help to explain the value of legal counsel’s
capacity for innovation, and perhaps even the general jockeying between parties for contract advantage. See
Marcel Kahan & Michael Klausner, Path Dependence in Corporate Contracting: Increasing Returns, Herd
Behavior, and Cognitive Biases, 74 W
ASH. U. L.Q. 347, 350 (1996) (describing the benefits of innovation). In
essence, such innovation might constitute an effort to maximize contract value on those terms as to which
network effects do not strongly favor standardization.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
714 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
what Klausner terms “marketing” network effects.
108
Such effects arise from
the nature of present-day sovereign debt. Until the late 1980s, sovereign debt
consisted almost entirely of syndicated bank loans.
109
Such loans were subject
to limited prospect of resale or transfer. As such, the terms of the relevant debt
contracts were of importance almost exclusively to the originator of the debt,
and there was little need to conform those terms to any more uniform set of
market standards.
With the shift to sovereign bonds, this pattern was turned on its head.
Bonds are widely dispersed and subject to active trading on secondary markets.
Such trading, in turn, creates a strong preference for standardized terms.
Standard terms, with which the market is familiar, can be expected to
maximize the ease of resale
the tradabilityof a given bond. Selection of
contract terms that are and will be used more widely therefore enhances a
bond’s value on the secondary market.
Klausner and Kahan primarily ground the network effects that naturally
follow from such pressure for standardizationby which the value of a given
term grows with its wider usein the reduced cost of pricing more uniform
corporate securities.
110
Lower cost of pricing, in turn, can reduce a firm’s cost
of capital, creating a “marketing” network effect favoring the standard term.
In slightly broader terms, widespread use of a given term can be expected to
produce more efficient and accurate pricing, by expanding the pool of relevant
financial information and thereby improving price precision.
111
Standardized
terms might also help to enhance bond value, in another iteration of marketing
network effects, by increasing liquidity. This may apply not only to the
particular bond issue involved, but also to later issues by the same sovereign.
While marketing network effects are given slightly less attention by
Klausner and Kahan than some of the other sources of network effects they
identify,
112
marketing effects are arguably the most important source of the
network pattern in sovereign debt contracting. Several factors might produce
relatively stronger marketing network effects in sovereign debt contracts than
in corporate contracts. The first turns on the balance of network and inherent
value in corporate versus sovereign contracts, including bonds. Obligations
108
See Klausner, supra note 39, at 785-86.
109
See supra notes 47-50 and accompanying text.
110
See Klausner, supra note 39, at 785; see also Marcel Kahan, The Qualified Case Against Mandatory
Terms in Bonds, 89 N
W. U. L. REV. 565, 586-87 (1995).
111
See Ahdieh, Making Markets, supra note 5, at 285-88.
112
Cf. Kahan, supra note 9, at 1079-80; Klausner, supra note 39, at 785-86.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 715
held against a domestic corporation clearly have an inherent value, regardless
of their network value. Even should trading in the given corporation’s bonds
be suspended, or the relevant corporation cease to be a going concern, its
bonds retain value as a residual claim against the corporation’s assets.
113
Such
claims can be asserted in bankruptcy. The inherent value of sovereign bonds,
by contrast, is far more constrained. Given the lack of any institutionalized
system of sovereign bankruptcy, or other form of receivership, debt claims
against a recalcitrant sovereign debtor are only as good as the market for their
resale.
114
This has arguably been evident in the Argentine financial crisis of
recent years.
115
In essence, Argentina has concluded that conciliation and
compromise with its private creditors offers little promise of future reward and
has consequently refused to negotiate.
116
A related factor arises from the significantly greater prospect of default on
sovereign bonds than corporate bonds. Given the greater likelihood of
sovereign default, the tradability of a sovereign bond is necessarily more
important. Such bonds, by comparison with corporate bonds, are relatively
less likely to reach maturity. As such, their inherent value is more limited, and
their network value proportionately greater.
117
Marketing network effects may
thus be essential to the valuation of sovereign bonds than corporate bonds,
given the latter’s inherent value upon maturity.
The proportion of network to inherent value generally, and the significance
of marketing network effects particularly, in sovereign debt versus corporate
debt contracts may also be influenced by the degree of heterogeneity among
borrowers. At least as they come to the debt markets, sovereign debtors may,
as a group, be relatively more homogeneous than corporate debtors.
Minimally, they may disaggregate into a more limited number of debtor
categories. If this is so, then marketing network effects are again likely to be
stronger in sovereign debt contracts. If differences among sovereign debtors
are more limited, their inherent preference for distinct terms should also be
less, and the relative value of participating in a larger network concomitantly
113
Cf. Ahdieh, Making Markets, supra note 5, at 292-96 & n.69.
114
This is not to deny the potential of creditor pressure and threats of future exclusion from the debt
markets to convince sovereign debtors to negotiate. It simply suggests that if the latter are ineffective,
creditors have little recourse.
115
See Michael Casey & Michael M. Phillips, Argentina Finds Middle Ground with IMF, Averts Loan
Default, W
ALL ST. J., Mar. 10, 2004, at A2.
116
See id.
117
Cf. Ahdieh, Making Markets, supra note 5, at 294-95.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
716 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
that much greater.
118
In the marketing of more homogeneous sovereign debt,
furthermore, investors are less likely to be seeking eccentric sources of
arbitrage.
A final reason to predict relatively more significant marketing network
effects in sovereign debt contracts turns on the sovereign debt markets’ focus
on the adverse implications of a shift from UACs to CACs, or to any relatively
more liberal CAC formulation.
119
A significant barrier to an emerging market
shift to CACs has been the fear that the latter might be interpreted as a signal
of some greater prospect (or even expectation) of future debt restructuring.
Given as much, network effects are likely to figure prominently in the choice
of any given sovereign to continue to use UACs or to shift to CACs. If a
growing tide of debtors is turning to CACs, any adverse implication for a given
emerging market is likely to be reduced, if not eliminated, and transition
rendered significantly easier.
Beyond marketing network effects, the other sources of network value
Klausner and Kahan identify in corporate contracts are also likely to be present
in sovereign debt contracts.
120
These include the value of future judicial rulings
regarding a contract terman “interpretive network externality”; the value of
tracking “common practices” that are pursued by similarly situated firms using
a given term; and the greater availability of legal services for the interpretation
and implementation of more common terms.
121
Interpretive network effects follow from the increase in relevant judicial
decisions that can be expected to result from wider use of a given term.
122
Such
decisions reduce uncertainty, and hence firms’ cost of capital.
123
Perhaps most
importantly, judicial decisions reduce uncertainty when they clarify ambiguous
118
Cf. Klausner, supra note 39, at 813-14, 817.
119
Cf. id. at 785.
120
It bears restating that I do not mean to offer any firm conclusion on the strength of network effects in
sovereign debt contracting. Choi and Gulati have begun the effort to address this empirical question. See Choi
& Gulati, supra note 5. Kahan and Klausner, among others, have used various empirical measures to explore
the strength of network effects in corporate bond contracts. See Kahan & Klausner, supra note 39, at 740-60
(outlining empirical analysis of network effects in corporate bonds). By contrast, this Article concentrates on
the origins of network effects in sovereign debt contracting, and suggests some of their important implications.
Further, it attempts to theorize what might trigger transition in network environments, including sovereign debt
contracting.
121
See Klausner, supra note 39, at 774-75.
122
See Lemley & McGowan, supra note 98, at 565.
123
See Klausner, supra note 39, at 777.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 717
or open-ended contract terms.
124
Consequently, the scope of interpretive
network effects in a given contract depends on the proportion of its terms that
require interpretation. If a contract is composed primarily of terms of a self-
explanatory nature, judicial interpretation
and hence the size of the network
of users of those terms
will be less important to the value of the contract, and
network effects will be of less consequence. The greater the proportion of
ambiguous terms, the more significant any network effects.
In sovereign debt contracts, judicial interpretation is likely to offer at least
some network value. Under a UAC contract, for example, it is necessary to
determine whether any given contract change comes within the enumerated list
of changes to basic financial terms that require unanimous consent. Greater
judicial clarity as to that enumeration is likely to reduce uncertainty. Judicial
interpretation of sovereign debt contracts may have become even more
important in recent years, moreover, given the rise of a variety of techniques
by which emerging market countries have attempted to skirt the limitations of
UACs.
125
Interpretive network effects may also have grown in importance
given the sudden emergence of various forms of CACs under New York law.
As these new and untested terms are adopted, judicial interpretation may be
especially valuable. A particular source of interpretive network effects in
sovereign debt contracts, in fact, may be the inevitable issues that newly
adopted CACs raise regarding the majority’s fair treatment of minority
creditors.
126
Thus, intercreditor duties of good faith and fair dealing, which are
essential to the efficacy of any CAC regime, will likely require active judicial
interpretation.
127
At least some interpretive network effects are therefore likely
in sovereign debt contracting.
128
The next type of network effect identified by Klausner and Kahan,
common practice network effects, also has application in the sovereign debt
124
Valuable judicial decisions, however, are not limited to those interpreting the terms themselves, but
might also address how particular terms relate to relevant statutory or regulatory rules. See Klausner, supra
note 39, at 776 n.62.
125
See infra notes 241- 49 and accompanying text.
126
Notably, Klausner references the interpretation of such intercreditor duty provisions as a prime source
of interpretive network effects in corporate contracts. See Klausner, supra note 39, at 775.
127
See Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7; cf. Lemley & McGowan, supra note 98, at 573-74 (discussing
interpretive network effects regarding good faith obligations in corporate contracts). As any interpretive
network effects arising from the adoption of CACs obviously postdate the transition to CACs, they do not help
to explain the longevity of UACs or the rapid shift to CACs. They may nonetheless be important in the
ongoing evolution of CAC terms and in any future contract transition.
128
Some features that make judicial decisions valuable in corporate contracts, however, may be less
common in sovereign debt contracts. See, e.g., Klausner, supra note 39, at 778 & nn.66-68.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
718 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
context. These network effects arise from contract terms tied to the practices
of contracting parties peers; “reasonable notice” requirements provide an
obvious example. Issues of intercreditor good faith under CACs may be the
most relevant example. The obligations of sovereign debtors under certain
collective action clauses, including provisions mandating disclosure,
engagement, and the like, might also give rise to common practice network
effects. In these cases, questions regarding any particular course of conduct in
debt restructuring, whether with reference to disclosure, notice, or other
procedural obligations, or with reference to the substantive terms of the
restructuring, can best be assessed with an eye to others’ practices regarding
the same procedural or substantive obligation under identical contractual
terms. Additionally, the existence of some common practice among a network
of users of the same term may also help to insulate a debtor’s or creditor’s
decision from adverse judicial review.
Legal services network effects, finally, also likely exist in sovereign debt
contracts, given the complexity of bond indentures, the foundational contract
of bond issues.
129
Legal services network effects may also have grown in
significance in sovereign debt contracting in recent years, as sovereign debtors
have pursued alternative avenues of restructuring.
130
Thus, Ecuador’s ability to
use exit consents to avoid the constraints of its UAC bonds
131
was grounded in
the availability of effective legal counsel to advise it how to do so. Such
opportunities are likely to be caseor contractspecific, and therefore
dependent on the availability of legal counsel to assist in the assessment and
application of a particular term.
132
Legal services network effects can therefore
be predicted in sovereign debt contracts. The more standard a given clause is,
the cheaper and better quality the legal services regarding its interpretation
may be.
Another increasingly important source of legal services network effects in
sovereign debt contracts is the need for legal counsel on the aforementioned
questions of intercreditor duty. Majority action under CACs creates a risk of
minority creditor abuse, against which courts and other regulators may act.
133
Yet the scope and nature of intercreditor duties remain unclear, creating an
129
See Klausner, supra note 39, at 784 n.87.
130
See infra Part III.B.2. But see supra note 127.
131
See infra notes 243-44 and accompanying text.
132
Thus, not every UAC or CAC contract’s terms are identical. See Stephen Choi & G. Mitu Gulati, Why
Lawyers Need to Take a Closer Look at Exit Consents, I
NTL FIN. L. REV., Sept. 2003, at 15.
133
See supra notes 126-27 and accompanying text .
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 719
essential need for effective counsel, and an important source of legal services
network effects, at least in the near future.
Finally, Klausner points to the benefits arising from the promptness of legal
advice in certain circumstances, including mergers and acquisitions.
134
The
same may be true in the sovereign debt context, given the transition process
often underway, and the exigent dynamic that often attends a debt
restructuring.
135
Given this need for speed, legal services network effects can
also be predicted.
Interpretive, common practices, and legal services network effects may,
like marketing network effects, be more significant in sovereign debt contracts
than in corporate contracts for at least two reasons. Most importantly, it is
relatively less likely that the demand for a given term will extend beyond the
reach of network effects in sovereign debt contracting. To clarify, the welfare
consequences of network effects are only significant if they encompass much
of the demand curve for a given product or term. If network gains taper off
early in the demand curveif only a few additional users are enough to
produce any and all network gainsthen network effects become incon-
sequential. They are, in the terms of the network literature, “inframarginal.”
136
By comparison, the extent of sovereign debt contract term usage and
interpretation is nowhere near the “consumption” of corporate contract
terms.
137
Consequently, network effects are relatively less likely to have
tapered off below the requisite level of demand in sovereign debt contracts
than in corporate contracts.
138
As compared with corporate charters in particular, network effects may
also be stronger in sovereign debt contracts because of the greater recurrence
of the latter. Thus, sovereign debt contracts are issued by sovereigns with
some regularity, sometimes as often as several times a year. Corporate
134
See Klausner, supra note 39, at 783.
135
With the transition to CACs, additional legal service efficiencies might be expected in the drafting
context. Just as UACs may have come to dominate sovereign debt contracts under New York law, on account
of the existing expertise of New York counsel with corporate debt contracts, in which UACs were mandatory,
see infra note 173, as drafting expertise increasingly shifts to the preparation of CACs, the relative cost of
drafting UACs may grow, strengthening the preference for CACs in new sovereign debt issues. These effects
are more in the nature of learning benefits, however, than network effects.
136
See Lemley & McGowan, supra note 98, at 573 n.403.
137
Cf. Ahdieh, Making Markets, supra note 5, at 288 n.40; Klausner, supra note 39, at 778-79.
Furthermore, there is a less vigorous legislative check on adverse, or even erroneous, judicial interpretations in
the sovereign debt context. Cf. id. at 778.
138
See Ribstein & Kobayashi, supra note 98, at 112.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
720 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
charters, by contrast, are by nature a rare occurrence.
139
Thus, one might
expect relatively less attention to be given to the drafting of sovereign debt
contracts.
140
Boilerplate, and resulting standardization, is that much more
likely, and more significant network effects can be expected to follow.
Of course, some features might be expected to reduce the significance of
network effects in sovereign debt, versus corporate, contracts. To begin with,
the population of relevant participants in sovereign debt contracting is smaller
than in corporate contracting, increasing the possibility of effective
communication or internalization of any network externalities.
