Tax Policy Choices
and New York City’s
Competitive Position
Prepared by Donald Boyd
for the Citizens Budget Commission
Citizens Budget Commission
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
TABLE OF CONTENTS
INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................................................................................................1
NEW YORK IN A COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE ...................................................................................................................2
TAXES AND MIGRATION .................................................................................................................................................................7
Lessons from the Literature .....................................................................................................................................................7
Migration in the New York Region .........................................................................................................................................9
NEW YORK CITY PERSONAL INCOME TAX POLICY ........................................................................................................12
NEW YORK CITY PROPERTY TAX POLICY ............................................................................................................................16
A Comparative View of Commercial Property Taxes ....................................................................................................16
Disparities between Commercial and Small Residential Property ...........................................................................18
CONCLUSION ..................................................................................................................................................................................21
APPENDIX A ......................................................................................................................................................................................22
APPENDIX B ......................................................................................................................................................................................25
APPENDIX C ......................................................................................................................................................................................26
APPENDIX D ......................................................................................................................................................................................27
ENDNOTES ........................................................................................................................................................................................29
Citizens Budget Commission
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
1
INTRODUCTION
The purpose of this background paper is to help inform tax policy choices that the new mayoral
administration may face. It examines levels of taxation in New York City compared to other cities, and
it reviews research on how taxes affect the local economy and migration patterns. The focus is on the
personal income tax and the real property tax, particularly the tax on commercial property. These are
two elements of tax policy for which New York City has distinctive policies and for which changes may
be considered.
The paper is organized in four sections. The first describes the structure of local taxes in New York City
and compares it to that of other large cities in the United States. The second reviews the literature
on the relationship between taxes and migration of residents and employment, and it presents data
on the current pattern of residential choice and migration in the New York region. The third focuses
on the local personal income tax, indicating how hypothetical increases in the rate structure would
affect household tax burdens. The fourth section focuses on the tax on commercial property indicating
how New York City compares to other large cites in this type of tax and commenting on the possible
implications of an increase.
Citizens Budget Commission
2
NEW YORK IN A COMPARATIVE PERSPECTIVE
New York City’s taxes are high. A comprehensive and unique study by the New York City Independent
Budget Office used data from 2004 to compare cities with a population over 1 million, computing taxes
as a percentage of taxable resources.
1
It found that New York City’s state and local taxes were the
highest among large cities by far: state and local taxes were 46 percent higher than the average for the
other cities, and local taxes were 90 percent higher than the average for other cities. (See Table 1.) The
combined state and local personal income tax in New York City was more than three times as high in
the other cities, and accounted for three quarters of the difference between New York and the other
cities.
Table 2 shows the state and the local burden for the individual cities. New York City’s taxes were 26
percent higher than the second-highest city, Philadelphia. The personal income tax was much higher
than in the four other cities that had such a tax. Business income taxes were double or even triple the
level in five of the eight other cities. The property tax was higher than in every city but San Antonio. The
sales tax and “other taxes” were typically lower than in other cities.
Average of
other cities New York City
Per $100 of
taxable
resources
Percent of
difference
Percent above
or below
Property tax $ 1.89 $ 2.28 $ 0.39 13.6% 20.6%
Sales tax 1.73 1.56 (0.17) -5.9% -9.8%
Personal income tax 0.95 3.12 2.17
75.9% 228.4%
Business income taxes 0.55 1.06 0.51 17.8% 92.7%
Other taxes 1.04 1.00 (0.04) -1.4% -3.8%
Total $ 6.16 $ 9.02 $ 2.86 100.0% 46.4%
Property tax $ 1.89 $ 2.28 $ 0.39 14.7
% 20.6%
Sales tax 0.52 0.82 0.30 11.3% 57.7%
Personal income tax 0.10 1.11 1.01 38.0% 1010.0%
Business income taxes 0.12 0.71 0.59 22.2% 491.7%
Other taxes 0.33 0.70 0.37
13.9% 112.1%
Total $ 2.96 $ 5.62 $ 2.66 100.0% 89.9%
Source: Author's analysis of informaon in New York City Independent Budget Oce, Comparing State and Local Taxes in Large U.S. Cies,
February 2007.
Note: Comparison cies are Los Angeles, Chicago, Houston, Philadelphia, Phoenix, San Diego, San Antonio and Dallas.
Table 1: State and Local Taxes in New York City and Average of Other Large U.S. Cities, 2004
Taxes per $100 of taxable
r
esources New York City above (below) average
State and local taxes
Local taxes only
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
3
Another comparison of taxes in individual cities is prepared annually by the Chief Financial Officer
of the District of Columbia. It calculates personal income tax, property tax, sales tax, and automobile
taxes on representative households in the District and in the largest city in each state (51 cities in
total) at five income levels ranging from $25,000 to $150,000. The study reasonably varies household
property values among locations (for example, at a given income level a New York City homeowner is
likely to own a more expensive house than a person with the same income in Boise, Idaho), but in other
respects the households are the same from place to place. Depending on the year of the study, the
household is assumed to have either one or two children.
Because this study considers only direct taxes on households, it does not take into account taxes on
businesses that may be borne in part by households or that may affect regional economies in other
ways. For example, the Independent Budget Office study considers all property taxes in New York City,
including taxes on commercial property, which are quite high, whereas the District of Columbia study
only includes homeowner property taxes, which in New York City are quite low. Still, it is a useful way
to examine direct taxes on households, and it is cited widely.
Table 3 shows taxes at each income level, relative to the median for 51 cities, for 21 cities that ranked in
the top 10 for one or more income levels in 2011, the last year for which data are available. New York
City’s ranking rises as income rises: the household with $25,000 of income pays 10.7 percent more in
taxes than a similar household in the median city, earning New York City the 16
th
-highest ranking, but
the New York City household with $150,000 of income pays 41.2 percent more than the median, the
third-highest ranking for this income group. Again, this does not reflect taxes on businesses, some of
which may be passed through to households in the form of higher utility bills, lower wages, or in other
ways. Because these taxes in New York City tend to be higher than in other cities, the indirect effects
could be large.
Table 4 focuses on the highest income households and the ten cities with the highest burden for that
group. New York City ranks number three, behind only Bridgeport and Philadelphia. New York’s
New York City $ 9.02 - - - - - -
Philadelphia 7.16 26.0% 57% 32% 39% -17% 0%
Los Angeles 6.88 31.1 39.0 (6.6) 72.4 53.6 (7.4)
San Antonio 6.73 34.0 (18.0) (37.8) n/a 341.7 (16.7)
Phoenix 6.25 44
.3 20.6 (46.0) 372.7 241.9 104.1
San Diego 6.01 50.1 54.1 (15.7) 93.8 107.8 75.4
Chicago 5.89 53.1 3.2 59.2 250.6 92.7 (20.6)
Houston 5.53 63.1 17.5 (20.4) n/a 171.8 (18.7)
Dallas 5.20 73.5
15.2 (12.8) n/a 158.5 (2.0)
Table 2: State and Local Taxes in New York City and Eight Other U.S. Cities, 2004
Percent that NYC is above (below) other city
Source: Author's analysis of informaon in New York City Independent Budget Oce, Comparing State and Local Taxes in Large U.S.
Cies, February 2007.
State & local
t
axes per $100 of
t
axable resources Total
Property
t
ax
Sales
t
ax
Personal
i
ncome tax
Business
i
ncome taxes
Other
t
axes
Citizens Budget Commission
4
high overall ranking is driven by its first-ranked personal income tax, which is 82.6 percent above the
median. Because New York City’s income tax is quite progressive and does not reach its top tax rate
until taxable income hits $500,000, the city’s relative ranking probably would rise if the study were to
include households with income of $500,000 or more.
Bridgeport 25.4% 5 161.1% 1 129.8% 1 100.9% 1 76.4% 1
Philadelphia 52.7 2 77.4 3 62.4 2 58.0 2 49.7 2
New York City 10.7 16 25.3 14 25.7 8 29.1 6 41.2 3
Columbus 14.0 12 53.7
4 41.1 4 38.7 3 36.9 4
Louisville 21.6 8 35.2 7 33.2 5 33.2 4 35.1 5
Baltimore (8.6) 39 28.4 11 26.1 6 27.0 7 28.6 6
Portland, ME (6.5)
33 21.2 15 17.3 13 18.7 10 23.3 7
Newark 1.5 25 95.3 2 48.3 3 31.8 5 20.3 8
Los Angeles 15.9 10 41.4 5 20.6 10 11.7 13 18.3 9
Detroit 10.
6 18 26.2 13 24.2 9 20.5 8 16.5 10
Milwaukee (6.5) 34 26.4 12 19.4 11 19.2 9 15.8 11
Chicago 31.9 4 36.6 6 25.9 7 18.4 11 11.2 14
Providenc
e 6.0 21 34.3 8 17.5 12 9.2 14 5.7 20
Atlanta 25.0 6 1.9 24 3.2 22 0.5 24 2.4 23
Boston 15.5 11 30.5 10 13.2 14 6.3 17 0.6
25
Burlington, VT (3.8) 31 31.0 9 10.5 15 0.6 23 (1.5) 30
Indianapolis 18.3 9 3.3 23 1.2 24 (0.8) 27 (1.7) 31
Birmingham, AL 52.9 1 3.5 22 - 26 (3.1)
28 (3.6) 33
Honolulu 39.5 3 (23.8) 43 (19.9) 39 (16.4) 37 (12.5) 37
Phoenix 23.6 7 (10.2) 33 (17.1) 38 (20.0) 38 (18.5) 40
$
75,000$50,000$25,000
Rank of
51
cities
Percent above
(below) median
of 51 cities
Rank of
51
cities
$
150,000$100,000
Percent above
(below) median
of 51 cities
Rank of
51
cities
Percent above
(below) median
of 51 cities
Rank of
51
cities
Percent above
(below) median
of 51 cities
Table 3: State and Local Taxes for Representative Households, Selected Cities, 2011
Source: Natwar M. Gandhi, Tax Rates and Tax Burdens in the District of Columbia - A Naonwide Comparison: 2011, Chief Financial Ocer, District of Columbia, September 2012.