141
Specific to
the latter possibility, the more select universe of attorneys involved in the
sovereign debt markets may serve as “norm entrepreneurs of a sort,
142
internalizing network benefits and hence facilitating efficient contract
transition.
143
This, in essence, is the pattern Choi and Gulati describe, with
reference to the role of Cleary, Gottlieb, Steen & Hamilton in facilitating
sovereign debt contract transition.
144
There may also be relatively fewer open-ended or ambiguous terms in
sovereign debt contracts than in corporate contracts.
145
As a result of this lack
of ambiguity, and because there are fewer sovereign debt contracts generally,
there are relatively fewer judicial interpretations of them.
146
Interpretive
139
Even amendments to corporate charters are relatively rare.
140
At the Georgetown Conference on Sovereign Debt Restructuring at which this Article was presented, a
participating banker commented that sovereign debt contracts are rarely read. Rather, in his view, bankers’
priority is the standardization of terms, not their actual content.
141
See Ribstein & Kobayashi, supra note 98, at 112-13.
142
See Cass R. Sunstein, Social Norms and Social Roles, 96 COLUM. L. REV. 903, 968 (1996).
143
See Ribstein & Kobayashi, supra note 98, at 12-13; see also Lemley & McGowan, supra note 98, at
578. On the other hand, there may be relatively less competition for legal services in sovereign debt
contracting than corporate contracting, reducing the degree of “entrepreneurship.
144
See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 951 tbl.2. If the relevant universe of sovereign debt participants is
construed not as the universe of sovereign debt debtors and creditors, but as the rather limited collection of
(mostly New York) law firms and banks that stand behind sovereign bond issues—one potential way of
thinking about Choi and Gulati’s analysis—network effects may remain significant, but have far fewer welfare
consequences than suggested below. See infra Part II.B. Further, the barriers to effective communication, and
resulting coordination, that are identified below will also present far more limited obstacles to efficient
contract transition.
145
Cf. Kahan, supra note 110, at 586-87 (enumerating categories of variation in corporate bond
contracts); Lemley & McGowan, supra note 98, at 571-72 (describing lesser importance of network effects in
contracts consisting primarily of specific terms). Sovereign debt contracts might also be argued to contain
relatively fewer specific, or non-open-ended, terms than corporate contracts.
146
Cf. Lemley & McGowan, supra note 98, at 572-73; Ribstein & Kobayashi, supra note 98, at 112.
Relatively less litigation of sovereign debt contracts may help to explain the smaller number of judicial
decisions. See Lemley & McGowan, supra note 98, at 572-73. The more “domestic” nature of corporate
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 721
network effects may therefore be less important in sovereign debt contracts.
Finally, given the sovereign character of one party to a sovereign debt contract,
courts may hew more rigidly to contract language, again reducing the
importance of any interpretive network effects.
On the whole, then, the present analysis cannot support strong conclusions
regarding the significance of network effects in sovereign debt contracting.
147
Such conclusions must rest on empirical analysis and study.
148
However, the
foregoing suggests good reasons to predict the presence of network value in
sovereign debt contracts, including the importance of secondary trading in
sovereign bonds and resulting marketing network effects, and the importance
of legal counsel in sovereign debt contracting and resulting legal services
network effects. Likewise, what empirical evidence we have indicates the
presence of network effects.
149
Given as much, it is worth considering the
compatibility of a network theory of sovereign debt contracting with the
observed reality of longstanding stasis and rapid change in sovereign debt
contracting, as described above. As we shall see, a network theory of
sovereign debt contracting offers a compelling explanation of both patterns.
B. Network Effects, Stasis, and Change in Sovereign Debt Contracting
A network theory of sovereign debt contracting, and perhaps contract
boilerplate more generally, offers a persuasive explanation of the observed
pattern of development in the sovereign debt market in recent years. Network
effects can first explain the stasis of market utilization of UACs,
notwithstanding their seeming inefficiency and the substantial pressure to
abandon their use. Yet, network effects can also explain the rapid shift to
CACs in 2003, as well as the wholesale nature of that transition. These
explanations will be considered in turn.
As articulated in an array of economic and legal analysis, network effects
have the potential to produce Pareto inferior consumption patterns and welfare
consequences. Among the efficiency concerns that have been identified in
contracts and differences in repeat player characteristics may, in turn, help explain the diminished volume of
litigation of sovereign debt contracts.
147
See Ribstein & Kobayashi, supra note 98, at 114-15.
148
To this effect, Steve Choi and Mitu Gulati have analyzed the existence of network effects in sovereign
debt contracting and found evidence of their presence. See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 931, 936, 938; see
also Kahan & Klausner, supra note 39, at 740-60 (outlining empirical evidence of network effects in corporate
bonds).
149
See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 931, 936, 938.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
722 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
network industries is the prospect of strong lock-in of existing technologies or
standards.
150
As Klausner and Kahan have put it, “when network externalities
are present . . . the outcome of decentralized individual maximizing decision in
the market will be path dependent.”
151
Thus, once a given network standard
has secured a dominant or even exclusive position, it may be difficult to shake
it from that position, no matter how inefficient it becomes.
152
This follows
from the unwillingness of market participants to move to a smaller network,
even given potential improvements in (inherent) product quality.
153
Network
environments thus exhibit “excess inertia.”
154
150
See Di Noia, supra note 99, at 43 (“The model shows that network externalities may lock-in exchanges
into inefficient outcomes, due to a lack of coordination, even in perfect competition.”); Sean P. Gates,
Standards, Innovation, and Antitrust: Integrating Innovation Concerns into the Analysis of Collaborative
Standard Setting, 47 E
MORY L.J. 583, 609-10 (1998); Klausner, supra note 39, at 791; see also Ahdieh,
Making Markets, supra note 5, at 317-18. Other potential network inefficiencies have also been identified.
See
Lemley & McGowan, supra note 98, at 567; Ribstein & Kobayashi, supra note 98, at 110.
151
Kahan & Klausner, supra note 100, at 763-64.
152
See Nicholas Economides, Network Economics with Application to Finance, 2 FIN. MARKETS, INST. &
I
NSTR., Dec. 1993, at 89, 93 (“Lock-in is particularly important in the presence of market power in sponsored
networks. In general, firms may be very reluctant to change their way of operation, especially if they have to
pay the costs of transition. The self-reinforcing nature of networks creates switching costs for the existing
customers. The existence of positive critical mass often means that in the presence of one network, a
differently organized one may not even exist. These facts give market power to firms that sponsor networks,
and may impede technological innovation.”).
153
See Catherine Fazio & Scott Stern, Innovation Incentives, Compatibility, and Expropriation as an
Antitrust Remedy: The Legacy of the Borland/Ashton-Tate Consent Decree, 68 A
NTITRUST L.J. 45, 52 (2000)
(discussing lock-in effects resulting “[w]hen marginal consumers weigh the network externality more heavily
than the intrinsic value of each technology”).
[C]onsumers might have difficulty moving to a new standard—even if they all agreed that the
adopted standard was suboptimal—because of collective action problems. The value of any
alternative system would depend on the number of users adopting it; the rational consumer might
well choose to wait until an alternative had been adopted by others who incurred the costs of
shifting to the new standard but reaped fewer benefits relative to later adopters.
Lemley & McGowan, supra note 98, at 497 (citation omitted); see also Lewis M. Branscomb & Brian Kahin,
Standards Processes and Objectives for the National Information Infrastructure, in S
TANDARDS POLICY FOR
INFORMATION INFRASTRUCTURE 5-6 (Brian Kahin & Janet Abbate eds., 1995); Shelanski & Sidak, supra note
98, at 5 (“As the benefits offered by one network grow, so too do the costs to consumers of choosing, or
switching to, a rival offering.”). Pirrong argues that:
Successful entry requires the new [network] to attract a sufficient number of traders from the
incumbent simultaneously. If this does not occur, the new [network] is very costly to [operate]
because it is illiquid . . . . Given the difficulty of coordinating the simultaneous defection of large
numbers of traders, it is quite costly for an entrant [network] to survive, even if its terms and . . .
policies [are preferable].
Stephen Craig Pirrong, The Self-Regulation of Commodity Exchanges: The Case of Market Manipulation, 38
J.L. & E
CON. 141, 155 n.24 (1995).
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 723
In this path-dependent dynamic,
155
an early standard may determine the
shape of the market long after it has grown inefficient.
156
A dominant
technology may thus neither evolve with the dictates of efficiency nor be
susceptible to displacement, given significant network effects. Such a pattern
has been suggested to explain the continued dominance of the Microsoft
Windows operating system, in spite of the asserted superiority of its
competitors.
157
Slightly further afield, I have suggested that network lock-in
may explain the persistent dominance of the New York Stock Exchange,
notwithstanding its limited adoption of electronic enhancements of its trading
Such network lock-in assumes a dispersed market, in which direct communication is not a viable
mechanism for network participants to share a preference for transition. A small community of readily
identifiable network participants might thus be able to transition effectively, by communicating among
themselves an intention to elect a nondominant, but otherwise preferable, standard. Network barriers to
transition are therefore limited—at least in the ordinary case—to those network markets in which size,
dispersion, anonymity, and the like prevent effective communication. Thus, as noted above, if the network of
sovereign debt contracting consists not of debtors and creditors, but of sovereign debtors’ counsel and
underwriters, network lock-in becomes easy to avoid, through direct communication among the latter groups.
See supra note 144.
154
See James B. Speta, Handicapping the Race for the Last Mile?: A Critique of Open Access Rules for
Broadband Platforms, 17 Y
ALE. J. ON REG. 39, 80 (2000) (describing potential “excess inertia” in network
industries); see also Joseph Farrell & Garth Saloner, Standardization, Compatibility, and Innovation, 16
RAND J. E
CON. 70, 71 (1985) (indicating that “it is plausible that the industry, once firmly bound together by
the benefits of compatibility or standardization, will be inclined to move extremely reluctantly to a new and
better standard because of the coordination problems involved”). But see Michael L. Katz & Carl Shapiro,
Product Introduction with Network Externalities, J. I
NDUS. ECON., Mar. 1992, at 55, 73 (suggesting potential
for “insufficient friction” in some network markets and resulting stranding of earlier purchasers).
155
Note that network effects produce a different form of lock-in than “path dependence” as formally
defined. Path dependence is grounded in historical patterns, while network lock-in is tied to the present
composition of the market. See Lemley & McGowan, supra note 98, at 495.
156
See Ahdieh, Making Markets, supra note 5, at 317-21. Of course, this does not mean that a new
network can never displace an established first-mover. If the new standard is sufficiently advantageous, its
inherent value might be able to overcome the network effects favoring the dominant standard. See Dwight R.
Lee & Richard B. McKenzie, A Case for Letting a Firm Take Advantage of “Locked-In” Customers, 52
H
ASTINGS L.J. 795, 796-98 (2001) (noting that “if the gains from switching are greater than the costs of doing
so, incentives exist for entrepreneurs—so-called ‘network sponsors’—to overcome the built-in resistance to
change”). In such circumstances, the new technology “leapfrogs” the established one. See Michael H. Knight
& Nicholas A. Widnell, Dark Clouds in the Distance? Network Effects and the Approaching B2B Storm, 9
G
EO. MASON L. REV. 599, 619 (2001) (describing how Sega gained substantial share from Nintendo through
“leapfrog technology”); Lemley & McGowan, supra note 98, at 517; Melonie L. McKenzie, How Should
Competing Software Programs Marry? The Antitrust Ramifications of Private Standard-Setting Consortia in
the Software Industry, 52 S
YRACUSE L. REV. 139, 155 (2002). In the presence of network effects, however,
this result cannot be assumed, and requires not merely a somewhat more advanced, or cheaper, standard, but
one offering significant improvements or cost-savings. See McKenzie, supra, at 155.
157
See W. Brian Arthur, Increasing Returns and the New World of Business, 74 HARV. BUS. REV. 100,
102 (1996).
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
724 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
mechanism.
158
In these cases, competing technologies that cannot offer
substantial efficiency gains have been unable to displace the network standard.
The dominant players, meanwhile, have exhibited inadequate receptivity to
technological upgrading or other forms of modernization.
159
A pattern of network lock-in readily captures the state of sovereign debt
contracting for much of the last century.
160
Notwithstanding apparent
efficiency gains to be had by a shift to CACs,
161
most sovereign debt issuers
were unwilling to choose the latter alternative.
162
Instead, bond issue after
bond issue under New York law relied on the dominant network standard of
unanimous action.
163
The lock-in of UACs should come as no surprise,
however, if network effects are significant in the selection of sovereign debt
restructuring terms.
164
Rather, lock-in of the UAC standard is precisely what a
158
See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 222-23; Ahdieh, Making Markets, supra note 5, at 316-21.
159
From a slightly different perspective, network lock-in can be conceived as a form of barrier to entry.
In essence, new producers are excluded from the market, absent their identification of a substantially more
efficient technology. Assessing network effects as such, I have previously suggested that new markets,
standards, or technologies may not emerge in the first place, even absent any dominant producer. See Ahdieh,
Making Markets, supra note 5, at 308–09; see also Ribstein & Kobayashi, supra note 98, at 110; Amitai
Aviram, Regulation by Networks 13 (2003) (unpublished manuscript), available at http://www.law.uchicago.
edu/Lawecon. In essence, the network-driven expectation that a dominant producer will emerge, see infra
notes 174-77 and accompanying text, may cause producers not to enter, for fear they will be unable to recover
their sunk costs if they do not ultimately emerge as the dominant network. See William J. Baumol et al.,
Parity Pricing and Its Critics: A Necessary Condition for Efficiency in the Provision of Bottleneck Services to
Competitors, 14 Y
ALE J. ON REG. 145, 160 (1997).
160
Cf. Kahan, supra note 9, at 1078-79; Kahan, supra note 110, at 587 (describing lock-in of corporate
bond contract terms). Other explanations have been offered for this pattern, including one by Lee Buchheit
and Mitu Gulati. See Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12, at 1359-60; see also Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at
931. At a minimum, a network interpretation may supplement any alternative explanation, such as the
pos sibility that the holdout concerns that CACs address were simply not a priority for market participants. See
Roubini & Setser, supra note 14, at 19.
161
See supra notes 8-13 and accompanying text.
162
See Eichengreen, Crisis Resolution, supra note 54, at 10; EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 7 &
tbl.1. It bears noting that scholars have flagged reservations about CACs. See Portes, supra note 16, at 48, 67,
69; see also Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7 (citing sources); Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12, at 1358 n.88;
Gulati & Skeel, supra note 4, at 1.
163
As a further sovereign debt contract puzzle, Choi and Gulati cite the failure of recent sovereign debt
contracts to resolve the ambiguity of the pari passu clause, notwithstanding the attention called to this obscure
provision by Elliott Associates’ predatory claim again Peru’s assets. See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 992-
93. Strong network lock -in can readily explain this pattern. In essence, sovereign debtors might fear that any
shift from existing contract norms—even toward seemingly greater clarity—would reduce the marketability of
their bonds. More difficult to explain from a network perspective, thus, is the increase in the percentage
requirement for amendment of the pari passu clause in several of the recent sovereign bond contracts. See id.