Note: Cies shown are those ranked in the top 10 at one or more income levels, ordered by tax at $150,000.
Percent above
(below) median
of 51 cities
Rank of
51
cities
Bridgeport 12.4% 15 213.3% 1 -1.8% 30 128.3% 3 76.4% 1
Philadelphia 52.4 2 82.7 3 (0.3) 28 (37.0) 36 49.7 2
New York City 82.6 1 (9.4) 29 18.7 18 (44.0) 41 41.2 3
Columbus 37.0 6 66.4 4 -
26 (43.0) 39 36.9 4
Louisville 50.0 3 29.3 12 (4.7) 33 9.7 24 35.1 5
Baltimore 37.0 7 39.2 9 (2.8) 31 (43.1) 40 28.6 6
Portland, ME 24.0 9 35.9 10 (29.9)
45 68.6 9 23.3 7
Newark (37.5) 39 148.3 2 (4.6) 32 (65.8) 51 20.3 8
Los Angeles (18.8) 33 63.2 5 18.6 19 96.0 7 18.3 9
Detroit 42.4 5 (11.8) 30 (16.3) 41 (10
.6) 28 16.5 10
Percent above
(below) median
of 51 cities
Rank
of 51
cities
Percent above
(below) median
of 51 cities
Rank
of 51
cities
Percent above
(below) median
of 51 cities
Rank
of 51
cities
Percent above
(below) median
of 51 cities
Rank
of 51
cities
Percent above
(below) median
of 51 cities
Rank
of 51
cities
Table 4: State and Local Taxes on Households with $150,000 Income, Selected Cities, 2011
TotalAuto taxSales taxProperty taxPersonal income tax
Source: Natwar M. Gandhi, Tax Rates and Tax Burdens in the District of Columbia - A Naonwide Comparison: 2011, Chief Financial Ocer, District of Columbia,
September 2012.
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
5
Due to changes in methodology over time it is not appropriate to compare tax levels calculated in the
District of Columbia studies from one year to another, but rankings are more robust and provide useful
information. Table 5 shows New York City’s ranking at three income levels for the personal income tax,
sales tax, and total taxes for selected years. For the highest income group, the state and local personal
income tax in New York City was the highest in the nation for all available years. The income tax on
higher income households is the main reason that total state and local taxes on these households in
New York City have long been among the highest in the nation.
1997 20 1 1 NA NA NA 19 4 3
1999 23 1 1 NA NA NA 21 5 4
2001 15 2 1 28 28 28 25 6 5
2003 42 2 1 18 18 18 23 3 2
2005 35 5 1 13 18 16 22 8 2
2007 41 2 1
18 16 16 NA NA NA
2009 40 4 1 15 13 13 16 5 2
2011 40 5 1 16 11 18 16 8 3
T
otal taxesSales taxPersonal income tax
Table 5: Ranking of New York City State and Local Taxes Among 51 Cities, by Income Levels, Selected Years
Source: District of Columbia, Tax Rates and Tax Burdens in the District of Columbia - A Naonwide Comparison. Chief Financial Ocer, District of Columbia,
Various Years.
Notes: Methodological changes, parcularly for the sales tax between 1999 and 2001, may have aected rankings. Income levels are
not adjusted for
inaon.
NA - Denotes a year for which comparave rankings are not reliable.
$25,000 $75,000 $150,000 $25,000 $75,000 $150,000 $25,000 $75,000 $150,000
0.0%
0.5%
1.0%
1.5%
2.0%
2.5%
3.0%
Percentage of Gross City Product
Figure 1: Major New York City Taxes as a Percent of Gross City Product, 1980-2012
Property tax Personal income tax Sales tax Business taxes
Sources: Taxes from NYC Independent Budget Oce, hp://www.ibo.nyc.ny.us/RevenueSpending/TaxRevenue.xls; Gross City Product
from 1996-2012 from NYC Oce of Management and Budget, hp://www.nyc.gov/html/omb/downloads/pdf/ec07_13.pdf; earlier
years esmated by author.
Citizens Budget Commission
6
While New York City’s overall taxes have been high relative to other cities for years, there have been
important changes over time. Table 6 shows New York City taxes by major category as a percentage of
gross city product for 1980, 1985, and 1990 through 2012. The table also shows the change to 2012
from the 1991-1994 period average (a previous high point), from the 2000 low point, and from 2002,
the last mayoral changeover year. The 1.3 percentage point increase from 2002 as a share of gross city
product is an increase in the level of taxation of 25 percent. Taxes most likely were depressed in 2002
due to the stock market declines in prior years and to a national recession. But comparisons to 2003 or
2004 also show increases that are considerable, albeit not as large.
Among the taxes, the property tax has shown the greatest variability. (See Figure 1.) Its current level is
well above the low point in 2000 and close to the peak in 1991. The personal income tax has trended
upward with notable variability; its 2012 level is below the peak in 2008 but close to the level of 1998,
1999, and 2005-2007.
1980 2.75% 0.76% 0.98% 0.71% 0.79% 5.99%
1985 2.27% 0.93% 0.98% 0.76% 0.71% 5.66%
1990 2.53% 0.98% 0.94% 0.65% 0.71% 5.80%
1991 2.83% 1.09% 0.92% 0.68% 0.66% 6.18%
1992 2.82% 1.17% 0.82% 0.70% 0.64% 6.15%
1993 2.77% 1.22% 0.84% 0.73% 0.62% 6.18%
1994 2.65% 1.21% 0.85% 0.84% 0.61% 6.17%
1995 2.43% 1.17% 0.85% 0.71% 0.59% 5.75%
1996 2.13% 1.18% 0.82% 0.76% 0.54% 5.44%
1997 2.04% 1.23% 0.82% 0.82% 0.49% 5.39%
1998 1.97% 1.40% 0.83% 0.84% 0.50% 5.54%
1999 1.88% 1.36% 0.79% 0.72% 0.
52% 5.27%
2000 1.74% 1.24% 0.78% 0.73% 0.49% 4.97%
2001 1.88% 1.41% 0.84% 0.75% 0.50% 5.38%
2002 2.02% 1.15% 0.78% 0.65% 0.51% 5.11%
2003 2.20% 1.10% 0.77% 0.60% 0.54% 5.21%
2004 2.35% 1.23% 0.82% 0.67% 0.65% 5.72%
2005 2.14% 1.33% 0.81% 0.78% 0.74% 5.79%
2006 2.12% 1.35% 0.75% 0.85% 0.74% 5.81%
2007 2.07% 1.36% 0.73% 1.10% 0.81% 6.08%
2008 2.17% 1.63% 0.80% 1.03% 0.73% 6.37%
2009 2.43% 1.29% 0.77% 1.01% 0.54% 6.04%
2010 2.55% 1.18% 0.79% 0.81% 0.46% 5.79%
2011 2.62% 1.25% 0.86
% 0.94% 0.51% 6.19%
2012 2.76% 1.30% 0.89% 0.91% 0.55% 6.41%
C
hange to 2012 from:
1991-1994 average (0.00%) 0.13% 0.03% 0.17% (0.09%) 0.24%
2000 lowpoint 1.03% 0.06% 0.11% 0.18% 0.06% 1.43%
2002 0.74% 0.15% 0.11% 0.26% 0.04% 1.30%
1991-1994 average (0.1%) 11.1% 3.2% 22.6% (13.5%) 3.8%
2000 lowpoint 59.0% 4.8% 13.6% 25.0% 12.3% 28.8%
2002 36.7% 12.8% 13.9% 39.4% 8.9% 25.4%
Sources: Taxes from NYC Independent Budget Oce, hp://www.ibo.nyc.ny.us/RevenueSpending/TaxRevenue.xls; Gross City Product from 1996-2012
from NYC Oce of Management and Budget, hp://www.nyc.gov/html/omb/downloads/pdf/ec07_13.pdf; earlier years esmated by author.
Change in percentage points
Percentage change in level of taxation
Table 6: New York City Taxes as Percent of Gross City Product, 1980-2012
Property tax
Personal
i
ncome tax Sales tax
Business
i
ncome taxes Other taxes Total
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
7
TAXES AND MIGRATION
Are New York City’s taxes so high that they are damaging economic growth or causing taxpayers to
flee to other locations? This question is much harder to answer than whether the City’s taxes are
comparatively high, where the answer is clear cut.
This section of the paper seeks to address the harder question in two ways. First it reviews the
economic literature on the topic, focusing particularly on recent studies examining interstate migration
in response to increases in upper-income bracket state tax rates. The implications of these studies
for New York City tax policy must be considered carefully because of the limited parallels between
state and local (especially New York City) circumstances. A second subsection examines the current
situation with respect to outmigration from New York City and other parts of the region and with
respect to the residential decisions of high income earners within the New York region. These data
suggest that: (1) higher-income households in New York City are more likely to migrate out of the area
than similar households in other parts of the New York region, and (2) individuals with high earnings
from jobs in New York City are more likely to opt to commute from suburban counties than those with
lower earnings from jobs in the city.
Lessons from the Literature
Economists have been studying how taxes affect the economy for decades. The research has been
evolving, with data and methods improving, questions becoming more refined, and answers becoming
more nuanced. It is clear that taxes do affect the economy, although there is still enormous variation in
the estimated magnitude of the diverse impacts. This research generally concludes that the employment
and population impacts are likely to be greatest within regions rather than across large geographic
differences, and that the effects depend in part on what tax revenue is spent on, since spending can
have positive economic effects for example, spending on infrastructure or education could, under
some circumstances, increase private sector productivity.
2
Whether taxes in New York City are so high that further increases would reduce economic growth
so much that the tax increase would not yield a net revenue increase has been debated. One paper
based on data through 2001 found that New York City then was near the peak of its “revenue hills”
it was nearing the point where tax-rate increases would have large enough negative effects that tax
revenue would actually decline. The paper concluded that New York City had relatively little room to
increase personal income or property tax rates, with somewhat more room to increase the sales tax.
3
Another analysis challenged this finding, arguing that the analysis left out important determinants of
employment in New York City.
4
More recently several studies have examined the relationship between income tax rates and interstate
migration. In the past decade, several states enacted “millionaire” taxes – higher rates on high-income
taxpayers, sometimes starting at thresholds below $1 million. For example, in 2004 New Jersey
raised its rate on taxable income above $500,000 by 2.6 percentage points, from 6.37 percent to 8.97
percent.
5
California and Maryland also adopted increased rates on the highest-income taxpayers, and
several other states have increased top rates as well.
6
Two sets of studies have attempted to analyze millionaire-tax policies specifically. These studies are
summarized below and described more fully in Appendix A.
The first set of studies by Cristobal Young and Charles Varner used progressively better data and
methods to examine the relationship between migration of high-income taxpayers and income tax
rates in New Jersey. Their first study used summary data from New Jersey tax records, with counts
Citizens Budget Commission
8
of the number of half-millionaire households (“HMHs”) in New Jersey and the number of them that
migrated in or out of the state in each year from 2000 to 2007.
7
Thus, the data covered four years
before the tax increase and four years with the tax increase. They found that the average outmigration
rate increased after 2003 (a low year for outmigration) while the average inmigration rate decreased.
8
They then estimated how many HMHs might have been lost due to the tax increase and how much
revenue might have been lost. To develop upper bound estimates, they assumed that the increase
in the outmigration rate from 2003 was attributable to the tax increase, yielding an estimated
HMH outmigration rate increase of 0.2 percent. Similarly, they assumed that the decrease in the
inmigration rate compared to the highest inmigration year before 2004 (which was 2000) was due
to the tax increase, yielding an estimated decrease in inmigration of HMHs annually of 0.4 percent
of HMHs outside New Jersey. They calculated the potential revenue loss under the assumption that
outmigrants and “missing” inmigrants would not be replaced by people already in New Jersey. Under
this assumption, the estimated revenue loss was 4.2 percent of the revenue projected from the tax
increase assuming no migration impact.
In a second study Young and Varner used individual tax records from New Jersey on all taxpayers
with income of $200,000 or more for each year from 2000 through 2007.
9
They compared migration
behavior of taxpayers with incomes between $200,000 and $500,000, who were not subject to the
tax increase, with that of taxpayers with incomes above $500,000. Versions of the statistical analysis
included controls for age, marital status, number of children, and the composition of taxpayer income.
10
The main tax-related conclusions from this analysis were:
• Half-millionaires were more likely to have net outmigration than near-half-millionaires,
whether before or after the tax increase, and the top 0.1 percent of taxpayers were even more
likely to have net outmigration, again regardless of the tax policy.
• The differences in the increase in net outmigration of half-millionaires and of near-half
millionaires after the policy change was not statistically significant.
11
• Increased net outmigration was significantly related to the tax increase for two subgroups of
half-millionaires: (a) those in the top 0.1 percent of taxpayers and who earned all of their income
from investments, and (b) elderly half-millionaires, particularly those in the top 0.1 percent.
Using their results, Young and Varner estimated that the migration effects resulted in a potential loss
of 1.8 percent of an estimated $900 million static revenue gain from the tax increase.
12
This is lower
than their estimate of 4.2 percent in the first study.
A third study by Varner and Young examined the 2005 Mental Health Services Tax in California, which
raised the top rate on income above $1 million by one percentage point.
13
It used a panel data set
on California taxpayers to compare the behavior of taxpayers with income between $500,000 and
$1,000,000 (who did not face the tax increase) with those with incomes above $1,000,000. They found
no difference between how millionaires and near-millionaires responded to the policy change. In other
words, they found no effect of the tax increase on millionaire migration. It is not clear how meaningful
these results are for the New York, New Jersey, Connecticut metropolitan area: it is much harder for
taxpayers in California to move to another state and still access job opportunities and amenities of the
California economy than it is for taxpayers in New York or New Jersey to do so.
Two studies were conducted by staff of the New Jersey Department of the Treasury. These studies
used Internal Revenue Service data to relate interstate outmigration to tax rates, unemployment,
housing prices, and distances between states.
14
They found that outmigration is higher when marginal
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
9
tax rates are greater in the origin state than in a potential destination state. They used the findings to
estimate a seven-year impact on migration and tax revenue due to the New Jersey tax rate increase.
The estimated impact is larger (about 8 to 14 percent of revenue) than in the Young and Varner studies
for two reasons: (1) they find a greater initial migration response, and (2) they assume the higher
migration response persists over time rather than being a one-time response to the tax policy change.
These recent studies are interesting and controversial, but their relevance to income tax policy for
New York City is limited. The situation in New York City differs from that in New Jersey and California
because the tax rate in New York City is already at non-comparable levels for high earners and because
New York City high earners have the option of moving to nearby suburban counties in New York State
where income tax rates are lower, but California and New Jersey taxpayers do not have a similar
option. For these reasons, it may be more instructive to consider the current patterns of migration and
residence within the New York region.
Migration in the New York Region
Nationally people move frequently, but migrate from one state to another infrequently. Between
2010 and 2011, 11.6 percent of the population moved: 7.7 percent moved within the same county,
2.0 percent moved to a different county in the same state, and 1.6 percent moved to a different state.
15
When people do move, housing markets and job opportunities often play a major role.
16
Characteristics
such as marriage, having children present in the home, or owning a house, are major impediments to
moving.
17
Many of these characteristics are associated with people with higher incomes.
The American Community Survey (ACS), a relatively new national data source, permits analysis of
interstate and intraregional migration. For the New York region, it is possible to determine (1) how
much more likely people, and particularly high income individuals, living in New York City are to leave
the region than are similar people living in other parts of the region, and (2) how much more likely are
individuals with high-paying jobs in New York City to choose to live outside the city than those with
lower earnings.
Regional Outmigration. To address the first issue, it is possible to use the ACS for 2007-2011 to
compare regional outmigration for people aged 18 or older who were residents of New York City,
residents of other parts of the region in New York State (Nassau, Rockland, Suffolk, and Westchester
counties), residents of Fairfield County in Connecticut, and residents of the major commuting counties
in New Jersey (Bergen, Essex, Hudson, Middlesex, and Monmouth). Table 7 summarizes the results.The
first point evident from the table is that among the higher-income regional residents, New York City
residents are more likely to move out of their region than residents of the other parts of the region.
For example, 4.0 percent of New York City adults with income of $100,000 - $400,000 outmigrated
compared with only 1.6 percent of adult residents of other New York metropolitan counties, 3.1
percent of adult residents of Fairfield County, and 3.0 percent of adult residents in the New Jersey
counties.
18
The second point is that in other parts of the region higher-income residents are less likely to outmigrate
than residents with income under $100,000, but higher income New York City residents are at least
as likely to outmigrate as city residents with lower incomes. For example, 3.1 percent of residents
of Fairfield County with income of $100,000 -$400,000 outmigrated, compared to 5.8 percent of
residents with incomes up to $100,000; in contrast, in New York City the higher income residents
were at least as likely to move as those with incomes up to $100,000.
19
The people who live in New York City and the people who live in nearby counties may differ in ways that
help explain these different migration rates, but it is possible to control for some of those differences.
Citizens Budget Commission
10
Appendix B presents the results of a logistic regression of outmigration, with independent variables
drawn from those commonly found in prior research. The results generally are consistent with the
academic research – the people most likely to move are those who are unemployed or not in the labor
force, and people with more education; those least likely to move are married or have children present
in the house. However, of particular relevance to tax policy is the finding that after controlling for these
other factors, high-income people (income above $400,000) who live in New York City are more likely
to move than otherwise similar people in the surrounding counties. The appendix presents “odds ratios”
for each variable. For example, the odds ratio for income above $400,000 is 1.9792, or about 2. This
means the probability that someone with income above $400,000 will outmigrate is approximately
twice the probability that someone who is otherwise similar, but with lower income, will outmigrate.
20
If the outmigration probability for someone with a particular set of characteristics and income below
$400,000 was 3 percent, this suggests that an otherwise similar person with income above $400,000
would have an outmigration probability of 6 percent.
Intraregional Migration. Commuting patterns indicate people’s willingness to live in New York City
versus living in another part of the region. Table 8 shows the number of adults who work in New York
City by whether they are commuters or city residents. On average 21.6 percent of workers commute
to New York City, but the share varies considerably by wage income. In general, higher-wage workers
are more likely to commute than are lower wage workers; 50.6 percent of workers earning $250,000
- $400,000 were commuters, while only 12.2 percent of workers earning less than $50,000 were
commuters. In other words, people with incomes above $50,000 are about two to four times more
likely to commute than people with incomes below $50,000.
These large differences in residential choice cannot be attributed fully to differences in the individuals’
demographic characteristics other than income. Appendix C presents the results of a logistic
regression of commuting. After adjusting for age, marital status, presence of children in the home,
education, and racial and ethnic characteristics, individuals with higher wage income are more likely
to be commuters to New York City than people with similar characteristics but lower wage income.
As with the outmigration regression, the results are presented in terms of odds ratios. The odds ratios
for the higher income groups range from about 2.5 to almost 4, suggesting that after adjusting for
demographic and other differences, higher income individuals are about 2.5 to 4 times more likely to
commute as the lowest income group.