164
Besides explaining lock-in of the UAC standard, network effects may also help to explain the
widespread usage of UACs. This is simply the flip side of the same coin. By preventing displacement of the
existing standard, network effects favor continued, and increasingly universalized, use of that standard.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 725
network theory of sovereign debt contracting would predict. Given the pattern
of dispersed ownership of sovereign bonds by anonymous holders,
communication among creditors and debtors of an intent to transition to CACs
was essentially impossible.
165
Without such communication, however, no party
to a sovereign debt contract would be willing to shift away from the dominant
network of UACs, even to the superior, but non-network, CAC standard.
Favoring this characterization, Barry Eichengreen, Kenneth Kletzer, and
Ashoka Mody offer an explanation of UACs’ persistence that overlaps with a
network analysis, describing the pattern as one of inertia.
166
Admittedly, the extent of network lock-in of UACs was likely reduced by
the presence of the competing MAC network under English law.
167
Thus, a
shift from the network dominant UAC standard to CACs did not require
adoption of a completely new and untested standard. Rather, MACs were
included in a significant portion of the universe of sovereign bonds.
168
While
the extent of network value would therefore be diminished by a shift to
collective action, it would not be completely lost. First-movers to CACs
would not be starting a new network, but would rather be joining a smaller, but
still significant, MAC network under English law. The presence of such a
competing network, even if smaller, might be expected to diminish the extent
of network lock-in.
169
On the other hand, it is not entirely clear that the New York law UAC and
the English law MAC networks represented true competitors for the business
of emerging markets for several reasons. Until the recent transition,
developing countries issued predominantly UAC bonds under New York
law.
170
Eichengreen, Kletzer, and Mody have grounded this pattern in those
nations’ relatively greater need to exhibit the “commitment” implicit in UACs,
than to maintain the “flexibility” facilitated by CACs.
171
Emerging market
issuers may therefore have faced less of a choice of networks (i.e., New York
law UACs versus English law MACs) than the existence and even size of the
minority MAC network might nominally suggest.
165
See supra notes 50- 53 and accompanying text.
166
See EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 17, 33-36; Eichengreen, supra note 16, at 86 -87.
167
See supra Part I.A.
168
See Mody, supra note 17, at 14, tbl.1.
169
The seeming ease of the ultimate transition to CACs might thus be explained, at least in part, by the
presence of the CAC-style English law network of MAC bond contracts.
170
See Mody, supra note 17, at 14.
171
See, e.g., id. at 13-14.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
726 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
Sovereign debt contracts, furthermore, consist of more than an election of
unanimous versus collective action provisions. Bond contracts encompass an
array of provisions, largely standardized within the New York and the English
debt markets, but distinct as between the two jurisdictions.
172
The body of New
York versus English law case precedent is also a point of distinction in a
sovereign’s choice to issue under New York or English law. For these reasons,
the choice to shift to English law MACs would have involved substantially
more than a choice between competing networks distinguished only by their
use of UACs instead of MACs. Rather, other network—as well as inherent—
utility might be sacrificed by such a shift. Network lock-in may have remained
significant for this reason as well.
A final network-related source of lock-in for emerging markets, which
might further obviate the nominal availability of the competing network of
English law MACs, turns on the signaling effect of such a shift.
173
Thus,
regardless of its rationale, the decision of a given emerging market, which has
ordinarily issued its debt with UACs, to make a unitary shift to MACs might
have been interpreted by the market to suggest nonpublic information
regarding the stability or creditworthiness of the issuer. For these reasons,
network lock-in of UACs likely remained significant in the sovereign debt
markets, notwithstanding the presence of English law MACs.
If a network conception of sovereign debt contracting offers a compelling
theory of the long persistence of UACs, notwithstanding widespread
challenges to their efficiency, what of UACs’ ultimate demise in the rapid and
wholesale transition to CACs over the course of 2003? Notably, network
effects also explain this pattern with relative ease. The network effects
literature predicts market “tipping” in the presence of strong network effects.
174
As described above, in network environments, consumers prefer to participate
172
Cf. Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 932.
173
See ERIC A. POSNER, LAW AND SOCIAL NORMS 18-19 (2000). One among many potential non-
network explanations for lock-in of the UAC standard is the strong reliance on form or model terms in drafting
bond contracts. Mitu Gulati and Ralph Brubaker have separately opined to the author that this tendency may
be especially strong in sovereign debt and other public finance groups at large law firms. See also supra note
39 and accompanying text.
174
See Shelanski & Sidak, supra note 98, at 5; see also Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 226-27;
Ahdieh, Making Markets, supra note 5, at 305 n.114 (characterizing network markets as “tippy,” such that “the
coexistence of incompatible products may be unstable, with a single winning standard dominating the market”)
(quoting Stanley L. Besen & Joseph Farrell, Choosing How to Compete: Strategies and Tactics in
Standardization, J. E
CON. PERSP., Spring 1994, at 117, 118); Michael L. Katz & Carl Shapiro, Systems
Competition and Network Effects, J. E
CON. PERSP., Spring 1994, at 93, 105–06; Lemley & McGowan, supra
note 98, at 496–97; cf. Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7 (noting potential for tipping from UACs to CACs).
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 727
in what is or will be the largest network. This preference arises from the
“positive externality conferred upon users of a term . . . that [is and] will be
widely used.”
175
A larger network, in essence, offers greater network utility to
its participants. Because of this preference to participate in the largest
network, however, network industries can be expected to move rapidly
towardand tip toa dominant, if not singular, network, as each new
participant, hoping to maximize its own network gains, jumps on the prevailing
network’s bandwagon.
176
A pattern of network tipping can readily explain the rapid shift from UACs
to CACs in 2003. In essence, as various signals suggested a likely shift to
CACs, and as a handful of countries took the plunge, the market tipped to
CACs. As each sovereign bond issuer made the decision to restructure existing
debt or issue new debt, it identified some widely recognized, or idiosyncratic,
reason to expect that future contract norms would favor CACs. It therefore
chose to adopt collective action terms itself, to avoid being stranded with the
non-network-dominant choice of termUACs. Assuming significant network
effects, moreover, the speed of this process should not be surprising. To the
contrary, once the process is underway, network theory would predict it to be
both rapid and wholesale, as each and every new issuer rationally adopts the
new standard. That CACs have emerged as the new norm, and not simply a
competing alternative to UACs, falls well within the expectations of network
theory.
177
175
Kahan & Klausner, supra note 100, at 729.
176
See Katz & Shapiro, supra note 174, at 105–06 (explaining “tipping” as the tendency of one system to
pull away from its rivals in popularity once it has gained an initial edge).
177
It bears noting that Klausner and Kahan’s “learning benefits,” see supra note 100, have the potential to
reduce a tipping effect tendency toward transition. See Klausner, supra note 39, at 789 n.102 (noting that
learning benefits encourage lock-in). By contrast with network effects, future gains that result from the
num ber of present and future users of a given good, standard, or term, learning benefits are products of the past
user base of a given good, standard, or term. Thus, unlike the future judicial decisions that produce
interpretive network effects, the learning benefits encompassed in the existing universe of judicial precedent
regarding a given term will persist, even if all users were now to abandon that term. Learning benefits thus
favor retention of an existing standard, regardless of its existing pool of users, so as not to sacrifice the benefits
of past learning. See id.
For any given user, it is entirely plausible that the learning benefits of the historic standard may
outweigh the network benefits of joining a larger, but newer network. Over time, this should be increasingly
less true, but at least at the outset, learning benefits may outweigh network effects. Ultimately, this will
depend on the balance of inherent value (including learning benefits) and network value in a given good. See
supra notes 99-104 and accompanying text. In the battle between the Betamax and VHS standard for
videocassette players, for example, the Betamax standard’s inherent benefits, including its existing base of
players and programs, would seem to have been inadequate to prevent a relatively rapid tipping of the market
to VHS. The growing network favoring the DVD standard, by contrast, would seem to be insufficiently strong
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
728 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
A network theory of sovereign debt contracting can therefore help to
explain much of what we have observed in the sovereign debt markets over the
last several years. Perhaps more importantly, such a theory discourages any
rote assumption that contract standards will naturally evolve in the face of
efficiency demands. Yet, a major gap remains in our understanding of the
pattern of recent developments in sovereign debt markets. Network theory
may explain why there was little change in sovereign debt restructuring terms
for many years, and why the change was both rapid and wholesale when it
came. But network analysis alone cannot explain why the change occurred
when it did. More specifically, it does not address what might trigger the shift
from network stasis to network transition. In the following Part, I suggest a
role for state action in that shift.
III. C
OORDINATION GAMES, FOCAL POINTS, AND A CUEING THEORY OF
SOVEREIGN DEBT TRANSITION
If a network theory of sovereign debt contracts can explain both the long
persistence of UACs and the alacrity with which they were abandoned, how
might we explain the timing of that shift? After decades of seeming resilience,
why were UACs replaced by CACs at the moment they were? While external
pressure in 2002 and 2003 might offer a partial explanation, it cannot alone
suffice. Pressure to shift to CACs had been in place since the 1990s, yet did
not make a dent in the widespread use of UACs. Something more must have
been added to the mix.
Applying a relatively unfamiliar corner of game theory to the network
dynamic of sovereign debt contracting, this Article posits that the driving force
behind the recent shift to CACs was a change in expectations, brought about
through what I term “regulatory cues.” The following begins with an
explication of a “coordination game” theory of sovereign debt contracting and
the identification of regulatory cues as a critical mode of state action in
facilitating coordination around alternative equilibria. I then identify potential
cues in the transition from UACs to CACs and use these examples to explore
the nature of regulatory cues in contract transition. In sum, the transition from
UACs to CACs in sovereign debt contracts suggests the role of regulatory cues
as an important, if inadequately appreciated, mechanism of state action.
to overcome the inherent benefits of the now-longstanding VHS network. In sovereign debt contract terms, for
the reasons outlined above, I would predict network effects to be of reasonable significance. Choi and Gulati’s
empirical analysis would seem to lend some support to this view. See Choi and Gulati, supra note 5.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 729
A. A Game Theoretic Account of Sovereign Debt Contracting
While game theory has found widespread application in the literature of
sovereign debt restructuring, the latter analysis has relied almost exclusively on
the familiar paradigm of the Prisoner’s Dilemma. Given an orientation to the
challenge of debt restructuring under unanimous action provisions, the
strategic dynamic of the Prisoner’s Dilemma is an appropriate frame of
reference. This strategic pattern arises in sovereign debt restructuring from the
incentive of each creditor to demand side payments for their participation in
any collective decision to restructure. In this way, each creditor attempts to
maximize its individual payoff.
178
This is the precise pattern of the Prisoner’s
Dilemma, in which each prisoner’s individual payoff favors defection
confession, or a refusal to participate in any agreed restructuring. Yet the
resulting outcome, in which both players defect, produces inferior payoffs for
both players than if they had kept to the agreement.
179
Coordination is
therefore at the heart of the Prisoner’s Dilemma of sovereign debt restructuring
under UACs.
Yet the Prisoner’s Dilemma actually involves a form of second-order
coordination, within the game of sovereign debt restructuring. With the terms
of the game defined by unanimous action contract provisions, the Prisoner’s
Dilemma necessarily plays itself out. In the present analysis, however, our
subject is the first-order coordination required to define the rules, or standards,
of the relevant game.
180
As with the restructuring of distressed foreign debt,
such coordination is not easy to achieve. The strategic dynamic at work,
however, is not characterized by the Prisoner’s Dilemma game, but by the less
familiar, yet no less prevalent, “coordination game” dynamic.
181
178
Buchheit & Gulati describe a slightly broader coordination dilemma than the conventional account, but
continue to focus on coordinated action among creditors; thus, they emphasize the prospect of acceleration or
litigation by holdout creditors, and consequently arrive at an iteration of the familiar Prisoner’s Dilemma. See
Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12, at 1320. A distinct inquiry regarding application of the Prisoner’s Dilemma
in sovereign debt restructuring suggests that the strategic dynamic at work in sovereign debt markets may not
be nearly as dire as the conventional analysis would suggest. See Arturo C. Porzecanski, The Constructive
Role of Private Creditors, E
THICS & INTL AFF., Fall 2003, at 18, 19.
179
See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 229-30.
180
See Charles J. Goetz & Robert F. Scott, The Limits of Expanded Choice: An Analysis of the
Interactions Between Express and Implied Contract Terms, 73 C
AL. L. REV. 261, 292-93 (1985) (highlighting
need for coordination in facilitating change in contract norms). In slightly different terms, one might think of
most game theory analysis in the sovereign debt literature to be about resolving sovereign debt crises, while
the present analysis considers how to avoid them.
181
See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 234. Coordination games have not received much attention
among legal scholars. See Steven Hetcher, Creating Safe Social Norms in a Dangerous World, 73 S. C
AL. L.
R
EV. 1, 7, 42 n.160 (1999). While various explanations for such neglect might be suggested, one possibility is
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
730 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
Coordination games involve the same challenge found in the network
context of the transition from UACs to CACs and analogous standard-setting
contexts: the need to coordinate and align player expectations.
182
This need is
readily apparent in the most basic model of coordination
the Meeting Place
game
in which a husband and wife who have become separated seek to find
each other.
183
In this situation, aligned interests and a resulting preference for
coordination
the hallmarks of network environments, in which market
participants gain from selection of a common network standard
are the
dominant features.
184
In graphical terms, with the added feature of one
potential equilibrium that is Pareto superior to the other, this dynamic is
captured in Figure 1.
the erroneous assumption that where interests are aligned, as in coordination games, efficient outcomes will
occur without legal intervention. See id. at 47 & n.47 (citing examples). A related argument posits that true
coordination game social dynamics are rare, as compared with Prisoner’s Dilemma-type social interactions.
To the contrary, however, “[e]veryday life is full of situations where we have to coordinate our actions with
those of other people.” See Karl Warneryd, Conventions and Transaction Costs, in 1 T
HE NEW PALGRAVE
DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW 460 (Peter Newman ed., 1998). Coordination games capture many
of the most funda mental forms of human interaction. Experimental evidence would appear to support the view
that coordination failures are more than a “theoretical curiosity.” See RUSSELL W. COOPER, COORDINATION
GAMES: COMPLEMENTARITIES AND MACROECONOMICS 1 (1999).
182
See Richard H. McAdams, A Focal Point Theory of Expressive Law, 86 VA. L. REV. 1649, 1679, 1680
(2000) (describing the capacity of a judge to achieve an outcome merely by altering the parties’ expectations).
183
In Thomas Schelling’s original Meeting Place game, a husband and wife were to determine where and
when they would attempt to find each other if they were separated at a department store. See id. at 1656
(describing Schelling’s original game). In simplest terms, this can be modeled as such:
Husband
Entrance
Information
Desk
Wife
Entrance 5,5 0,0
Information
Desk
0,0 5,5
Schelling also conducted other “matching game” experiments. See Robert Sugden, A Theory of Focal Points,
105 E
CON. J. 533, 543 (1995) (noting “Schelling’s New York game, Choose a Disc, Choose a Letter, and
Coloured Disks”). For more examples of coordination games, see McAdams, supra note 182, at 1654–58.
184
See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 233-37. In coordination games such as the Meeting Place
game, interests and incentives are aligned, but the players lack the necessary information—specifically,
accurate expectations of one another—to “find each other” and solve the game.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 731
FIGURE 1
Sovereign Debt Contracting as a Meeting Place Coordination Game
185
This game, like coordination games generally, is characterized by multiple
Nash equilibriahere, in the northwest and southeast quadrants.
186
At these
points, players cannot enhance their welfare by a unilateral change in
strategy.
187
Nash equilibria are consequently quite stable. Neither party can be
expected to diverge from them, absent some expectation that their counterpart
will do likewise. Even if players are at the suboptimal coordination point of
the southeast quadrant, thus, they may not move to the Pareto superior
northwest one.
188
If the northwest quadrant is the Pareto optimal coordination norm of CACs
and the southeast represents the longstanding use of UACs, then, what might
produce a shift from the latter to the former? At heart, the shift among Nash
equilibria is an issue of expectations.
189
If they are to move among Nash
equilibria, market participants need some mechanism by which they can
develop accurate expectations of the future behavior of other market
participants, and make resulting adjustments to their own behavior. In the
185
I demarcate the game participants as Mexico and Brazil. In its broader form, however, the game of
sovereign debt contracting I describe herein includes the entire array of sovereign debtors, as well as the
universe of institutional and individual lenders. As such, iterations of the same game would be expected to
play out between Mexico and the United States, between Mexico and any given lender, between Mexico and
the IMF, between the IMF and other lenders, between the IMF and the United States, and so on.
186
Notably, Bratton and Gulati also identify a multiple equilibrium issue in sovereign debt contracting,
but one directed to the prospect of defection underlying the Prisoner’s Dilemma. See Bratton & Gulati, supra
note 7.
187
See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 232, 235-36.
188
See id. at 236-37.
189
See id. at 230-33; Ahdieh, Making Markets, supra note 5, at 308-10.
Brazil
CACs UACs
Mexico
CACs 10,10 0,0
UACs 0,0 5,5
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
732 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
simple terms of the Meeting Place game, I need to develop accurate
expectations of where you are likely to expect me, to expect you to go, and so
on.
190
Once such expectations are developed, one can predict a common shift
to the Pareto superior choice—here, CACs.
How do such expectations develop, then? How might the array of
participants in a stable coordination game develop the common set of
expectations necessary to trigger abandonment of the existing (Pareto inferior)
Nash equilibrium, for a more efficient alternative? Most obviously, they might
communicate with one another. In sovereign debt contracting, for example, a
creditor conference might be convened, market analysis of competing contract
terms might be developed and widely circulated, or debtors might organize
themselves into political groupings. In a variety of circumstances, however,
communication may not be an available, or effective, source of common
expectations.
191
To begin with, the greater the heterogeneity of participants in the relevant
game, the less effective communication is likely to be. Heterogeneous parties
are less likely to come together, or to be able to reach common understandings,
if they do. In sovereign debt contracting, the relevant community consists,
most significantly, of competing populations of creditors and debtors.
192
Even
within these groups, the extent of heterogeneity is substantial, with debtors
ranging from the United States to the least-developed countries, and creditors
ranging from banks and other institutional holders of sovereign debt to
individual bondholders.
193
Moreover, the efficacy of communication in sovereign debt contracting is
likely to be further diminished by the number of relevant participants. This
follows from the shift from syndicated bank loans to bonds, as described
above.
194
With this shift, the community of sovereign debt creditors went from
a small collection of large banks, who could easily come together or otherwise
consult, to a massive number of dispersed and anonymous bondholders, among
whom communication is all but impossible. As noted above, this obstacle is
further aggravated by the tradability of bonds on the secondary markets.
190
See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 236 n.94.
191
See id. at 239-41.
192
But see supra note 144.
193
Among the relevant creditors, moreover, are so-called “vulture funds,” which purchase bonds of
distressed sovereigns with the specific intent to hold out from any agreed restructuring. A greater
heterogeneity of interests among coordination game participants is difficult to imagine.
194
See supra notes 47-50 and accompanying text.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 733
Consequently, the universe of participants in the coordination game of
sovereign debt contract transition is in near constant flux.
But the tradability of sovereign bonds is actually even more problematic for
coordinating expectations than this suggests. Given the relatively extended
term of sovereign bonds and their tradability on the secondary markets, the
network of sovereign debt lenders actually has an even broader character than
the present pool of bondholders. Instead, it encompasses the universe of
potential purchasers of such bonds.
195
Among this broad group, it is even
clearer that communication cannot be relied on to achieve efficient
coordination.
Lastly, cheap talk
the devaluation of nonbinding speechmay also limit
the efficacy of communication as a means of creating common expectations
and thereby facilitating the shift to a Pareto superior coordination point.
196
In
sovereign debt contracting, this may be an especially acute difficulty, given the
need for effective communication among debtors and creditors. Even given
the existence of some significant coordination dynamic, driving both parties to
the relevant communication to seek convergence on a common standard, the
strategic interaction of debtors and creditors must necessarily also involve
some strong divergence of interest. Given as much, distortive cheap talk is
likely to be unavoidable.
197
195
Cf. Ahdieh, Making Markets, supra note 5, at 291.
196
See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 239-41.
197
See id. at 240-41. For this reason, something akin to a “Battle of the Sexes” coordination game is
likely most appropriate to the sovereign debt contracting strategic environment.
Husband
Ballet Boxing Match
Wife
Ballet 10,5 3,3
Boxing Match -3,-3 5,10
In this conflictual coordination game, wife and husband wish to spend the evening together (hence, the need
for coordination), but have distinct preferences as to where to go—a boxing match or the ballet (hence, the
element of conflict). See id. at 240 n.102.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
734 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
In the face of this dilemma, in which coordination is desirable, but
communication is difficult or impossible, Thomas Schelling famously offered
“focal points” as a mechanism by which coordination games might be solved.
In Schelling’s approach, focal points are those equilibrium choices in
coordination games “that, for cultural or psychological reasons, [are] more
‘salient’ and therefore seem[] more natural.”
198
A focal point analysis thus asks
whether a particular solution stands out or is more prominent
199
and suggests
that such solutions can be expected to be chosen by any given coordination
game player and, therefore, to be the preferred choice of players collectively.
200
While useful as an explanation of players’ preliminary choice of one Nash
equilibrium over another, however, Schelling’s analysis cannot alone resolve
dilemma of transition. Where the parties have already arrived at a given
equilibrium, thus, a focal point theory cannot explain subsequent transition.
The most focal point in a coordination game already played is thus the
equilibrium at which the players have arrived, whether it be efficient or
otherwise.
For focal points to facilitate a shift among Nash equilibria, then, what is
needed is some mechanism to render an alternative solution focal. While
various agents might contribute to this end,
201
I would propose that there is an
important public, or official, role to play in this function, by means of what I
have previously termed “regulatory cues.”
202
Such cues are a form of state
198
David A. Strauss, Common Law Constitutional Interpretation, 63 U. CHI. L. REV. 877, 910 (1996).
On focal points generally, see Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 129-30, and McAdams, supra note 182,
at 1659-63.
199
See DOUGLAS G. BAIRD ET AL., GAME THEORY AND THE LAW 39 (1994); ROBERT SUGDEN, THE
ECONOMICS OF RIGHTS, CO-OPERATION AND WELFARE 49 (1986); EDNA ULLMANN-MARGALIT, THE
EMERGENCE OF NORMS 83-84 (1977); McAdams, supra note 182, at 1659. The term “salience” is commonly
used in the coordination game literature as an alternative characterization of focal points. See Gerald J.
Postema, Conventions at the Foundation of Law, in 1 D
ICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND THE LAW, supra note
181, at 469-70 (describing the regularity of behavior as a source of salience because it makes “one particular
combination of actions stand out as uniquely eligible among a number of possible combinations”); see also
S
UGDEN, supra, at 89- 90 (noting the interchangeable terminology of prominence, salience, and focal points).
200
See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 244-45.
201
Private sources of focal points can thus be identified. Schelling refers to a picture of the Empire State
Building on the cover of The New York Times as a privately created focal point, which might help solve his
New York game, in which two friends become separated in New York City without having previously
identified a meeting place. Choi and Gulati’s emphasis on the role of the law firm of Cleary, Gottlieb, Steen &
Hamilton, which serves as counsel to a substantial number of sovereign debt issuers, in facilitating the
transition to new terms might also be characterized to constitute a privately created focal point. See Choi &
Gulati, supra note 5, at 951 tbl.2, 975, 977.
202
See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 245-47.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 735
action, but are not mandates in any conventional regulatory sense.
203
They
involve no threat of sanction, or even the existence of such sanction.
204
The
role of regulatory cues in the coordination game dynamic of network
industries, including contract transition, is to help shape expectations in a way
that permits efficient private transition.
205
Coercion
whether in the form of
threatened sanction or promised reward
is unnecessary for this adjustment of
expectations (rather than incentives), the key to the efficient resolution of
coordination games.
206
Thus, regulatory cues play an informational, a facilitative, and an
encouragement role, not a coercive one. In a variety of forms, regulatory cues
encourage the emergence of common expectations around a particular
equilibrium outcome, thereby facilitating coordination around that equilibrium
and resolution of the relevant coordination game.
207
In the terms of the
coordination game of sovereign debt contracting, regulatory cues might serve
to make alternative contract terms focal and thus facilitate transition to the
Pareto superior coordination equilibria of CACs.
Notably, such an intermediate public role in sovereign debt contracting is
not without precedent. In fact, just this pattern is evident in the English and
U.S. governments’ role in organizing dispersed foreign bondholders during the
interwar period. In England, Parliament granted the Corporation of Foreign
Bondholders a royal charter, while in the United States, the Foreign
Bondholders Protective Council arose out of a working party sponsored in
1932-33 by the State Department.
208
In each case, coordination among
creditors was facilitated through indirect state action. Today, as in the 1930s,
changes in sovereign debt contract norms may again “require moral suasion by
203
See id. at 255-59.
204
See id.
205
See id. at 229-33; Ahdieh, Making Markets, supra note 5, at 308-09.
206
See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 229-33. It is important to note, in this view, that the
“coercive” nature of conventional regulation can come in two guises. Whether carrot or stick, reward or
punishment, these are perfect substitutes for one another. In some sense, then, government “persuasion” is no
different from government “mandate.” In each case, the incentives of the regulated entity are altered by public
action.
207
In an earlier article, I describe the nature and function of such cues in extended detail. See id. at 245-
68. Arguably, the debt restructuring strategy of the Brady Plan exhibited some cueing dimensionc in its
pressure on developing countries to make the shift to Brady Bonds. See Eichengreen & Portes, supra note 48,
at 15-16.
208
See Portes, supra note 16, at 59-60. The SEC also played a role in the evolution of the Foreign
Bondholders Protective Council in the United States. See id. at 60.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
736 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
G-7 governments, central banks, and the IMF to overcome the markets’
reluctance” to change.
209
B. Regulatory Cues in Sovereign Debt Contract Transition
In the recent transition from UACs to CACs in sovereign debt contracts,
several important regulatory cues can be identified. Each of these likely
helped to influence both debtor and creditor expectations of a shift to CACs;
collectively, they helped to tip the market to the latter. By rendering the use of
CACs as focal, such cues helped to break the lock-in of the Pareto inferior
Nash equilibrium of UACs, in the southeast quadrant, and facilitate a shift to
the Pareto superior Nash equilibrium of CACs, in the northwest quadrant.
210
The range of relevant cues can be divided into two broad categories, based on
the relevant actor. The first set encompasses the range of regulatory cues
offered by the United States and other developed economies, the official sector
(e.g., the IMF and the World Bank), and international groupings of these
actors. The second includes those cues offered by emerging market sovereign
debtors. Both categories of regulatory cues, furthermore, can be graded along
a pair of independent axes, which I define in the following section as the extent
to which the relevant cue has a coercive potentiality beyond its cueing
function, and the extent to which its coordinative role arises from its provision
of information.
1. Regulatory Cues of Creditor States and the Official Sector
In the first category, perhaps the most significant regulatory cue was the
U.S. Department of Treasury’s strong encouragement of a shift to CACs.
211
Before 2003, “[t]he U.S. Treasury and leading investment bankers [had] been
searching for at least one reputable emerging-market sovereign willing to
volunteer to issue a benchmark bond with new collective-action clauses
facilitating an eventual restructuring.”
212
Roubini and Setser have implicitly
209
Id. at 65.
210
See supra notes 184-88 and accompanying text.
211
See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 973; Dealing with Default, supra note 81; Porzecanski, supra note
178, at 24. Although there is no evidence of it to date, pressure on investment banks could also serve a cueing
role in contract transition. See Roubini & Setser, supra note 14, at 23 (“A handful of investment banks
dominate the emerging market bond business. These investment banks could be summoned by the Treasury
and the Federal Reserve and it could be made clear that the authorities expect them to follow the lead of [those
banks that are using CACs] and to bring to market a new generation of bonds that have clauses. If not, the
authorities would ‘name and shame’ the investment banks that refuse to cooperate.”).
212
Porzecanski, supra note 15, at 41. Similarly, Under Secretary of Treasury John Taylor suggested the
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 737
suggested the value of such encouragement by the United States and other
developed countries in facilitating sovereign debt contract transition.
213
Of
course, such strong encouragement
or mild pressure, as it might be seen in
the eyes of the beholder
may have contributed to the shift to CACs as much,
if not more, because of its coercive force, as its cueing function. As I describe
below, these functions are not exclusive of one another.
214
Rather, a given
public act may both coerce and cue transition. For present purposes, however,
I focus particularly on the cueing function of such pressure.
The cueing function of U.S. encouragement of a shift to CACs is readily
apparent in the case of Mexico, which became the first investment-grade issuer
of New York law bonds to include CACs, under pressure from the United
States.
215
Notably, Mexico announced its issue
unexpected given earlier
indications that it had no plans for a new issuance
216
immediately before the
April 2003 IMF meeting at which the final SDRM proposal was to be
presented for approval.
217
In doing so, it effectively cut the legs out from under
the SDRM, as the United States had long sought to do.
218
Mexico has seemed
to acknowledge the external role in its decision.
219
As put by one Mexican
finance official: “This is more about sending a signal to the international
markets than it is about reducing our borrowing costs.”
220
The immediate
praise of Mexico by the United States and the G-7 may also be suggestive: “As
a solid investment-grade borrower, Mexico is making an important
contribution to strengthening the international financial system.”
221
U.S. expectation that new European Union members would soon adopt CACs. See Taylor, Using Clauses,
supra note 15.