Income ($000)
Up to $100 3.6% 3.8% 5.8% 4.7%
$100-400 4.0% 1.6% 3.1% 3.0%
$400+ 3.5% 1.1% 2.4% 3.1%
Total 3.6% 3.5% 5.3% 4.5%
N
ew
York City
New York
C
ity suburbs
Connecticut
(Fairfield County)
New Jersey
c
ommuting counties
Table 7: Regional Outmigration as a Percent of Residents by County of Origin,
2007-2011
Note: New York City suburbs are Nassau, Suolk, Westchester and Rockland counes. New Jersey commung
counes are Bergen, Essex, Hudson, Middlesex and Monmouth counes.
Source: Author's analysis of U.S. Census Bureau, American Community Survey, 2007-2011 Five-Year Public Use
Microdata.
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
11
This analysis indicates that higher income individuals are already more likely to opt for suburban
residences than lower income individuals. But it does not necessarily mean that they are even more
likely to do so if tax rates rise. However, it does suggest the likelihood of becoming a commuter will rise
if an accumulation of factors influencing the choice – including taxes – weighs in favor of living outside
the city.
Up to $50 305.3 2,194.8 2,500.1 12.2%
$50-75 183.3 547.3 730.6 25.1
$75-100 145.3 260.0 405.3 35.8
$100-250 224.9 282.4 507.3 44.3
$250-400 24.3 23.8 48.0 50.6
Above $400 38.6 41.9 80.5 48.0
Total 921.7 3,350.
1 4,271.8 21.6%
Table 8: New York City Workers by Commuter Status and Wage Level, 2007-2011
Number of Workers (in thousands)
Source: Author's analysis of U.S. Census Bureau, American Community Survey, 2007-2011 Five-Year Public Use
Microdata.
Wages ($000) Commuters Residents Total
Commuters
as a percent
o
f total
Citizens Budget Commission
12
NEW YORK CITY PERSONAL INCOME TAX POLICY
When assessing different taxes, analysts and policymakers often seek to strike a balance between
goals of equity and adherence to a “benefit” principle of taxation. Concerns for equity favor taxes that
are progressive, meaning higher income households pay a larger share of their income in taxes than do
lower income households. The personal income tax usually scores high on the equity criterion, because
it is largely based on ability to pay and policymakers can control progressivity well by adjusting tax
brackets and other characteristics of the tax. This is especially true for national tax policy, but at the
state and local level varying reliance on income taxes can create competitive disadvantages for states
or cites that depend too heavily on the income tax.
The benefit principle favors taxes that are distributed among residents (and businesses) in proportion to
their consumption of services provided by the government; that is, people should pay in relation to the
extent they receive benefits. The property tax is often seen as scoring well on this criterion, especially
for local governments, because household reliance on core local government services (police, fire, and
sanitation) correlates with the size and value of the property they own or occupy. However, because it
is in many respects a tax on housing, the property tax is also regressive and scores poorly in terms of
equity. Thus, choices between the taxes are a difficult balancing act. This section considers the impact
on progressivity and regional competitiveness of two changes to the New York City personal income
tax. The next section considers New York City’s competitive position with respect to real estate taxes,
particularly commercial real estate taxes. The two income tax policy alternatives are: (1) a 10 percent
across the board surcharge, and (2) a 0.75 percent increase in the top tax rate, from 3.876 percent to
4.626 percent. These options are policies that are near the bounds of past tax increases. New York
City imposed a 14 percent surcharge several times in the past; a 10 percent surcharge is well within
the bounds of historical experience. It would raise more than $800 million annually at current income
levels. The second option, increasing the top rate to 4.626 percent, would exceed the previous highest
top rate in New York City of 4.464 percent in 1998. However, that top rate began at income of $108,000
while this option would take effect at income of $500,000 and would apply to less income. This option
likely would raise more than $750 million annually. It is reasonably consistent with past experience,
similar in revenue magnitude to the surcharge, and a round number (0.75 percent increase).
The analysis of the options has two elements. First, it identifies the impact on the combined state and
local tax rate paid by New York City residents at different income levels. The analysis uses 19 different
income levels based on the 10 income categories used in New York State Department of Taxation
and Finance reports and expanded to include more income ranges at the upper level.
21
The income
levels used are based on the midpoint of each reported or interpolated income range, rounded to a
multiple of $1,000; the 19 hypothetical taxpayers are married taxpayers with incomes ranging from
approximately $23,000 to $1.9 million.
The second element of the analysis is a comparison of the state and local tax rates under the two options
to current state and local income tax rates in New York City, in areas of New York State outside New
York City, in New Jersey and in Connecticut. In each case the state and local income tax rate is “net”
income tax taking into account the benefit of deductibility of state and local income taxes against the
federal income tax, for those taxpayers who itemize deductions for their federal taxes. This deduction
lowers federal tax liability, effectively offsetting some of the difference between the City income tax
and income tax in other locations and softening the impact of a local income tax increase. (See Appendix
D for a more detailed description of the method used.)
Table 9 summarizes the results of the analysis. As expected, in comparison to current New York City
rates, the surcharge modestly increases the rate at all income levels. The increase is between one- and
two- tenths of a percentage point across the board. The other option increases the rate only at the
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
13
three highest levels, by between one-tenth and three-tenths of a percentage point.
The impact of the options on competitiveness with other parts of the region is more subtle. Income
tax rates in New York City currently are much higher than in Connecticut, New Jersey, or the rest of
New York State. The rates in New York City at the five highest levels are between 6.2 percent and 9.5
percent; in New Jersey the range at these levels is from 4.6 percent to 5.4 percent; in Connecticut and
other parts of New York from 4.0 to 6.1 percent. Given these large differences under current policy,
the increase in rates in New York City under the two options has only a modest adverse impact on the
differential between New York City and the other areas.
22
Figure 2 shows the difference in tax rates under the alternative policies. Values above the zero
horizontal line indicate state and local income taxes that are higher than taxes under the current New
York City tax regime. Under the two tax increase options, taxes are higher than under the current tax.
Values below the horizontal line indicate that income taxes under an alternative regime are lower than
current income taxes in New York City. This is the case for all hypothetical taxpayers for New York
outside of New York City, Connecticut, and New Jersey. The differences in tax rates are particularly
large for low- and middle- income taxpayers, but they narrow somewhat for taxpayers with more than
$1 million of income.
Figure 3 shows the tax differentials in actual dollar terms rather than as tax rates. These dollar figures
$23,000 2.0% 2.0% 2.1% 1.0% - % 1.0%
$28,000 2.9 2.9 3.0 1.6 0.1 1.1
$33,000 3.7 3.7 3.8 2.1 0.4 1.2
$38,000 4.1 4.1 4.3 2.4 0.7 1.3
$42,000 4.6
4.6 4.8 2.7 1.1 1.3
$47,000 5.1 5.1 5.3 3.0 1.4 1.4
$52,000 5.5 5.5 5.7 3.3 2.2 1.4
$57,000 5.8 5.8 6.1 3.5 2.8 1.5
$63,000 6.2 6.2
6.4 3.8 3.3 1.5
$70,000 6.6 6.6 6.8 4.0 3.9 1.6
$87,000 6.6 6.6 6.8 4.2 3.9 1.9
$121,000 6.0 6.0 6.2 3.7 3.7 2.1
$171,000 6.1 6.1
6.3 3.9 3.9 2.7
$230,000 7.6 7.6 7.9 4.5 4.3 3.2
$290,000 8.9 8.9 9.2 5.7 5.5 4.7
$490,000 9.5 9.5 9.8 6.1 6.1 5.4
$690,000 8.7 8.8 9.0
5.2 5.5 5.2
$1,300,000 6.2 6.5 6.4 4.0 4.0 4.6
$1,900,000 6.3 6.6 6.5 4.0 4.0 4.8
Source: Author's analysis of hypothecal married-ling-joint taxpayers, as described in text and Appendix D.
Note: Net of savings from deducbility a
gainst federal income tax.
New JerseyConnecticut
New York
C
ity suburbs
10%
s
urcharge
0.75% top
r
ate increase
Current
p
olicy
Federal adjusted gross
i
ncome (rounded)
Table 9: State and Local Income Taxes as a Percent of Federal Adjusted Gross Income,
by Area and Policy Option
New York City
Citizens Budget Commission
14
make clear the impact of the tax policy changes relative to the already existing differences among
jurisdictions. For example, the 10 percent surcharge would raise taxes on a married couple earning
approximately $1.9 million by just under $5,000; the couple already pays approximately $28,000 more
in New York City under the current regime than they would in New Jersey
-5
-4
-3
-2
-1
+0
+1
$0 $500 $1,000 $1,500 $2,000
Tax after federal deductibility as % of federal AGI: alternative
regime minus current NYC tax
Note: Net eecve tax rate takes into account deducbility of state and local income taxes against federal tax.
Source: Author's calculaons for hypothecal married taxpayers constructed using data from NYS Department of
Taxaon and Finance.
Federal adjusted gross
income, $ thousands
Figure 2: Difference in Net Effective Income Tax Rates,
Current New York City Policy vs. Other Policy Options
NYC 10% surcharge NYC 0.75% top rate increase
NYS outside NYC Connecticut
New Jersey
($50)
($40)
($30)
($20)
($10)
$0
$10
$0 $500 $1,000 $1,500 $2,000
Alternative regime minus current NYC tax
($ thousands)
Note: Net tax calculaon takes into account deducbility of state and local income taxes against federal tax.
Source: Author's calculaons for hypothecal married taxpayers constructed using data from NYS Department
of Taxaon and Finance.