213
See Roubini & Setser, supra note 14, at 23 (“Issuers that continue to use the old boilerplate should at a
minimum expect that their unwillingness to use collective action clauses will be publicly noted in the course of
IMF surveillance and that they will have unpleasant conversations with U.S. authorities.”).
214
See infra note 264-65 and accompanying text.
215
See Skeel, supra note 25, at 418 n.3.
216
See Mexico Pioneers Plan to Ease Debt, supra note 1.
217
See Gulati & Skeel, supra note 4, at 3.
218
See Taylor, Using Clauses, supra note 15.
219
See Eichengreen, supra note 16, at 87 n.6.
220
Mexico Pioneers Plan to Ease Debt, supra note 1.
221
Id. I elaborate infra why this pattern is not best understood as U.S. coercion of Mexico. See infra Part
III.C.1. Such coercion might encompass both the possibility I emphasize herein—what might be characterized
as the “negative coercion” of threatened sanctions—and the “positive coercion” of promised rewards. In either
case, Mexico’s strategy is altered based on changed incentives, as opposed to expectations. A cueing theory,
however, emphasizes the role of U.S. action in shaping Mexican expectations. See infra Part III.C.1.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
738 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
A related regulatory cue was the decision of many developed economies to
incorporate CACs into their own debt instruments.
222
Such “leadership by
example” was actively encouraged by the IMF and others.
223
Responding to
this encouragement, in September 2002, the membership of the European
Union, including Italy, Spain, and Sweden, which regularly issue debt in
foreign jurisdictions, announced plans to incorporate CACs into their bond
contracts.
224
Canada and Switzerland followed suit.
225
Collectively, these
choices encouraged an expectation that generalized transition might be
imminent.
226
The clearly articulated goal of the G-7 to minimize IMF bailouts was
another important cue behind the shift to CACs. Beginning with a proposal
from the Council on Foreign Relations in 1999, scholars and policymakers
increasingly insisted that the IMF should hew more closely to the constraints
of its bylaws on the provision of bailout funds.
227
In the period immediately
preceding the shift to CACs, several countries, as well as the official sector,
began to sound an even more forceful note on this issue. John Taylor, the U.S.
Under Secretary of Treasury, offered the clearest example of this pattern in an
April 2002 address regarding CACs and the SDRM initiative.
228
This was far from cheap talk, meanwhile, given the actual limitation of
official sector relief in the recent cases of Argentina, Ukraine, and Ecuador.
229
222
See Boorman, supra note 15, at 67.
223
See Portes, supra note 16, at 47 (quoting 1999 IMF Report); see also Eichengreen, Crisis Resolution,
supra note 54, at 15; Taylor, Using Clauses, supra note 15.
224
See Taylor, Using Clauses, supra note 15.
225
See EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 9; Eichengreen, supra note 16, at 87; Portes, supra note 16,
at 70.
226
The nature of any cueing effect of the developed countries’ choice of CACs warrants careful
definition. Such shifts do not serve, at least in primary part, to facilitate transition by enhancing the returns on
the now-larger CAC network. Given the miniscule possibility that Canada, Switzerland, Italy, or Sweden will
ever seek to restructure their debt, it is not obvious that they can be meaningfully included in the CAC network
encompassing Mexico, Brazil, and Uruguay. Admittedly, the use of CACs by Canada, Switzerland, Italy, and
Sweden may enhance awareness and improve the pricing of CACs, indirectly enhancing value. See supra Part
II.A. Yet this is not the primary cueing function of that choice. Rather, developed countries’ use of CACs acts
as a cue for any given emerging market because they signal a greater likelihood that other emerging markets
will follow the lead of Canada, Switzerland, and the others, and also adopt CACs.
227
See EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 8. In addition to the Council on Foreign Relations, the
Bank of Canada and the Bank of England jointly proposed as much, as did the Meltzer Commission. See id.
228
See Taylor, Sovereign Debt Restructuring, supra note 15; see also Barry Eichengreen, Crisis
Prevention and Management: Any New Lessons from Argentina and Turkey?, G
LOBAL DEV. FIN., Oct. 2001, at
20- 21; Porzecanski, supra note 15, at 40; Porzecanski, supra note 178, at 24.
229
See Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7; Eichengreen, supra note 228, at 21-22, 22 n.42; cf. EICHENGREEN
ET AL., supra note 14, at 8.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 739
Even more important for the adjustment of market expectations regarding the
use of CACs was the willingness of the international community to allow
several nations to fall into default, notwithstanding longstanding talk of the
risks of “contagion.”
230
This included Russia in 1998,
231
Ecuador in 1999, and
Argentina, arguably, in 2002.
232
Following directly from the latter set of regulatory cues, the IMF’s serious
consideration of an SDRM
which suggested its growing reticence to pay a
hundred cents on the dollar in emerging market bailouts
233
and even more so,
the actual prospect that an SDRM might come into being, were important cues
for the transition from UACs to CACs. “Why have borrowers changed their
minds? One reason is fear. Once the SDRM was mooteda far worse idea
than collective-action clauses in borrowers’ eyes
the thought that it might be
put into effect focused minds on the search for a market-based alternative.”
234
Yet IMF interest in an SDRM might not have been enough to alter
longstanding expectations. The United States’s apparent wavering on the
SDRM, however, greatly strengthened the force of the SDRM cue to the
markets.
235
“The [U.S.] Treasury, apparently annoyed by bondholders’ failure
to embrace its contractarian accommodation of their interests, responded with a
public tilt in the direction of the IMF proposal.”
236
If this was the United
States’s gambit, it was an effective cue. In the aftermath of the U.S.
expression of interest in the SDRM, the Institute of International Finance,
representative of the interests of sovereign debt creditors and long opposed to
the adoption of CACs, suddenly embraced them. Other creditor groups also
came to identify CACs as an alternative approach and even proposed
boilerplate language for such clauses.
237
230
See Frank Partnoy, Why Markets Crash and What Law Can Do About It, 61 U. PITT. L. REV. 741, 753
(2000).
231
See Eichengreen, supra note 16, at 80 n.3.
232
See Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7; Eichengreen, supra note 228, at 21-22, 22 n.42; Portes, supra note
16, at 70-71; Porzecanski, supra note 15, at 42.
233
See Eichengreen, Crisis Resolution, supra note 54, at 12.
234
Dealing with Default, supra note 81.
235
See Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7; Eichengreen, supra note 228, at 32; Taylor, Using Clauses, supra
note 15; see also Christopher Bowe & James Harding, Wall Street Wants Fiscal Prudence, Voters Want Money
in Their Pockets, F
IN. TIMES, Dec. 10, 2002, at 23; Gulati & Skeel, supra note 4, at 3.
236
Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7. This was as likely a strategic feint as anything else: “The U.S., which
is still formulating its tactics for the [April IMF] meetings, may decide to leave the threat of the SDRM alive
as an incentive for emerging market countries to follow its alternative proposal . . . .” Beattie, supra note 76,
at 13.
237
See EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 9.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
740 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
A final cue that may prove important in the further evolution of sovereign
debt contract standards is creation of the mechanisms necessary for the
efficacy of a CAC regime. Most particularly, this calls to mind Bratton and
Gulati’s proposed judicialization of the development of intercreditor duties in
sovereign debt contracts.
238
The emergence of such a regime, in essence, might
serve to raise expectations that a strong CAC arrangement might realistically
be chosen by sovereign debtors and accepted by creditor markets.
239
Collectively, these nearly simultaneous acts, decrees, and pronouncements
of the United States, the G-7, the IMF, and others helped to facilitate the
transition from UACs to CACs, without ever mandating as much. They might
be said to have done no more than create some “constructive ambiguity” with
regard to future action (or inaction) by the official sector.
240
Given resulting
adjustments in debtor and creditor expectations, the need to minimize the costs
of restructuring may have come to loom larger for both groups, creating wider
expectations of a shift to the more efficient CACs, and thereby inducing that
shift.
2. Emerging Market Regulatory Cues
By contrast with the foregoing regulatory cues, several important cues
behind the recent shift to CACs were signaled by developing countries
themselves. Perhaps most importantly, the transition to CACs may have been
encountered by emerging markets’ growing willingness to press forward with
restructuring, regardless of creditor or official sector opposition.
241
Essentially,
recent events may have signaled that debtor nations would find a way to
restructure their debt, without regard to the conventional “stick” of reputational
harm in the capital markets.
242
If such willingness was becoming the norm,
then more efficient mechanisms of restructuring, such as CACs, would
increasingly be preferred by creditors and debtors alike, and a shift to CACs
might be expected.
238
See generally Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7.
239
A related cue that deserves note was the encouragement of CACs through the preparation of draft CAC
language by the G-7, as well as several groups of creditors. See E
ICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 35;
Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 997. Such language may reduce the cost of developing CACs, and therefore
heighten expectations of their adoption.
240
See Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7.
241
See Eichengreen, Crisis Resolution, supra note 54, at 15 (noting the example of Russia in 1998).
242
After Ecuador’s use of New York law amendment clauses to modify the nonfinancial terms of its
Brady Bonds and Eurobonds, and thereby induce participation by holdout creditors, “[e]xpressions of praise
and outrage, depending on the source, inevitably followed.” See Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12, at 1334.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 741
Ecuador was perhaps the greatest contributor to this particular cue.
243
In
2000, in the face of expected repayment difficulties on its outstanding debt,
Ecuador proposed to restructure its debt, by exchanging it for new bonds with
longer terms, but reduced interest rates. To minimize the potential for costly
holdouts, Ecuador made use of so-called “exit consents.” Under this scheme,
creditors who agreed to the exchange simultaneously gave Ecuador their proxy
for changes to the nonfinancial terms of the existing bonds. Because such
changes required only a majority vote, even in UAC contracts, Ecuador was
able to secure the authority to amend the nonfinancial terms of the old debt,
without regard to any dissenters from the exchange itself.
244
Yet through
selective changes to the nonfinancial terms of the bond issue (including choice
of law), Ecuador could dramatically reduce the liquidity and overall value of
the old bonds. As a result, potential holdouts had little incentive to refuse the
exchange, as evident in their nearly universal agreement to what was
nominally a “voluntary” exchange.
Other debtor states followed Ecuador’s lead toward more aggressive forms
of restructuring, whether through exit consents or other techniques. This
included Russia, which offered a unilateral exchange in 2000, and Pakistan and
Ukraine, which likewise took a “take-it-or-leave-it” approach.
245
In the case of
Uruguay, meanwhile, separate negotiations with private creditors permitted
restructuring to occur, notwithstanding the limited support of the IMF, which
had previously been considered a precondition to any attempt at
restructuring.
246
Collectively, these aggressive moves by emerging markets to
restructure their debt between 2000 and 2002 may have served as an important
cue in changing prevailing expectations. If these countries could do it, so
could others.
247
Their ability to force a restructuring of their debt, and the fact
that the IMF had essentially let them get away with it,
248
made clear that “the
era of bondholder immunity from restructuring” was over.
249
As such, creditors
might be expected to increasingly favor a shift to CACs.
243
See id. at 1331, 1334; Silverman & Deveno, supra note 51, at 184; see also Choi & Gulati, supra note
5, at 933-35 (describing role of Ecuador exit consent in subsequent contractual shifts). On Ecuador, see also
Felix Salmon, The Buy Side Starts to Bite Back, EUROMONEY, Apr. 2001, at 46, 58-59.
244
See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 933; Choi & Gulati, supra note 132, at 15; see also Lee C.
Buchheit & G. Mitu Gulati, Exit Consents in Sovereign Bond Exchanges, 48 UCLA L. R
EV. 59 (2000).
245
See Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12, at 1346.
246
See Porzecanski, supra note 178, at 20; see also EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 29-30.
247
See Porzecanski, supra note 178, at 20.
248
See Boorman, supra note 15, at 61.
249
See Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7; Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 934, 939. In fact, the period from
2000 to 2002 was characterized by growing talk of ways in which emerging markets might achieve their
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
742 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
Another emerging market cue of importance, at least for the later phases of
the transition to CACs, was Mexico’s successful issuance of a New York law
bond with CACs. By avoiding the imposition of any substantial discount,
Mexico undermined the claim that CACs would be costly for developing
economies.
250
This signal arguably began to take shape even earlier, in fact,
with Lebanon’s and Qatar’s placement of CAC bonds in 2000, and Egypt’s
similar issue in 2001.
251
While these were private placements,
252
the fact that
they did not register with the markets as aberrational may have been an
important cue that CACs would not be unwelcome on the market.
In coordination game terms, the collection of cues outlined above helped to
encourage an expectation among debtors and creditors that their peers were
increasingly more likely to shift to CACs. This allowed some to make the
shift, which in turn caused others to do so. In network terms, these regulatory
cues helped to tip the market to CACs. They did so not by means of coercion,
whether dictating or affirmatively rewarding the use of CACs, but instead by
signaling expectations of a transition to them.
C. The Nature and Role of Regulatory Cues
From the enumeration of potential regulatory cues in the prior section, it is
readily apparent that the particular character and form of such cues may vary
widely. Nonetheless, one might analyze regulatory cues along the paired
dimensions of relative coerciveness and information provision. Along the first
axis, of coercion, public intervention in sovereign debt contracting may range
from acts that are purely cues and have little potential for coercion, to more
coercive acts, approximating law or regulation as ordinarily conceived. Along
the second axis, cues might be plotted based on how much information they
provide to coordination game participants, whether regarding the benefits of
coordination generally, or the likely return on particular coordination
equilibria. These twin scales, which do not posit competing characterizations
of cues as either coercive or informational, but rather acknowledge the
restructuring goals, without recourse to conventional, negotiated workouts. In particular, one might note J.P.
Morgan’s “two-step” process, see Roubini & Setser, supra note 14, at 25, by which outstanding debt would be
exchanged for new debt with CACs, which would then be restructured. See Boorman, supra note 15, at 59, 60,
68- 69; see also Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 934.
250
See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 969-70.
251
See Eichengreen et al., supra note 14, at 3 n.3; Anthony Richards & Mark Gugiatti, The Use of
Collective Action Clauses in New York Law Bonds, 35 G
EO. J. INTL L. (forthcoming 2004); see also Choi &
Gulati, supra note 5, at 962.
252
See EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 22.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 743
possibility of cues that are at once coercive in tenor and information-rich, or
vice-versa, can be considered in turn.
1. Cues and Coercion in Sovereign Debt Contract Transition
Among the most important characteristics of regulatory cues is their
noncoercive nature.
253
In essence, they can be distinguished from public
regulation as conventionally conceived, because their efficacy does not depend
on the threat, imposition, or even existence of any public sanction. As I have
elaborated elsewhere, regulatory cues may resolve even intractable
coordination problems, without restraints on parties’ behavior
the ordinary
mechanism of legal regulation.
254
Given the strategic dynamic of coordination
games, in which players’ expectations, rather than incentives, require
adjustment, cues function by offering information, facilitating inter-action, and
encouraging common understandings.
Notwithstanding their noncoercive nature, however, regulatory cues can be
defined along some continuum of relative “coerciveness.” This is evident in
the examples above. The United States’s pressure on Mexico and other
investment-grade markets to incorporate CACs into new bond issues falls at
the relatively coercive end of the spectrum.
255
As suggested above, such
pressure may serve a cueing function, but maywhether by design or
inadvertencealso coerce a change in behavior. Mexico may have had great
confidence that U.S. pressure to shift to CACs was toothless and may
consequently have adjusted its contract standards based only on the cueing
effect of U.S. policy. Yet even a small possibility of U.S. sanction may have
been enough to have altered Mexico’s incentive to use UACs instead of CACs,
and thus have coerced the transition to CACs.
256
Besides U.S. encouragement
of CACs, other relatively more coercive cues might be the IMF’s insistence on
the seemingly unrealistic SDRM, and the United States’s abrupt expression of
potential interest in that proposal in mid-2002, notwithstanding its prior strong
resistance to it.
257
253
See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 255-59. Other important features of regulatory cues
include their complex intertwining of public and private functions and their fundamentally expressive
character. See id. at 259-65.
254
See id. at 255-56.
255
See supra notes 215-21 and accompanying text.
256
Although I highlight the threat of sanctions as coercion, it is important to note that the provision of
rewards is no less coercive, as the latter concept is used here. In both cases, behavior is modified based on
altered incentives, and not simply altered expectations.
257
See supra Part III.B.1.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
744 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
At the opposite end of the continuum of coercion, meanwhile, are various
patently noncoercive cues, including most, though not all, of the cues
originating from debtor states themselves. Ecuador’s use of exit consents is
one example. Mexico’s successful issuance with CACs is another. Developed
countries’ promised and actual use of CACs in their own bonds also lacked any
coercive dimension and was a pure cue.
Falling somewhere in the middle, finally, are cues such as the growing
emphasis on the IMF’s obligation to limit bailouts and the imposition of such
limits in several important cases. Speculatively, a possible intermediate cue
might be a speech by Alan Greenspan favoring a transition to CACs. While
more coercive than the foregoing emerging market cues enumerated above,
these examples fall far short of the near-regulatory character of U.S. pressure
on emerging markets to use CACs and the IMF’s threat of an SDRM.
It bears emphasizing, however, that even seemingly coercive cues are not
coercive at heart.
258
Rather, debtors and creditors may choose to reject an
inefficient coordination equilibrium signaled by public authorities, whether it
be the United States or the IMF.
259
They can be expected to do so, moreover,
in any case where the inherent inefficiency of the proposed solution outweighs
any resulting coordination, or network, benefits.
260
If the “costs” of CACs to
Mexico were sufficiently high, for example, Mexican authorities would be
expected to have more forcefully resisted any U.S. pressure to adopt them.
Stating the point slightly differently, even the most coercive-seeming
regulatory cues are not meant to dictate coordination, at least in the first
258
See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 256-59. To this effect, Edna Ullmann-Margalit has
suggested that coordination norms are “used” or “conformed to” by private parties, rather than complied with.
See ULLMANN-MARGALIT, supra note 199, at 98.
259
See LEMLEY & MCGOWAN, supra note 98, at 545.
260
See Randal C. Picker, Simple Games in a Complex World: A Generative Approach to the Adoption of
Norms, 64 U. C
HI. L. REV. 1225, 1285 (1997). A somewhat parallel dynamic can be observed in experimental
analyses of what have been termed “Ultimatum” games. See generally Werner Guth et al., An Experimental
Analysis of Ultimatum Bargaining, 3 J. E
CON. BEHAV. & ORG. 367 (1982). In this situation, an allocator (or
proposer) proposes how to divide a sum of money. The receiver (or responder) must then choose to accept or
to refuse the proposal. If the receiver refuses it, however, neither player will receive any payoff. In this
dynamic, as little as a penny should be accepted by a rational receiver. Economists have observed a tendency
toward a breakpoint, however, below which receivers reject the proposal, notwithstanding the consequent loss
to themselves. See, e.g., Colin Camerer & Richard H. Thaler, Anomalies: Ultimatums, Dictators and
Manners, J. E
CON. PERSP., Spring 1995, at 209, 210; Elizabeth Hoffman et al., On Expectations and the
Monetary Stakes in Ultimatum Games, 25 I
NTL J. GAME THEORY 289, 291-92, 295-96, 299-300 (1996); Peter
H. Huang, Dangers of Monetary Commensurability: A Psychological Game Model of Contagion, 146 U. P
A.
L. R
EV. 1701, 1711-12 (1998).
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 745
instance. Instead, they seek to encourage efficient coordination, by influencing
the expectations of coordination game participants.
261
In the transition from
UACs to CACs, thus, a shift was never dictated. Rather, the array of cues
outlined above collectively pointed to a likely adjustment of individual debtor
and creditor strategies to favor the incorporation of CACs. In this way,
expectations
and ultimately behaviorschanged. Had the relevant debtors
and creditors found the benefits of the use of CACs, including both their
inherent value and network value, to be sufficiently less than the existing
benefits of UACs, no individual cue, or even collection of them, would have
been effective in prompting a transition.
262
Even if regulatory cues have the capacity to accomplish efficient transition
without need for coercion, however, the category of most coercive-seeming
cues
U.S. pressure for the adoption of CACs, the IMF’s SDRM proposal, and
the like
would seem to beg the question of what dynamic actually triggered
the shift to CACs. Perhaps a coercive story offers a better, or at least a
simpler, account of the transition? This sharper narrative of the recent
transition in sovereign debt contracting, one favored by the maxim of Occam’s
Razor,
263
would acknowledge the presence of network effects and the resulting
tendencies toward lock-in and tipping in sovereign debt contracting practice. It
would not identify noncoercive regulatory cues as the trigger behind the
ultimate transition, however, but transnational coercion by the United States,
other developed countries, and the IMF. In this view, pressure from the United
States to abandon UACs and to choose CACs over the SDRM can fully explain
the observed patterns of transition. Such a theory, in fact, could point to the
very same collection of public acts that I label as only seemingly coercive and
suggest that appearances may not be deceiving in this case. Rather, seeming
coercion by the United States may have actually coerced the shift to CACs.
The present account does not entirely dispute this version of events.
Rather, a cueing theory of the transition from UACs to CACs acknowledges
the potential for multiple triggering events, including some element of
coercion.
264
An accounting grounded exclusively in coercion, however, sits
uneasily with the delay between the onset of external pressure to move to
261
See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 258-59.
262
See id. at 256.
263
See Tracey E. George & Robert J. Pushaw, Jr., How Is Constitutional Law Made?, 100 MICH. L. REV.
1265, 1275 n.38 (2002).
264
Similarly, it acknowledges that various non-network factors may have contributed to the long pattern
of UAC lock-in in New York law bonds. See supra Part I.A.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
746 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
CACs, and the ultimate decision of Mexico and others to make that shift. With
an eye to this delay, the present analysis posits that something additional may
have been at worknamely, the effect of the collection of regulatory cues
enumerated above, all pointing toward the likely, but not mandatory, shift to
CACs by an array of autonomous sovereign debt creditors and debtors.
Yet if at least some of what I identify as regulatory cues
including U.S.
pressure on emerging market debtors
are likewise tools of coercion, does the
distinction between cueing and coercion not become mere semantics? What
distinguishes the most coercive-seeming cues from coercion? In essence, the
answer lies in the particular motivation to change strategy in coordination
games, including network environments such as the transition of contract
boilerplate. In the Prisoner’s Dilemma and other noncooperative strategic
situations to which conventional legal regulation seems to respond, players
shift their behavior to socially preferred alternatives in the face of changes in
their incentives to choose a particular strategy. Law and regulation facilitate
efficient outcomes by altering parties incentives. In coordination games, by
contrast, players change strategies not because of any change in incentives, but
because their expectations regarding the strategy of their counterpart have
changed. As described above, thus, regulatory cues are directed to
expectations, not incentives.
What might this mean in practice? How is the cue of U.S. encouragement
of a shift to CACs any different than the coercion of U.S. pressure to shift?
The coercive account posits that Mexico’s incentives to use UACs instead of
CACs in its bond contracts, and the analogous incentives of other emerging
markets, were altered by U.S. pressure. The costs of utilizing UACs increased,
thus, once the threat of direct or indirect U.S. sanctionsbroadly defined, of
coursebecame clear.
A cueing analysis, observing the same U.S. behavior, suggests that a
different mechanism might have been at work. U.S. pressure may have
primarily served to alter Mexico’s expectations regarding emerging markets
use of UACs versus CACs in the years ahead. In combination with the other
cues enumerated above, the cueing theory posits that U.S. pressure may have
simply signaled to Mexican authorities that other debtors, as well as creditors,
were likely to shift to CACs. Given as much, a transition to the latter by
Mexico became appropriate as well.
Far from mere semantics, this difference has important implications for the
conception and design of state action. It suggests, for example, that even if
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 747
Mexico knew it would face no sanction for its failure to respond to U.S.
demandsimagine, for example, that it had been offered clear guarantees to
that effect, or even that it was strong enough to resist such pressure
265
it might
nonetheless have made the shift to CACs. It would do so not based on U.S.
coercion, at least of Mexico itself, but based on its expectation that other
nations would respond to U.S. pressure
or the perception of U.S.
pressure
by shifting to CACs. In this view, Mexico might even shift to
CACs in the absence of any pressure from the United States, but instead in
response to real or perceived pressure on Brazil, Russia, or other emerging
markets.
Perhaps most importantly, a cueing model of the transition from UACs to
CACs offers the lesson that coercion may not be necessary to achieve efficient
transition. Thus, regardless of whether Mexico’s decision to shift to CACs,
and the ensuing decisions of other emerging markets, were driven more by
coercion or cueing, ensuing changes in sovereign debt contracting practices
may not require coercion. More generally, cueing theory suggests that public
authorities may be able to rely on a cueing function of law in a number of areas
in which coercive regulation has conventionally been the norm. Policy goals
vis-à-vis a given subject of regulation (whether a nation-state or domestic
private actor), finally, may be achieved without need for sanction, or any
action regarding that particular subject, as opposed to other, similarly situated
subjects of regulation.
2. Regulatory Cues as Sources of Information
A second continuum in the characterization of regulatory cues is the
amount of information provided by the relevant cue. To what extent does it
serve its coordination function by enhancing the quality, and perhaps simply
the commonality, of the information available to coordination game
participants? Expectations regarding the likely choices of other playersthe
key to any shift among Nash equilibria in the coordination game of contract
boilerplate transitionare ultimately a question of information.
266
265
Even if Mexico was politically or economically strong enough to resist U.S. pressure to adopt CACs,
thus it might nonetheless shift to CACs, based on its expectations regarding other countries’ ability (or
inability, to be more precise) to resist U.S. pressure.
266
See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 258-59. To related effect, Anne-Marie Slaughter speaks of
“regulation by information.” See A
NNE-MARIE SLAUGHTER, A NEW WORLD ORDER 24 (2004).
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
748 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
Information regarding the value of an alternative equilibrium, as well as the
costs of transition to that equilibrium, will thus enhance or diminish
expectations regarding the occurrence of a transition.
267
In essence, information
may render a given coordination point more focal and thereby encourage
coordination around that point.
268
This information function is apparent in the
regulatory cues enumerated above, as is the gradation of its importance in the
operation of various cues.
Mexico’s nondiscounted bond issuance, notwithstanding its inclusion of
CACs, is perhaps the best example of a regulatory cue serving as a source of
information
in that case, to other potential issuers. Other information-
oriented cues in sovereign debt contracting might include the willingness of the
IMF and G-7 to allow several important sovereign debtors to go into default
and the ability of several developing countries to go at it alone in their
restructuring.
269
The Greenspan testimony imagined above might be construed
as an important informational regulatory cue, as would a publicly com-
missioned study of the efficiency gains from a shift to CACs and the potential
debtor premiums for such a shift.
270
By contrast, the seemingly feigned interest
of the United States in the SDRM and the U.S. pressure on Mexico to issue
debt with collective action provisions were relatively less directed to
information provision, at least in any meaningful sense.
271
Ultimately, then, along the twin axes of relative coerciveness and the extent
of information offered by a regulatory cue, we can plot an array of cueing
behaviors of public authorities. U.S. pressure on Mexico was relatively more
coercive, and less information-intense. Mexico’s successful issuance, by
contrast, was primarily important as a source of information, and had little or
no coercive dimension. Finally, the IMF’s failure to prevent several countries
from falling into default may have been both relatively coercive, and an
267
Elsewhere, I have described the respective role of regulatory cues in facilitating coordination outcomes
generally, and in facilitating the Pareto efficient Nash equilibrium particularly. See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal,
supra note 5, at 247-48. Cues’ provision of information might be conceived as directed to these same two
ends. Some information points to coordination generally as optimal, while other information favors a
particular coordination outcome.
268
Besides offering information regarding the value of a particular equilibrium, regulatory cues might
also, by providing information, be seen to be enhancing that value. I am grateful to Steve Choi for noting this
point.
269
See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 934 (describing Ecuador’s exit consents as source of information
for other sovereign debtors).
270
The IMF, in fact, has supported several such studies.
271
See supra Part III.B.1.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 749
important source of information to participants in the coordination game of
sovereign debt contracting.
3. The Shifting Role of Regulatory Cues in Sovereign Debt Contract
Transition
A final point regarding the role of regulatory cues in facilitating change in
boilerplate contract terms concerns the application of such cues in distinct
circumstances and contexts. The need for greater or lesser coerciveness, as
well as the nature and extent of information offered by cues in facilitating
contract transition, can be expected to vary, depending on the particular
dynamic within which the relevant cue is meant to operate. Thus, different
demographic and transitional dynamics among participants in distinct cases of
boilerplate contract transition may demand different forms of regulatory cues.
Perhaps most importantly, this variable nature of cueing forms might be
expected to turn on the stability of the status quo equilibrium.
272
The longer
Nash equilibrium has been in place, the relatively greater the coercive tenor or
amount of information contained in any cue may have to be, in order to
achieve the desired change in player expectations. Additonally, the greater the
number of players who operate at the status quo equilibrium, and the
consequently greater the network value of that equilibrium, the greater the
potential need for coercion or information. In essence, shared expectations
may be more difficult to achieve across a larger and/or more heterogeneous
population. Across a wider universe of more diverse participants, information
may be more difficult to share, absent the public intervention of regulatory
cues.
273
Conflicting cues may also increase the need for more coercive-style
cues. Amidst the noise of various cues favoring an expectation of alternative,
and even competing, outcomes, cues of a coercive tenor may be particularly
focal, and hence effective.
Finally, even partial displacement of the dominant equilibrium may allow
relatively less coercive cues to facilitate efficient transition. Choi and Gulati’s
analysis of network effects in sovereign debt contracting would seem to
suggest as much.
274
Thus, as long as the dynamics of the market involved
272
Cf. Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 243.
273
It bears reiterating, in this regard, that regulatory cues’ degree of coerciveness and information-
provision are not competing characteristics. Rather, a given cue might be quite coercive in tenor, yet also
provide substantial coordination-related information.