Federal adjusted gross income, $ thousands
Figure 3: Difference in Net Income Tax Liability,
Current New York City Income Tax vs. Other Policy Options
NYC 10% surcharge NYC 0.75% top rate increase NYS outside NYC
Connecticut New Jersey
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
15
How large would the adverse impacts on the competitiveness of New York City be if either of the
options was pursued? The fact that the increase in tax differentials among jurisdictions is small
relative to already existing differentials, combined with the modest negative impacts found in studies
of state income tax rate changes, might suggest the impacts would not be great. But this is a highly
speculative inference. The situation in New York City is unique. The already high rates, together with
the relatively easy opportunities for intraregional migration (already used by many high earners), make
any predictions about likely outmigration highly uncertain.
Citizens Budget Commission
16
NEW YORK CITY PROPERTY TAX POLICY
This section examines New York City’s current property tax policy and its effects on the competitiveness
of the city for commercial activity. The available comparative data indicate New York City imposes a
property tax on commercial property that is much higher than in most competitive areas, and that
New York City also creates differential rates between commercial and other types of property that are
much greater than in other areas. The policy implication is that these conditions should be considered
in any initiatives to raise more revenue from the property tax.
The analysis in this section relies primarily on annual data published jointly by the Lincoln Institute
of Land Policy and the Minnesota Center on Fiscal Excellence. Their reports compute effective tax
rates for different kinds of properties for the largest city in each state and for the largest 50 cities
in the nation, as well as for selected suburban and rural locations. The analysis takes into account all
property taxes imposed on a parcel of property in a given location, such as county taxes, school taxes,
city taxes or taxes imposed by villages and towns, and special district taxes. It does not generally reflect
special-purpose exemptions or other programs that are available to some properties but not to others.
In the case of New York City it does adjust for the average impact of transitional assessed values and
exemptions.
23
The published data do not include information for key jurisdictions within the New York region that
compete with New York City notably Mineola and White Plains in New York, Hoboken and Jersey City
in New Jersey, and Stamford, Connecticut. The author has applied the Lincoln Institute methodology
to these locations using data from 2012.
The data for New York City include only the property tax, and do not include the commercial rent tax.
New York City is one of only two jurisdictions in the United States that impose a tax on commercial rent.
(The other is the state of Florida.) The tax was enacted in 1963 when New York City was approaching
a state constitutional limit on the property tax; it was a means to capture some of the growth in real
estate values without exceeding the constitutional cap.
24
The current tax is imposed on commercial
rents on properties in Manhattan south of 96
th
Street. The effective rate is 3.9 percent of gross rent
for properties with gross rent of more than $300,000 annually; the effective rate phases up from zero
to 3.9 percent for properties with gross rent between $250,000 and $300,000. The property tax
equivalent of the commercial rent tax depends on the relationship of rent to property value, which
varies with market conditions. Applying assumptions about market values and rents for Manhattan
office properties that were used by the New York City Department of Finance in early 2013, the
commercial rent tax likely was about 0.7 to 0.9 percent of market value, or about 15 to 20 percent of
the property tax.
25
(Based on market conditions during the 2000’s, this would have ranged from about
10 percent to 25 percent.
26
) Put differently, for properties in Manhattan subject to the commercial
rent tax, the effective tax likely was 15 to 20 percent higher than shown in the tables below.
A Comparative View of Commercial Property Taxes
Table 10 shows the property tax on a $25 million commercial property in 2012 in the 15 largest cities
in the nation by population, and in selected jurisdictions in the New York region. The New York City
commercial property tax (not reflecting the commercial rent tax) was second highest among large
cities, behind Chicago. New York’s commercial property tax was 10 percent higher than third-highest
Philadelphia, 35 percent higher than Houston, and 154 percent higher than Los Angeles. It was 51
percent higher than the average for the other 14 of the 15 largest cities an annual difference of
$327,000 for a $25 million property.
Closer to home, New York was 30 percent higher than the average for the five locations within the
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
17
Jurisdiction
15 largest cities in the U.S.:
Chicago $ 1,166 3.89% (17.3%)
New York City 964 3.21
Philadelphia 876 2.92 10.0%
Dallas 792 2.64 21.6%
San Antonio 761 2.54 26.7%
Houston 717 2.39 34.5%
Austin 693 2.31 39.2%
Phoenix 687 2.29
40.2%
Columbus 687 2.29 40.3%
Indianapolis 571 1.90 68.9%
Jacksonville 526 1.75 83.2%
San Jose 382 1.27 152.2%
Los Angeles 380 1.27 153.8%
San Francisco 351 1.17 174.9%
San Diego 333 1.11 188.9%
Average of largest 15
cities,
excluding NYC
$ 637 2.12% 51.3%
Nearby jurisdictions:
Mineola $ 1,450 4.83% (33.5%)
New York City 964 3.21
White Plains 813 2.71 18.6%
Jersey City 563 1.88 71.2%
Stamford 505 1.68 90.9%
Hoboken 368 1.23 161.8%
Average of nearby jurisdictions,
excluding NYC $ 740 2.47% 3
0.3%
T
ax RateTax
New York City percent
above (below)
other jurisdiction
Table 10: Property Tax on $25 Million Commercial Property,
Selected Locations, 2012
(dollars in thousands)
Source: Minnesota Center for Fiscal Excellence and Lincoln Instute for Land Policy, 50-State Property Tax
Comparison Study , 2012, and author's analysis.
Notes: Esmates for Mineola, White Plains, Jersey City, Stamford, and Hoboken developed by the author using
methodology of the Minnesota/Linco
ln Instute study.
Citizens Budget Commission
18
region. New York City’s tax is reported as lower than in Mineola, but that is a questionable finding,
because Nassau County appears to have an extraordinarily variable and contentious property tax
system. Many observers believe that the relationship between true market value and the value carried
on the Nassau County assessment roll is inconsistent at best.
27
At the other extreme, a $25 million
commercial property in Hoboken is subject to property tax of $368,000, about $596,000 less, annually,
than in New York City.
It may be surprising to readers to see Chicago higher than New York City in 2012. That is a recent
phenomenon. Table 11 shows the tax rates on commercial property for each year from 2005 through
2012. In every year between 2005 and 2011, the New York tax rate was higher than the Chicago rate.
The recent increase in Chicago reflects, in part, increases in the median level of assessment.
28
Disparities between Commercial and Small Residential Property
One reason the commercial property tax is so high in New York City is because taxes on small residential
properties (know as Class 1 in New York City) are so low, a longstanding policy in New York. Table 12
shows the effective tax rate on commercial and homeowner properties in New York City, the City’s
ranking among the 50 large cities included in the Lincoln Institute and Minnesota Center analysis,
and the average for large cities, for available years from 1995 through 2012. In a typical year New
York City’s commercial property tax is 50 percent or more above the average for large cities, while the
homeowner property tax generally is 50 percent or more below the average.
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Chicago 3.11% 2.80% 2.41% 2.09% 2.03% 1.79% 2.04% 3.89%
New York City 3.87 3.64 3.29 2.96 3.24 3.31 3.20 3.21
Philadelphia 2.90 3.16 3.04 2.98 3.43 3.40 2.05 2.92
Dallas 2.83 2.72 2.41 2.31 2.38 2.55 2.62
2.64
San Antonio 2.67 2.81 2.41 2.47 2.58 2.49 2.48 2.54
Houston 2.79 2.40 1.99 2.01 2.39 2.34 2.34 2.39
Austin 2.56 2.31 2.10 2.06 2.13 2.27 2.27 2.31
Phoenix 3.34 3.05
3.05 2.35 2.02 2.09 2.10 2.29
Columbus 1.52 1.74 1.89 1.67 1.83 1.96 1.83 2.29
Indianapolis 2.47 2.60 3.28 na 2.62 1.94 3.04 1.90
Jacksonville 1.79 1.71 1.73 1.49 1.58
1.67 1.72 1.75
San Jose 1.16 1.19 1.19 1.22 1.25 1.27 1.29 1.27
Los Angeles 1.20 1.18 1.18 1.19 1.22 1.27 1.25 1.27
San Francisco 1.14 1.14 1.14 1.16 1.16 1.16 1.17
1.17
San Diego 1.11 1.10 1.10 1.08 1.10 1.10 1.11 1.11
Note: Commercial property eecve tax rates are for the highest-value property group examined; year generally is the year of
the tax levy.
Source: Minnesota Center for Fiscal Excellence and Lincoln Instute for Land Policy, 50-State Property Tax Comparison Study ,
various years.
Table 11: Tax Rates on Large Commercial Property, Selected Cities, 2005-2012
(percent of market value)
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
19
Year
2005 3.87% 1 2.06% 88.0%
2006 3.64 2 2.03 79.4%
2007 3.29 2 1.94 69.4%
2008 2.96 3 1.83 62.2%
2009 3.24 3 1.86 73.7%
2010 3.31 3 1.87 76.5%
2011 3.20 3 1.97 62.8%
2012 3.21 4 2.06 55.8%
Table 12: Property Tax Rates in New York City and Other
Large Cities, by Type of Property, 2005-2012
(percent of market value)
Commercial property
Tax Rate Rank 50 largest cities (below) the average
New York City Average tax rate, NYC percent above
0.59% 46 1.50% (60.5%)
0.54 46 1.44 (62.2%)
0.38 49 1.39 (72.8%)
0.33 49 1.34 (75.4%)
0.59 45 1.38 (57.4%)
0.65 44 1.41 (54.2%)
0.62 47 1.48 (58.1%)
0.63 47 1.51 (58.1%)
Homestead property
RankTax Rate 50 largest cities
NYC percent above
(below) the average
New York City Average tax rate,
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
6.5 1 1.4
6.7 1 1.4
8.7 1 1.4
9.0 1 1.4
5.5 1 1.3
5.1 1 1.3
5.2 1 1.3
5.1 1 1.4
Ratio of Commercial Rate
to Homestead Rate
Ratio Rank largest cities
Average, 50 New York City
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
Note: Commercial and homestead property eecve tax rates are for the highest-value
property group examined; year generally is the year of the tax levy.