274
See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 936-38.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
750 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
solely a choice between longstanding and widely adopted UACs and less
familiar CACs, existing cues were inadequate to trigger transition. In the
aftermath of Ecuador’s use of exit consents, however, this dynamic changed.
With Ecuador’s decision, the equilibrium choice of UACs was bifurcated into
two strategies, offering UACs as conventionally understood and applied or the
prospect of their circumvention through the use of exit consents.
275
Now, with
the focal character of UACs somewhat diminished, regulatory cues could
effectively shift the market to the CAC alternative.
276
As this analysis suggests, regulatory cues are not a panacea. While cues
may be as effective as regulatory coercion in the presence of network effects
and a resulting coordination dynamic, they will not always be so. While strong
network effects can enhance the efficacy of regulatory cues, they may also
raise too high a barrier to the effective operation of cues. In such
circumstances, ordinary regulation may be needed to at least displace the
inefficient status quo equilibrium, even if not necessarily to replace it.
Likewise, too great an array of conflicting cues, unlike the relative unanimity
of the signals identified above, may limit the efficacy of a cueing approach. At
least in sovereign debt contracting, however, noncoercive cues would appear to
have been sufficient to facilitate transition to the Pareto superior Nash
equilibrium of CACs.
IV. R
EGULATORY CUES IN THE INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL ARCHITECTURE
Having identified the role of regulatory cues in the recent transition from
UACs to CACs and described important aspects of the nature of such cues, a
few comments on the potential importance of cues in the ongoing transition in
sovereign debt contract standards deserve note. A role for cues remains
essential, but its precise scope and limitations must be appreciated as well.
A. Between Mandate and Market: Cueing Transition in Sovereign Debt
Contracting
This Article’s analysis has direct implications for the appropriate role of
national authorities and the IMF in facilitating more efficient sovereign debt
275
Choi and Gulati describe a similar conception of the consequence of Ecuador’s decision for the
existing equilibrium, and suggest it created additional axes along which sovereign debt contracts might vary.
See id. at 933.
276
Additional Nash equilibria might also reduce the prospects of displacement, however, by diminishing
the focal force of a singular alternative equilibrium, such as CACs.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 751
restructuring. Until now, the debate around this issue has been posed as a
choice between the IMF’s institutional approach
the creation of an
SDRM
and the contractual approach favored by the United States, which
hoped the increased use of CACs would reduce delays and other inefficiencies
in debt restructuring. As between these stark alternatives, cueing theory stands
somewhat closer to a contractual approach. It suggests that an efficient scheme
for sovereign debt restructuring can emerge without the need for the complex
mandates and institutions of the SDRM.
Yet cueing theory goes further in its challenge to the need for regulatory
mandate in sovereign debt contract transition. Before the recent shift to CACs,
many proponents of the contractual approach could be heard to encourage
regulators to dictate the universal adoption of CACs. Many thus argued for
IMF conditionality to be used to mandate sovereign debtors’ use of CACs.
277
Cueing theory would deny the need for such regulation, a view seemingly
affirmed by the noncoerced shift of the market in 2003. Yet even as CACs
have become the norm, notwithstanding the lack of regulatory mandate, calls
for coercive regulation have not abated, including among contractarians. A
strong chorus has thus called for regulatory intervention to dictate
standardization in the terms of collective action utilized in sovereign debt
contracts.
278
New debt contracts have adopted varying percentage requirements
for majority action (as well as distinct definitions of a qualified majority), and
have applied those requirements to different sets of enumerated contract
changes. In the face of such divergence, many have proposed that the IMF and
national authorities mandate specific CAC provisions, in order to facilitate
ultimate convergence around those provisions: “[The international community]
needs to do more than examine, encourage and consider. Without the
introduction of actual legislation and regulation in the creditor countries,
progress on this front is unlikely.”
279
277
See Boorman, supra note 15, at 67-68. Others proposed that domestic authorities, such as the SEC, act
to dictate transition to CACs. See Roubini & Setser, supra note 14, at 13 -14 (describing potential regulatory
interventions by the SEC and various international institutions); see also Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7. A
cueing theory of contract transition, however, denies the need for the SEC to mandate CACs in SEC-registered
bonds, see Roubini & Setser, supra note 14, at 23 -24, or to make CACs a legal requirement for enforcement of
bonds in U.S. courts (in an inversion of the Trust Indenture Act, see E
ICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at
36), or for the IMF to amend its Articles of Agreement or offer preferred interest rates based on the use of
CACs. See Eichengreen, Crisis Resolution, supra note 54, at 15.
278
Even Under Secretary of Treasury John Taylor has suggested a potential need to mandate adoption of
standardized CACs. See E
ICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 36-37.
279
Portes, supra note 16, at 71; Eichengreen, Crisis Resolution, supra note 54, at 15.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
752 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
Cueing theory, by contrast, suggests that network effects can be expected to
achieve desirable standardization, without the need for coercive public
intervention. Again, recollection of the coordination game dynamic at work in
sovereign debt contracting is helpful: In this environment, players hope to
agree
to convergein order to tap beneficial network effects, and simply
require the information necessary to develop accurate expectations of one
another. This, of course, is adequately offered by noncoercive regulatory
cues.
280
This is not to suggest that there may not be other reasons to mandate
transition, or subsequent standardization, in sovereign debt contracting. Barry
Eichengreen suggests the need to adopt CACs as a matter of law, given the
risks of litigation
281
and other potential difficulties.
282
While there may be
numerous reasons to mandate the adoption of CACs, and particular forms
thereof, cueing theory counsels that neither the goal of adoption generally, nor
a desire for rapid adoption or even uniform CAC standards, requires
mandate.
283
With the careful use of regulatory cues, rapid and widespread
adoption of standardized terms can be predicted.
Notwithstanding the challenge of cueing theory to the imposition of
regulatory mandate, however, it does not favor a purely contractual approach
to sovereign debt restructuring standards either. While cueing theory
challenges the argument for mandate, it likewise recognizes limits on the
capacity of the market to facilitate efficient transition on its own. As we have
already seen, in the network environment of sovereign debt contracts,
unanimous action standards were locked-in and difficult to displace, despite
their relative inefficiency.
284
280
See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 255-59 (describing capacity of cues to function without
need for public sanction). Thus, while I agree with Choi and Gulati that contract standardization may require
some extra-contractual process or regime, I offer the possibility that it may not. See Choi & Gulati, supra note
5, at 932.
281
See Eichengreen, Crisis Resolution, supra note 54, at 9-10.
282
See id. at 11-12. Because Eichengreen highlights adverse selection as a central obstacle to efficient
transition, he argues for greater intervention than the present analysis suggests, including proposals for IMF
conditionality and favorable interest rates for CAC users. See id. at 15. In subsequent analyses, in fact,
Eichengreen has suggested even more aggressive forms of regulatory intervention, given questions of the
legality of the foregoing approaches, as well as questions of time consistency.
283
See id. at 12-13 (proposing amendment of IMF Articles or domestic law to encourage adoption of
CACs).
284
See supra notes 150-73 and accompanying text.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 753
Even with the prevailing standard of UACs now eliminated, there is no
guarantee that the standard that emerges will be optimal. Notwithstanding the
capacity of network effects to produce desirable standardization, as described
above, the pattern of tipping in network environments also means that there is
no guarantee of efficient outcomes.
285
Rather, in network environments, a first-
mover is likely to prevail.
286
If network size matters, each new entrant can be
expected to elect the largest available network, producing a bandwagon effect
leading to the initial entrant. This will be true, at least at the margin, regardless
of the efficiency of the preliminary standard.
287
The dominant first-mover is
unlikely to be displaced, moreover, once it establishes itself. With network
effects, thus, a suboptimal standard will not necessarily fail or quickly be
replaced.
288
Rather, in network environments, “[i]nefficient institutions that are
not conducive to economic growth and development can emerge and
survive.”
289
As a result, a network effects and coordination game theory of sovereign
debt contracting cannot endorse a purely contractual approach to the evolution
of contracting norms and standards, whether it be the choice of UACs or
CACs, the election of a particular form of CAC, or the determination of other
standard-setting issues.
290
Instead, cueing theory suggests that some public
impetus may be needed for efficient sovereign debt contract transition.
291
“The
285
See Ahdieh, Making Markets, supra note 5, at 316-17; see also Katz & Shapiro, supra note 174, at 94
(noting first-mover advantages arising from sunk costs of particular computer systems). This outcome, of
course, assumes exclusivity—that is, an inability to join multiple networks at once. Cf. Bratton & Gulati,
supra note 7 (noting first-mover issues).
286
See Joseph F. Brodley & Ching-to Albert Ma, Contract Penalties, Monopolizing Strategies, and
Antitrust Policy, 45 S
TAN. L. REV. 1161, 1163-64 (1993) (noting that new entrants into a market often find
themselves handicapped by their late arrival); cf. Nicholas Economides, The Economics of Networks, 14 I
NTL
J. INDUS. ORG. 673, 694 (1996); Katz & Shapiro, supra note 174, at 107.
287
See Karl Warneryd, Network Externality and Convention, in 2 DICTIONARY OF ECONOMICS AND THE
LAW, supra note 181, at 676 (noting decisive character of initial player’s strategy in sequential coordination
game). Conversely, potential first-mover advantages and tipping-related monopoly rents might also serve to
spur competition and industry growth, as some believe has occurred in Silicon Valley.
288
See Daniel R. Fischel & Sanford J. Grossman, Customer Protection in Futures and Securities Markets,
4 J. F
UTURES MKTS. 273, 292 (1984).
289
Stefan Voigt & Hella Engerer, Institutions and Transformation—Possible Policy Implications of the
New Institutional Economics, in F
RONTIERS IN ECONOMICS 131, 139 (Klaus F. Zimmermann ed., 2002); see
Shelanski & Sidak, supra note 98, at 9 (“The market leaders will set the technological standard . . . even if
other technological standards are superior in some economic or engineering sense.”).
290
The persistence of pari passu clauses may also evidence network lock-in. See Choi & Gulati, supra
note 5, at 998.
291
See Roubini & Setser, supra note 14, at 13, 24. As noted above, even the U.S. Department of the
Treasury seems to have acknowledged the need for some public intervention in the sovereign debt markets,
suggesting a need for collective agreement on the contractual approach as the preferred model and the
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
754 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
historical evidenceand developments since the Mexican crisis
indicate that
the markets will not spontaneously achieve [efficient] outcomes. The
equivalent of law is required, although not the kind of law that would be
needed to establish an international bankruptcy court.”
292
The kind of “law”
that is needed, I would suggest, is regulatory cueing.
Choi and Gulati’s analysis of the patterns of transition in sovereign debt
contracts resonates with this conclusion. To this effect, they speak of small
changes that may help lead to even larger later changes.
293
Likewise, they
describe a role for the official sector grounded in the exact tasks of
encouragement, education, and facilitation that regulatory cues are meant to
achieve.
294
Bratton and Gulati also echo the notion of an initial cueing-like role for the
official and public sector, followed by a more limited (but still essential, I
suggest below) role thereafter:
Under this view, a sovereign bankruptcy regime need do little more
than trump UACs with CACs and then leave the parties free to
renegotiate their contracts. With CACs in place (however imposed),
the parties simply can be remitted to the law governing their
contracts—the law of the State of New York in most cases—without
needing the adjudicatory or administrative assistance of a bankruptcy
infrastructure.
295
Yet cueing theory differs slightly at both ends. Bratton and Gulati hint at
greater dictation of CACs at the outset than a cueing approach would suggest.
Thus, in their view, “[i]f the contractarian strategy is to accomplish anything,
the IMF, the U.S. Treasury, and the other G-7 nations will have to use financial
threats to induce the move.”
296
Further, from the perspective of cueing theory,
development of “incentives to encourage borrowers and lenders to incorporate such terms.” See Taylor,
Sovereign Debt Restructuring, supra note 15. In fact, John Taylor has suggested the potential for even
stronger measures, including an IMF requirement of CACs, as well as preferential IMF interest rates for bonds
incorporating such clauses. See id. While cueing theory rejects this position, earlier Treasury assertions that
no official action was necessary to achieve a transition to CACs. See Portes, supra note 16, at 67 (quoting
Larry Summers, the former Under Secretary of Treasury for International Affairs, that the official sector
should not “mandate the terms of debt contracts” or even adopt policies to induce borrowers to include them).
292
Portes, supra note 16, at 50-51.
293
See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 934.
294
See id. at 998; see also id. at 998, n.110 (“In the sovereign context, it is likely that the many official
sector efforts at supporting research on new contract terms, in organizing conferences, and setting up drafting
committees, all played an important role in producing change.”).
295
Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7.
296
Id. at 67.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 755
their analysis downplays the role of state action in the ensuing evolution of
contract standards.
Ultimately, a cueing approach offers the benefit of efficient transition,
without dictation. It leaves the final determination of efficient outcomes to the
market itself, which can decline to follow any relevant cues, and can
circumvent the outcomes they lead to, should efficiency dictate as much.
297
Thus might a cueing model, finally, be analogized to Randal Picker’s notion of
“seeding norm clusters,” by which public authorities selectively encourage
certain norms, and see what happens.
298
Norm seeding is a low-risk strategy. If the government seeds an
inefficient cluster, it will die, and little will be lost. If the new norm
is superior to the old norm, however, the artificially created norm
cluster will thrive and spread. This analysis suggests that the
government should embrace test policies or norms or take steps to
foster social meanings in particular local contexts as a way of testing
whether a superior approach can take root and spread.
299
Like norm seeding, a cueing model of state action in sovereign debt
contracting does what is necessary to break network-driven coordination
logjams at the outset, and at successive stages of the transition to new contract
standards, but does not dictate the results of that transition. Ultimate outcomes
are left to the sovereign debt market itself.
B. The Continuing Role of Regulatory Cues in Sovereign Debt Contract
Transition
As suggested above, beyond their preliminary role in facilitating the shift
from UACs to CACs, regulatory cues continue to have an important, if limited,
role in sovereign debt contracting. A variety of significant issues in the design
and standardization of CACs remain unresolved.
300
Perhaps most important is
the risk of minority creditor abuse under CACs.
301
With the adoption of CACs,
there is an urgent need for the development of norms of good faith and fair
dealing, to prevent the exploitation of minority creditors by newly empowered
majorities.
302
This need has triggered discussion of a “code of conduct” for
297
See Ahdieh, Law’s Signal, supra note 5, at 256; Eichengreen, supra note 16, at 94 -95.
298
See Picker, supra note 260, at 1284-85; see also Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 998.
299
Picker, supra note 260, at 1285.
300
See EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 39-40.
301
See Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7; Gulati & Skeel, supra note 4, at 5.
302
See Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12, at 1336-42.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
756 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
sovereign debt restructuring.
303
Yet the development of such a code will
require ongoing coordination to define its terms. As a preliminary matter, in
fact, debtors and creditors will need to coordinate their choice of a code or
various competing possibilities, including Bratton and Gulati’s preference for
common law adjudication of intercreditor duties in U.S. courts,
304
the IMF’s
proposal to require that all creditors receive the same settlement offer (or menu
of offers),
305
and the possible use of trust deeds.