Source: Minnesota Center for Fiscal Excellence and Lincoln Instute for Land Policy, 50-
State Property Tax Comparison Study , various years.
Citizens Budget Commission
20
The relationship between commercial and homeowner property tax rates is notably different in New
York City than in other large cities: in a typical year the tax rate on commercial property is 5-6 times
as great as the tax rate on homeowner property. While other large cities also tend to tax commercial
property more heavily than homeowner property, the difference is not as extreme. Table 12 shows that
in most years the rate for commercial property in the average large city is about 40 percent higher than
the effective rate for homeowner property, rather than 5-6 times as great as it is in New York City. New
York City has the highest ratio of commercial property tax rate to homestead tax rate of any large city
in the country, and has held this distinction each year from 2005 through 2012.
The extraordinary extent to which New York City taxes commercial property more than homestead
property is evident in Table 13. It identifies the ten cities, out of the top 50 by population, with the
highest ratio of commercial tax rate to homestead tax rate. New York’s ratio is 9 percent higher than
second-ranking Boston’s. After that the disparity widens dramatically: New York is 39 percent higher
than third-ranked Colorado Springs and 140 percent higher than tenth ranked Kansas City.
What are the implications of the distinctive way in which New York City taxes commercial property?
A 10 percent increase in the tax on commercial property (Class 4) would be roughly comparable in
to the 10 percent surcharge on the personal income tax examined earlier. If the City were to adopt
such an increase it would exacerbate the already-large differences in New York City commercial
property taxes compared to other large cities and to nearby jurisdictions: New York’s commercial
property tax would be 188 percent higher than in Hoboken, 110 percent higher than in Stamford, and
88 percent higher than in Jersey City again, without considering the impact of the commercial rent
tax, which does not have counterparts in these other locations. Estimating the economic impact of a
commercial property tax increase is not practical, but such a change would be tantamount to taking the
price of a luxury good (a New York City location) that already is substantially more expensive than its
competitors and increasing it further, rather than increasing taxes that are not as far out of line with
those of competitors.
New York City 3.21% 0.63% 5.1
Boston 2.85 0.61 4.7 9.3%
Colorado Springs 1.72 0.47 3.7 38.8%
Denver 2.02 0.57 3.6 43.1%
Washington 2.06 0.64 3.2 57.8%
Mesa 1.92 0.68 2.8
79.6%
Phoenix 2.29 0.86 2.7 89.7%
Tucson 2.48 0.97 2.6 97.8%
Chicago 3.89 1.64 2.4 114.7%
Kansas City 2.92 1.38 2.1 140.3%
Note: Commercial and homestead property eecve tax rates are for the highest-value property group examined; year
generally is the year of the tax levy.
Source: Minnesota Center for Fiscal Excellence and Lincoln Instute for Land Policy, 50-State Property Tax Comparison
Study , 2012.
Commercial
p
roperty
Homestead
p
roperty
Commercial:
Homestead Ratio
NYC percent
a
bove other city
Tax rate
(as a percent of market value)
Table 13: Tax Rates on Commercial Property Relative to Homestead Property,
Selected Cities, 2012
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
21
CONCLUSION
New York City’s tax burden is far greater than that in other large cities. Higher taxes can, in concept,
cause people to flee a high-tax jurisdiction, potentially reducing the tax base. Empirical research on
migration suggests that people move, or choose not to move, primarily for non-tax reasons such as
to seek employment in better labor markets, to go to less-expensive housing markets, and to take
advantage of opportunities that college degrees provide. Analysis of recent relevant data, however,
suggests that high-income New Yorkers are more likely to outmigrate than are high-income individuals
in neighboring or metropolitan counties in New York, Connecticut, and New Jersey. Similar analysis
suggests that individuals who work in New York City are more likely to be commuters if their wages
are high.
Some people do move for tax reasons. The empirical research on “millionaire taxes” suggests that their
impact on migration has been relatively small. Based on prior research, there is likely to be some “tax
flight” migration from New York City to other locations if the City enacts new increases, but it is not
practical to quantify this impact with any confidence because tax differentials between New York City
and its neighbors already are great and intraregional migration is a very real possibiIty. It is important
to remember that New York City’s income tax already is an outlier. The combined city and state tax
rate is far higher than in neighboring or competitor states, and the personal income tax accounts
for three quarters of the difference between tax burdens in New York City and in other large cities.
Furthermore, the research on tax migration based on New Jersey data examined top marginal rates
that are well below those currently in effect in New York City when combined state and city rates are
taken into account. Thus, the experience in New York City may be different from that in New Jersey.
Although the property tax in New York City, on average, contributes relatively little to the City’s outlier
status, that fact alone is deceptive. The tax on homeowner properties is very low compared with other
large cities – typically ranking the City at or near 50 in an annual study of property tax rates in 50 large
cities. By contrast, the commercial property tax rate is about 5-6 times the homeowner tax rate in
most years, and New York City’s commercial property tax rate is much higher than in most other large
cities and much higher than in potential competitors in the region. In 2012 the commercial rate was
47 percent higher than the average of the other 14 largest cities in the nation and 42 percent higher
than the average for Hoboken, Jersey City, Mineola, Stamford, and White Plains. It was 162 percent
higher than in Hoboken – a difference of $596,000 annually on a property worth $25 million. Further
increases in the commercial property tax would make New York City even more of an outlier.
Policymakers considering raising the personal income tax or the commercial property tax need to be
aware that both taxes are already significantly higher than in other large cities. They are dealing with
uncertainty related to these distinct competitive circumstances and would be well advised to examine
options where New York City is not as far out of line with other cities.
Citizens Budget Commission
22
APPENDIX A
Study
Policy
or trend
examined
Data & methods Authors’ conclusions Comments
Young, Varner,
& Massey
2008; Policy
Research
Institute for
the Region,
Princeton
University
Outmigration
from NJ
2004+ 8.97%
tax rate on
taxable income
above $500k
(for HMH’s –
half-millionaire
households).
Census Bureau annual summary
data by state, for description of
longer-term migration trends
without regard to income levels.
Census ACS person-level
microdata for 2000-2006
combined. Logistic models of
outmigration and inmigration
based on demographic
characteristics.
NJ annual summary of tax data,
with counts of HMHs and of
numbers of in- and outmigrating
HMHs (based on part-year filings),
2000-2007.
Outmigration is driven by low-
income individuals, especially
unemployed and not in labor
force. Elderly and individuals
with children much less likely to
move than others. Outmigration
reflects NJ’s high cost of living.
Number of HMH outmigrants
increased in 2004+, but rate
of outmigration increased only
very slightly. Inmigration slowed
slightly. NJ loses at most ~350
HMHs per year due to the 2004
tax increase, out of 44,000 (0.8%
of HMHs). About $38m annual
loss on average.
CA, MA, NY outmigration
similarly largely driven by low-
income individuals. Tax rates,
climate, and crime do not appear
to explain their outmigration.
In YVM analysis, impacts do
not grow with time.
Implicitly assumes that
when people leave, they
take their jobs and income
with them – the money is
gone.
Authors report their ACS
income data are top-coded
at $300k. However, more-
current ACS data are more
promising: 2007-2011 data
for NY has wages topcoded
at $507k and other income
also has high topcoding.
Highest income in the data
is around $1.3 million.
Cohen, Lai, &
Steindel, 2011,
New Jersey
Dept. of the
Treasury
Interstate
differences in
tax rates.
Hypothetical
1% across-
the-board rate
increase.
Combined
impact of all
changes since
2003: 2004+
HMH increase,
temporary
rate increases,
bracket creep.
IRS annual state-level data on
state-to-state migration: total
number of migrants and their
income, by year, based on tax filing,
1992-2008.
Description of trends.
OLS linear and log-linear models
of state-to-state outmigration
rates, based on differences in tax
rates, unemployment, and housing
prices, and on distances between
states.
When taxes, housing prices, or
unemployment are relatively
higher in the home state,
outmigration is greater.
Clear but modest effects of
tax differentials on interstate
migration.
1% across the board increase
would raise $2.5b revenue, but
lose 4,200 taxpayers and $29m
revenue (1.2% of the increase)
to outmigration.
Cumulative changes from 2003
to 2009 lowered number of
taxpayers by 20,000, with loss of
over $125m in state tax revenue,
partially offsetting increases
from tax changes.
State-level summary data
(as opposed to microdata)
limit the inferences that
can be drawn. Cannot
confidently address HMH
tax questions with these
data.
Assumes outmigration
response to a tax increase
persists forever.
Implicitly assumes that
when people leave, they
take their jobs with them –
the money is gone.
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
23
Study
Policy
or trend
examined
Data & methods Authors’ conclusions Comments
Young &
Varner 2011,
National Tax
Journal
NJ 2004+
8.97% tax rate
on taxable
income above
$500k (for
HMH’s – half-
millionaire
households).
Time-series cross-section
taxpayer-level data on ALL NJ-
1040 tax returns 2000-2007
(without individual linkage
identifier).
Data included outmigrants coded
+1, inmigrants coded -1, and
stayers coded 0.
Difference-in-differences
model - compares inmigration,
outmigration, and non-moving
behavior pre- and post- tax
change, for HMHs and for $200-
500k income households used as
control. Allows estimates of the
“treatment effect” (the effect of
higher 2004+ tax rates).
HMH outmigration increased
after tax was put into effect,
but so did outmigration of
unaffected near-HMHs.
NJ HMH outmigration in a
typical year is about 459 HMHs,
or 1.2% of all HMHs. 1% point
increase in effective tax rate
leads to ~ 0.04% decrease in #
of HMHs.
Groups that are more likely
than average millionaires to
outmigrate in response to tax
increase: those reliant solely on
investment income; those over
age 65; extremely high income
business owners. These groups
are a very small subset of HMHs
and don’t affect totals much.
“Static” estimate was that the
tax increase raised ~$900m.
Model suggests about 70 HMHs
outmigrated because of the tax.
IF they take their jobs/income
with them, revenue loss of
~$16m (1.8% of the increase);
mostly attributable to HMHs
with income above $3m.
Authors also examined
multinomial logit models;
did not change fundamental
conclusions (per
correspondence).
Method forces explanatory
variables to have the same
influence in both directions
– e.g., if elderly people are
more likely to migrate out of
NJ, they also are more likely
to migrate into NJ.
Treats outmigration as one-
time behavioral change in
response to policy change,
rather than occurring year
after year after year. Tax-
averse people leave once,
rather than continually year
after year.
Cohen, Lai, &
Steindel, Feb.
2012, State Tax
Notes
Essentially
same as 2011
report
Same as 2011 report; annual
IRS state-level state-to-state
migration data, updated to 2010.
Essentially same as 2011 report:
“average marginal tax rates have
a small but significant effect on
migration.” Impact of tax changes
from 2004-2009 reduced $1
billion annual static revenue gain
by about $115m (11%).
Implicitly assumes that
when people leave, they
take their jobs with them –
the money is gone.
Cannot distinguish
millionaires.
Assumes outmigration
response to a tax increase
persists forever – people
keep leaving at higher rates,
year after year after year.
Varner &
Young 2012
California’s
Mental Health
Services Tax
(MHST) –
increased top
rate by 1%
for taxable
income above
$1 million, in
2005+.
Longitudinal tax return data for
taxpayers in California who had
adjusted gross income of $500k
or more in any year during 1992-
2009. Panel data with individuals
linked over time.
Difference-in-differences
regression. Control group is those
earning $500k-$1m.
Migration counts at most for
1.2% of annual changes in
millionaire population.
Neither inmigration nor
outmigration shows a tax-flight
effect from the MHST.
Panel nature of data (with
individuals linked over
time) allows improved
identification of migrants,
compared with earlier
studies.
Most million-dollar earners
are having an unusually
good year, and tax may be
transitory.
Citizens Budget Commission
24
Study
Policy
or trend
examined
Data & methods Authors’ conclusions Comments
Cohen, Lai,
& Steindel,
Sep. 2013,
unpublished
draft
NJ 2004+
8.97% tax rate
on taxable
income above
$500k (for
HMH’s – half-
millionaire
households).
Time-series cross-section
taxpayer-level data on ALL NJ-
1040 tax returns 2000-2007
(without individual linkage
identifier).
Replication of Young &
Varner 2011. Also, estimated
outmigration separately (YV
had estimated inmigration and
outmigration together).
Replicated the YV 2011
conclusions with minor
differences.
Separate outmigration
equation suggested that
annual outmigration of HMHs
increased by about 80.
Report argues that near-
millionaires could be affected,
also, out of concern that they
could be HMHs in the future.
Draft provided to me by
study’s authors.
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
25
APPENDIX B
Income-related characteristics
Some self-employment income 1.5874 1.4844 1.6959 INCREASES odds of outmigration
Some retirement income 1.0235 0.9554 1.0957
No wage income 0.4256 0.4070 0.4451 LOWERS odds of outmigration
Income above $400,000 1.9792 1.4559 2.6664 INCREASES odds of outmigration
Income above $400,000 & resided in
NYC previous year 2.2937 1.6811 3.1386 INCREASES odds of outmigration
Income above $400,000 & age 65+ 1.2441 0.5836 2.3259
Resided in NYC previous year 0.9572 0.9277 0.9877 LOWERS odds of outmigration
Resided in NYC previous year & age 65+ 0.9674 0.8752 1.0686
Age group:
18-24 0.5044 0.4736 0.5373 LOWERS odds of outmigration
25-4
4 0.4539 0.4255 0.4843 LOWERS odds of outmigration
45-64 0.1397 0.1300 0.1501 LOWERS odds of outmigration
65+ 0.0807 0.0734 0.0887 LOWERS odds of outmigration
Labor force status, compared to working
Unemployed 2.1189 2.0017 2.2418 INCREASES odds of outmigration
Not in labor force 3.5371 3.3776 3.7036 INCREA
SES odds of outmigration
Marital status, compared to single
Married 0.8779 0.8435 0.9138 LOWERS odds of outmigration
Widowed, divorced, or separated 1.4205 1.3488 1.4958 INCREASES odds of outmigration
Person's children are present in the household 0.4521 0.4275 0.4778 LOWERS odds of outmigration
Education, compared to no high school diploma
HS Gra
duate 1.1999 1.1375 1.2661 INCREASES odds of outmigration
Some college 1.4565 1.3794 1.5383 INCREASES odds of outmigration
Associate's degree 1.1659 1.0768 1.2616 INCREASES odds of outmigration
Bachelor's degree 1.7904 1.6912 1.8959 INCREASES odds of outmigration
Master's degree 1.9279 1.8025 2.0621 INCREASE
S odds of outmigration
Professional degree or doctorate 2.7221 2.5089 2.9519 INCREASES odds of outmigration
Male 1.0609 1.0283 1.0945 INCREASES odds of outmigration
Hispanic 0.9102 0.8681 0.9539 LOWERS odds of outmigration
Race, compared to white
Black 1.0414 1.0000 1.0842
Another race, alone 0.8455 0.7871 0.9077
LOWERS odds of outmigration
Multiple races 1.2492 1.1403 1.3658 INCREASES odds of outmigration
Other 0.9104 0.8676 0.9549 LOWERS odds of outmigration
# of individuals (observations) 547,678
McFadden pseudo r-squared= 0.0888
Characteristics Affecting Outmigration: Logistic Regression Results
Data: U.S. Census Bureau, American Community Survey, 2007-2011 Five-Year Public Use Microdata, residents of and outmigrants from: New York City, Nassau, Rockland, Suolk, and
Westchester Counes in New York; Bergen, Essex, Hudson, Middlesex, and Monmouth Counes in New Jersey; and Faireld County in Conneccut.
Odds ratio
Lower bound
(
2.5%)
Upper bound
(
97.5%)
95% confidence interval for
o
dds ratio
Comment
Citizens Budget Commission
26
APPENDIX C
Income-related characteristics
Wages in $ thousands
$50-100 2.4983 2.3183 2.6923 INCREASES odds of commuting
$100-250 3.6432 3.3698 3.9388 INCREASES odds of commuting
$250-400 3.8363 3.3969 4.3325 INCREASES odds of commuting
Greater than $400 3.0625 2.7640 3.3932 INCREASES odds of commuting
Age group and family situation
25-44 0.7849 0
.7310 0.8427 LOWERS odds of commuting
45-64 1.0819 1.0039 1.1660 INCREASES odds of commuting
65+ 1.0015 0.8745 1.1468
Married, age 24-44 2.3137 1.8038 2.9677 INCREASES odds of commuting
Married, age 45-64 2.0003 1.5581 2.5681 INCREASES odds of commuting
Married, age 65+ 1.8276 1.3748 2.4294 I
NCREASES odds of commuting
Children present in the home 1.2472 1.1875 1.3099 INCREASES odds of commuting
Education, compared to no high school diploma
HS Graduate 1.8310 1.6986 1.9737 INCREASES odds of commuting
Some college 2.3810 2.2073 2.5683 INCREASES odds of commuting
Associate's degree 2.5069 2.3002 2.7321 INCREASES odds
of commuting
Bachelor's degree 2.4241 2.2511 2.6105 INCREASES odds of commuting
Master's degree 2.3386 2.1626 2.5290 INCREASES odds of commuting
Professional degree or doctorate 1.8059 1.6559 1.9694 INCREASES odds of commuting
Male 1.4736 1.4239 1.5250 INCREASES odds of commuting
Hispanic 0.7573 0.7206 0.7959
LOWERS odds of commuting
Race, compared to white
Black 0.5462 0.5222 0.5714 LOWERS odds of commuting
Another race, alone 0.5406 0.5001 0.5843 LOWERS odds of commuting
Multiple races 0.7397 0.6629 0.8253 LOWERS odds of commuting
Other 0.6640 0.6366 0.6926 LOWERS odds of commuting
# of individuals (observations) 174,871
Data: U.S. Census Bureau, American Community Survey, 2007-2011 Five-Year Public Use Microdata, adult (18+) workers in New York City.
Odds ratio
Lower bound
(
2.5%)
Upper bound
(
97.5%)
95% confidence interval for
o
dds ratio
Comment
Characteristics Affecting Commuting to New York City: Logistic Regression Results
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
27
APPENDIX D
Methodology for hypothetical taxpayers model
I analyzed the potential impact of alternative tax regimes by building a database of hypothetical
taxpayers for whom I could calculate income tax under alternative tax regimes. The database includes
income and deduction components for single and married New York state taxpayers in different income
ranges in 2010, constructed from income-range averages using data in the state’s annual analysis
of personal income tax returns.
35
Because the state uses broad income ranges for upper-income
taxpayers, I constructed 10 additional hypothetical taxpayers by interpolating values from adjacent
income ranges. This analysis focuses on 19 hypothetical taxpayers, married taxpayers with incomes
ranging from approximately $23,000 to $1.9 million. I also computed results for single taxpayers; they
do not alter any important conclusions so they are not reported here.
The database is based on averages for New York State taxpayers rather than for New York City
taxpayers because the state publishes detailed components of income and deductions for the entire
state, and only limited details for substate areas.
36
The most important way in which average state
taxpayers in a given income range are likely to differ from average city taxpayers in the same income
range is in the deduction for state and local taxes, where at any given level taxes are higher in the city.
However, I discard the reported income tax deduction and calculate the income tax deduction for each
taxpayer based on the law under examination so the income tax deduction should not be an issue. I
do not attempt to recalculate the property taxes. Because property taxes on residences are lower in
New York City than in much of the state, this may overstate deductions somewhat in any given income
range. Because the taxpayers are average they cannot be used to illustrate some of the extreme
situations that may occur under any particular set of tax laws.