306
Another outstanding issue of some importance concerns the aggregation of
debt restructuring across classes of bonds, especially in those cases where the
relevant sovereign has a wide array of bonds outstanding.
307
To address such
aggregation problems, there is a continuing need to develop some form of
“super-CAC,” a norm on the use of bondholder committees, or a relevant code
of creditor conduct.
308
Again, the market itself has begun this process, as
suggested by the use of super-CACs in Uruguay’s 2003 bonds,
309
but cues may
be important in facilitating a transition to such terms.
Finally, a variety of more specific standardization issues are still
outstanding.
310
Thus, it remains unclear whether the relevant percentage
required for majority action should be tied to attendance at a meeting with
quorum, as in English law majority action clauses, or should be a percentage of
outstanding debt.
311
Likewise, the exact percentage required for majority
action remains to be determined, with Brazil having set a rate of eighty-five
percent,
312
rather than the conventional seventy-five percent. There also
303
See EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 5, 30-32. On the value of such a code, see id. at 32. Much
of the general discussion of codes of conduct, has been directed to the conduct of debtors. See Roubini &
Setser, supra note 14, at 10-11. With the adoption of CACs, however, the conduct of majority creditors
toward minority creditors, in the exercise of their majority action rights, is a newly significant concern.
304
See Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7.
305
See INTL MONETARY FUND, THE RESTRUCTURING OF SOVEREIGN DEBT—ASSESSING THE BENEFITS,
R
ISKS, AND FEASIBILITY OF AGGREGATING CLAIMS 14 (Sept. 3, 2003), available at http://www.imf.org/
external/np.pdr/sdrm/2003/090303.pdf.
306
See INTL MONETARY FUND, THE DESIGN AND EFFECTIVENESS OF COLLECTION ACTION CLAUSES 10
(June 6, 2002), available at http://www.imf.org/external/np/psi/2002/eng/060602.pdf.
307
See Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12, at 1344; Skeel, supra note 25, at 422-23; see also EICHENGREEN
ET AL., supra note 14, at 4, 15; Boorman, supra note 15, at 66.
308
See EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 5.
309
See Gulati & Skeel, supra note 4, at 4; see also EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 29-30. On the
array of innovations in the Uruguay issue, see Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 946-47.
310
See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 947-49 (identifying variety of issues on which a standard has not
emerged to date); Porzecanski, supra note 178, at 24.
311
Cf. Buchheit & Gulati, supra note 12, at 1324-25.
312
See Gulati & Skeel, supra note 4, at 5. Guatemala’s bonds also set an eighty-five percent level. See
Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 981.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 757
continues to be a need to reconcile various contractual provisions indirectly
related to the potential for collective action.
313
These provisions include
requirements for information sharing and disclosure,
314
as well as potential
“engagement” requirements.
315
As competing approaches and proposals emerge, regulatory cues can help
to encourage particular standards, to avoid premature lock-in, and, perhaps
more importantly, to offer valuable information on various alternatives. In this
way, cues can help to facilitate the emergence of an efficient regime of CACs,
just as they have already contributed to the preliminary shift from UACs to
CACs.
C. Convergence and Fragmentation in Sovereign Debt Contracting
While I have emphasized the network tendency toward standardization, it
bears noting in conclusion that the proposed network conception of sovereign
debt contracting does not necessitate complete convergence to a network
standard.
316
Rather, network effects in sovereign debt may favor beneficial
standardization, yet permit some persistent diversity. A network theory of
sovereign debt is thus readily reconciled with both the long persistence of
MACs in English law bonds, notwithstanding the network predominance of
UACs,
317
and with the continued use of UACs by a very small group of issuers
under New York law, even today.
318
313
See Boorman, supra note 15, at 67.
314
See Gulati & Skeel, supra note 4, at 4-5.
315
See EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 30-31. Cueing theory also has implications for the so-
called “transition problem,” which concerns the large pool of existing sovereign debt without CACs. See id. at
25. From a network/coordination game perspective, this is not an especially significant concern. While the
transition problem has been asserted to favor creation of an SDRM, see Boorman, supra note 15, at 66;
Roubini & Setser, supra note 14, at 11, if a network effects analysis is warranted, transition should not be
unduly difficult. Rather, market participants can be expected to voluntarily switch to CACs in due course.
A related concern has been the potential for a regression to UACs. See E
ICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note
14, at 4, 17-18; Bratton & Gulati, supra note 7. A network analysis suggests that is unlikely to occur. Given
the network tendency toward lock-in, such regression would require overcoming the network size benefits of
remaining with the newly dominant CAC standard.
316
Nor does it entirely obviate the benefits of innovation. See Kahan & Klausner, supra note 107, at 350
(describing benefits of innovation).
317
The same is true of the persistence of different forms of UACs and CACs, both in the past and today.
This diversity is described by Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 963-65.
318
These include Israel, China, and the Philippines. See id. at 970. Ribstein and Kobayashi have
critiqued the network theory of corporate contracting along such lines. See Ribstein & Kobayashi, supra note
98, at 117-18. For the reasons outlined above, this criticism is inapposite.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
758 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
Both the long persistence of UACs and MACs in sovereign debt contracts
and the continued use of various forms of each
319
are consistent with the
network dynamic described above, because of the existence of both network
and inherent value in any contract term (or other network good).
320
Depending
on the particular balance of network and inherent utility that a given user
derives from the relevant good or service
that is, the blend of value
dependent on, and independent of, network size
321
some users may find that
the inherent benefits of the non-network dominant choice outweigh the
network gains of its more widely used competitor.
322
Such is the claim, for
example, of insistent users of Apple personal computers.
323
In the eyes of the
latter, greater ease of use, fewer crashes, and other perceived benefits are worth
more than the greater access to software and repair services and other network
gains that would follow from their use of the dominant Microsoft Windows
operating system.
With sovereign debt contracts, this pattern may be manifest in some
preference for UACs among higher credit risk sovereign debtors.
324
Empirical
analysis has thus suggested that high-risk sovereigns may be forced to pay a
premium by shifting to CACs (in the form of a wider spread), while low-risk
borrowers will enjoy a savings from that shift.
325
It is at least possible, then,
that the inherent benefits of UACs for high-risk debtors might outweigh any
network benefit of being on the dominant network of CACs. That this was an
important explanatory variable in the failure of the pre-2003 market to
converge completely around the network-dominant UAC standard is suggested
319
See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 961-63. Choi and Gulati develop a theory of such persistence,
based on the costs of larger, versus smaller, innovations. See id. at 945-46.
320
See supra notes 100-04 and accompanying text.
321
See supra notes 100-04 and accompanying text.
322
See Lemley & McGowan, supra note 98, at 592.
323
See Pamela Samuelson & Suzanne Scotchmer, The Law and Economics of Reverse Engineering, 111
Y
ALE L.J. 1575, 1617-18 (2002).
324
See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 965 (“Indeed, we expect that a range of preferences may exist
among countries for collective-action oriented modification terms. Some countries may desire UACs without
possibility of modification as a means of convincing investors of the countries’ low-risk of default.”).
325
See Portes, supra note 16, at 68-69; see also EICHENGREEN ET AL., supra note 14, at 4. At first glance,
this result may appear counterintuitive. The shift of lower-risk sovereign debtors to CACs ought to mean little
to the market, given the low risk of their default. High-risk debtors, on the other hand, ought to be rewarded
for their shift to CACs, given the consequently greater ease of handling their much more likely future debt
restructuring. Yet low-risk debtors gain, and high-risk debtors lose. The key to this puzzle lies in the central
emphasis of the sovereign debt markets on moral hazard. From the latter perspective, the high-risk debtors
with CAC bonds may be more prone to pursue restructuring, given its greater ease. The low-risk sovereign, by
contrast, is expected to be adequately constrained by the reputational harm attendant to any restructuring, and
will therefore avoid it, regardless of its greater or lesser ease, under CACs or UACs, respectively.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 759
by the relatively strong tendency of emerging market issuers to issue UAC
bonds under New York law, rather than MAC bonds under English law.
326
The persistence of a small network of UACs after the transition to CACs
may also be explained by diminishing or even declining network returns to
scale, beyond some point in the demand curve.
327
Thus, network gains may
accrue up to some level of use of a given term. At that point, sufficient use
may exist to produce the desired degree of interpretive network effects,
common practice network effects, and legal services network effects.
Additional adoptions beyond that point may offer little added network utility to
existing users.
328
In that case, users on a smaller, yet sufficiently large, network
would not be expected to shift to the dominant network. Even more
significantly, one might imagine a point beyond which use of a given term
begins to produce negative externalities. For example, a scarce supply of legal
or financial services may become more difficult or costly to access. Excessive
judicial review might also potentially produce too great a diversity of
interpretation, and hence an increase rather than decrease in uncertainty.
329
Given as much, the benefits of flexible regulatory cues becomes especially
evident, as compared with the public mandate of a particular majority standard
for collective action, a specific enumeration of good faith obligations, or the
transition to CACs generally. In essence, regulatory cues offer sovereign
debtors and their creditors freedom to define their preferred terms, and thereby
maximize efficiency gains. While some standardization can be predicted to
result from this process, given the presence of network effects, debtors and
creditors who find sufficient inherent value in preserving the non-network
standard can do so in a regulatory scheme characterized by cues rather than
coercion.
326
See Mody, supra note 17, at 14.
327
See Robert B. Ahdieh, Playing Games: Chicken, Battle of the Sexes, and the Model of Securities
Market Transition 13 (unpublished manuscript, on file with author).
328
See id. at 19.
329
See id. at 23; Klausner, supra note 39, at 777 n.65. Besides these network-specific points, it bears
noting that network tipping need not entail instantaneous change. Rather, a progressive transition is also
consistent with the presence of network effects. The present phase of transition may therefore exhibit a greater
degree of diversity than is likely to exist in the near future. This, in fact, comports with the pattern of
transition described by Choi and Gulati. See Choi & Gulati, supra note 5, at 969-71 (analyzing “big shift”
hypothesis).
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
760 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
CONCLUSION
Freedom of contract is among the foundational features of the U.S. legal
system. Yet network-driven lock-in of contract boilerplate
and the
potentially related reliance on standard-form contracts
present some
challenge to contractual autonomy, broadly defined. If network effects
significantly restrain contracting parties in their selection of Pareto efficient
contract terms, their contractual freedom might fairly be seen as constrained.
In this Article, I have considered the potential lock-in of contract
boilerplate, and how such lock-in might be overcome, using the shift from
stasis to change in sovereign debt contracting as a salient example. But the
implications of the present analysis extend beyond the natural experiment of
sovereign debt contract transition. If network effects constitute an important
explanation of contract term lock-in, whether in sovereign debt contracts,
corporate or real estate contracts, or other standardized agreements, it is
important to consider whether there might be a broader regulatory role in
preserving contractual choice than is ordinarily acknowledged.
330
Public intervention may help to overcome network barriers to efficient
contracting, yet not create its own obstacles to freedom of contract, through the
noncoercive intervention of regulatory cues. At a minimum, such cues may
serve to displacebut not precludestatus quo equilibrium, and thereby
facilitate contracting parties’ election of efficient alternatives. Cues may also
offer beneficial information on the relative utility of preserving an existing
coordination equilibrium versus adopting an alternative. In these and other
ways outlined above, regulatory cues can serve to facilitate coordination
around efficient contracting norms.
It might be questioned, however, whether the lessons of sovereign debt
contracting emphasized in this Article can be applied outside the peculiar
330
Freedom of contract has long been a theme in the study of standard-form contracts and boilerplate
contract terms. Most commonly, it has been invoked to enforce boilerplate and other terms incorporated by
the drafter, in recognition of a “duty to read.” Llewellyn, conversely, cites freedom of contract for just the
opposite conclusion, arguing that rote enforcement of boilerplate terms eviscerates the freedom of the party
bound, who has not, in any meaningful sense, assented to the relevant terms. See K
ARL N. LLEWELLYN, THE
COMMON LAW TRADITION: DECIDING APPEALS 365-67 (1960). The network effects-driven pattern described
herein likewise challenges the freedom of contract, not of one party or the other, but arguably of both.
Network lock-in, and the resulting constraint on parties’ ability to avoid inefficient constructions, or to elect an
efficient alternative, is a distinct sort of challenge—but not an unimportant one—to freedom of contract in the
broadest sense.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
2004] BETWEEN MANDATE AND MARKET 761
institutional context of the international financial architecture. In particular,
official action would seem to stand more in the foreground of sovereign debt
contracting than it does in conventional contracting, in which public actors
would appear to play a lesser role. Yet this may be just the point: State action
may deserve a more prominent place in contracting environments
whether
international or domestic
in which standard terms are widely used.
It is not
evident, thus, that the relative prominence of official action in sovereign debt
contracting rests on any difference in kind with domestic contracting.
Relevant regulatory cues will surely have a distinct character and form in
different contracting environments, including international versus domestic
settings. When a coordination dynamic exists, however, regulatory cues may
still have an important role to play.
Just as the normative values of the freedom of contract favor a cueing
approach to public intervention in private contracting, the dynamics of
transnational regulation may also favor a reliance on regulatory cues. As
evident in the case of sovereign debt contracting, cross-border regulation is of
growing importance in today’s increasingly globalized marketplace. In areas
from antitrust to securities law, transnational coordination has become
essential to regulatory success. Regulatory cuesas a mechanism of
coordinationmay constitute a valuable implement in the toolkit of national
and international regulators. Through noncoercive cues, transnational policy
ends may be effectively pursued, while preserving norms of national
sovereignty and avoiding the extraterritorial application of law.
331
Regulatory cues, in this vein, may be a particularly useful tool in the hands
of constrained public regulators. Weak regulatory authoritywhether born of
normative design, as in the desire to maximize the freedom of contract; of
institutional constraints, as in the international regime; or of the recency of
national development, as in many transitional statesmay prevent reliance on
ordinary command-and-control regulation. In the presence of a coordination
dynamic, however, noncoercive cues may be an effective regulatory
alternative.
A cueing theory of law might thus be said to offer both negative and
positive lessons for theories of contract and transnational regulation. In the
negative, cueing theory posits that ordinary regulationwith its mandate and
331
To this effect, Anne-Marie Slaughter has suggested the growing importance of soft power in
international law and regulation given the inevitable limitations of hard power in the international sphere. See
S
LAUGHTER, supra note 266, at 4.
Hosted by The Berkeley Electronic Press
16891-TEXT.NATIVE.1115237184 5/4/2005 1:10 PM
762 EMORY LAW JOURNAL [Vol. 53
coercionmay not be necessary to overcome barriers to efficiency and
achieve efficient outcomes. In the positive, cueing theory offers an alternative
mode of public regulation. In the realm between the conventional poles of
mandate and the market, cueing theory suggests a pattern of regulation that is
at once adequate to achieve desired policy ends, yet restrained in its
interference with contractual and national autonomy.
http://law.bepress.com/emorylwps/art6