I do not change the taxpayers from location to location. For example, if I calculate the New Jersey
income tax for a particular taxpayer, I do not assume the person’s characteristics change they do
not purchase a New Jersey home and pay (higher) New Jersey property taxes, nor do their medical or
charitable deductions change. There is no perfect way to deal with this issue; the way I have done it is
to calculate taxes on the same individual in each location, with the only difference being in the state
and local income taxes they pay and in how that affects their federal income tax liability.
To analyze this database I built a model that calculates 2013 tax liability for each taxpayer under
the current New York City income tax, the New York State income tax, the state income taxes in
Connecticut and New Jersey, and the federal income tax. The model allows taxpayers to deduct state
and local taxes, including income taxes, against the federal income tax, if itemization is better for them
than the federal standard deduction. Thus, a given taxpayer will have a different federal tax liability
when the state and tax regime being evaluated changes. I tried to incorporate all major features of
each tax system into the model. At the federal level it reflects the reduced tax rate on capital gains
and the alternative minimum tax. The state and local tax calculations in each jurisdiction incorporate
major tax features that are broadly available or required, such as phaseouts of exemptions, deductions,
and lower tax bracket savings, but not those that are dependent on more-unusual circumstances. For
example, the model incorporates the New York State and New York City household credits, and the
New Jersey property tax credit, but it does not reflect the New York State college tuition tax credit.
For each taxpayer the model calculates tax liabilities under the following tax regimes:
1. Current NYC tax regime: New York City income tax liability, associated New York State
liability, and associated federal tax liability.
Citizens Budget Commission
28
2. 0.75 percent top rate increase: New York City, New York State, and federal tax liabilities,
using a top tax rate of 4.626 percent and with the itemized deduction for income taxes adjusted
accordingly.
3. 10 percent surcharge: New York City, New York State, and federal tax liabilities, assuming
that New York City tax before credits is increased by 10 percent, with the itemized deduction
for income taxes adjusted accordingly.
4. New York outside of New York City: New York state tax liability and associated federal tax
liability, without calculation of City liability.
5. Connecticut tax liability: Connecticut state income tax and associated federal income tax.
6. New Jersey tax liability: New Jersey state income tax and associated federal income tax.
The model also calculates summary measures for each taxpayer under each tax regime, including
effective tax rates for federal, state, and local income taxes as a percentage of federal adjusted gross
income, and net effective tax rates after taking deductibility of state and local taxes against the federal
income tax. For each taxpayer, under each regime, the model calculates federal income tax with and
without the deduction for income taxes. It treats the difference between the two as the savings from
federal deductibility. Finally, the model compares the various tax measures under each regime to taxes
under the current New York City income tax.
22,530 447 447 468 233 - 228
27,508 803 803 839 446 26 309
32,702 1,198 1,198 1,248 695
144 397
37,575 1,551 1,551 1,615 908 265 478
42,488 1,954 1,954 2,035 1,148 471 557
47,486 2,419 2,
419 2,517 1,438 658 645
52,410 2,875 2,875 2,990 1,723 1,143 728
57,486 3,349 3,349 3,482 2,021 1,597 834
62,576
3,859 3,859 4,010 2,349 2,051 962
70,047 4,603 4,603 4,754 2,827 2,747 1,140
87,039 5,704 5,704 5,907 3,678 3,370 1,644
121,315 7,235 7,235 7,504 4,546 4,479 2,569
171,490 10,465 10,465 10,850 6,609 6,699 4,607
230,088 17,518 17,518 18,242 10,286 9,982 7,453
288,686 25,747 25,747 26,679 16,423 15,821 13,431
487,798 46,351 46,351 48,003 29,835 29,557 26,110
686,909 59,587 60,755 61,993 35,522 38,054 35,453
1,295,235 80,350
83,827 83,236 51,491 52,416 59,095
1,903,561 119,986 126,235 124,304 76,805 77,033 92,053
Source: Author's analysis of hypothecal married-ling-joint taxpayers, as described in text.
Federal adjusted
gross income Current policy
0.75%
top rate
10%
surcharge
New York City
s
uburbs Connecticut New Jersey
New York City
(Reflecting Savings from Deductibility Against Federal Income Tax)
Table D-1: State and Local Tax Liability for Hypothetical Taxpayers
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
29
ENDNOTES
1
Comparing State and Local Taxes in Large U.S. Cities, Fiscal Brief (New York City Independent Budget Office,
February 2007).
2
For a review of the literature, see Elizabeth A. Roistacher, How Much Do Taxes Matter? What Economists Can -
and Can Not - Tell New York City Policymakers (Citizens Budget Commisssion, December 11, 2006).
3
Andrew Haughwout et al., “Local Revenue Hills: Evidence from Four US Cities,” Review of Economics and
Statistics 86, no. 2 (2004): 570–585.
4
Moshe Adler, Oliver Cooke, and James Parrott, “Do Tax Increases in New York City Cause a Loss of Jobs? A
Review of the Evidence,State Tax Notes, February 4, 2002, http://fiscalpolicy.org/wp-content/uploads/2011/06/
critique.pdf.
5
Andrew Lai, Roger Cohen, and Charles Steindel, The Effects of Marginal Tax Rates on Interstate Migration in
the US (New Jersey Department of the Treasury, October 2011).
6
“Trend #1: ‘Millionaires’ Taxes’ | Tax Foundation,” 1, accessed November 4, 2013, http://taxfoundation.org/
article/trend-1-millionaires-taxes.
7
Cristobal Young, Charles Varner, and Douglas S. Massey, Trends in New Jersey Migration: Housing, Employment,
and Taxation (Policy Research Institute for the Region, Princeton University, September 2008).
8
Out migration rates were relative to the population of HMHs in New Jersey. Inmigration rates were relative to
the number of HMHs outside of New Jersey (the pool of available inmigrants).
9
Cristobal Young and Charles Varner, “Millionaire Migration and State Taxation of Top Incomes: Evidence from a
Natural Experiment,” National Tax Journal 64, no. 2 (2011): 255–284.
10
Most versions of the model used all 1.4 million observations of individual taxpayers with income of $200,000 or
more, for the years 2000 through 2007. The dependent variable was an indicator that was coded -1 if a taxpayer
outmigrated, +1 if they inmigrated, and 0 if they had not moved. They estimated the model by ordinary least
squares (OLS), and calculated robust standard errors that were clustered within 20 income groups. One analysis
criticized their use of OLS for this model rather than a multinomial logit model (Antony Davies and John Pulito.
Tax Rates and Migration. Working Paper. Mercatus Center, George Mason University, August 2011.) In response
to a query from me, Young stated that the complaint reflects an outdated understanding of what is important
in econometric analysis. Today, OLS is routinely used for limited dependent variables because the results are
readily interpretable, which is not the case for ordered or multinomial logit.(Email correspondence, October
26, 2013.)
11
In this discussion, a coefficient is deemed statistically significant if 5 percent level of significance using a two-
tailed test.
12
I describe the revenue loss as “potential” because it relies on the assumption that all outmigrants take their jobs
with them and on coefficients in the analysis that were not statistically significant.
13
Charles Varner and Cristobal Young, “Millionaire Migration in California: The Impa ct of Top Tax Rates” (2012),
http://www.stanford.edu/group/scspi/_media/working_papers/Varner-Young_Millionaire_Migration_in_CA.pdf.
14
Andrew Lai, Roger Cohen, and Charles Steindel, The Effects of Marginal Tax Rates on Interstate Migration
in the US (New Jersey Department of the Treasury, October 2011). Roger Cohen, Andrew Lai, and Charles
Steindel, “Tax Flight Has Tangible Effects On Income Tax Revenue,” State Tax Notes, February 20, 2012.
Citizens Budget Commission
30
15
Stanley J. Rolark, Alison Fields, and William Frey, “Migration Data From the U.S. Census Bureau,November 15,
2011. In addition, 0.4 percent moved from abroad. The numbers do not add to 11.6 percent because of rounding.
16
Alicia Sasser, Voting with Their Feet? Local Economic Conditions and Migration Patterns in New England”
(2009), http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2125167.
17
Raven Molloy, Christopher L. Smith, and Abigail K. Wozniak, Internal Migration in the United States (National
Bureau of Economic Research, 2011), http://www.nber.org/papers/w17307.
18
The denominator for the rates is the number of people who stayed in the region from one year to the next, plus
the number who moved out.
19
All of the ACS data are from a sample and are subject to sampling error. Most differences discussed here are
statistically significant at the 5 percent level of significance.
20
In this case, the odds ratio is significant at the 5 percent level.
21
The data are from Tables 37, 38, 41, 42, 43, and 46 of the New York State Department of Taxation and Finance’s
Analysis of 2010 Personal Income Tax Returns, September 2013, available at http://www.tax.ny.gov/pdf/stats/
stat_pit/pit/analysis_of_2010_personal_income_tax_returns.xls.
22
Note that federal deductibility narrows inter-jurisdictional differences substantially for some taxpayers but
not others. Some taxpayers receive little or no benefit from federal deductibility of state and local income taxes –
those who do not itemize deductions, and those who are subject to the federal alternative minimum tax.
23
The average impact of this adjustment in New York City is to reduce taxable assessed value by about 15 percent.
24
Marilyn M. Rubin, A Guide to New York City Taxes: History, Issues and Concerns (Peter J. Solomon Family
Foundation, December 2010).
25
Michael Hyman et al., “FY’ 2014 Guidelines for Properties Valued Based on the Income Approach, Including
Office Buildings, Retail, Garages, Hotels, and Residential Properties” (Property Division, New York City
Department of Finance, 2013).
26
Based on author’s analysis of data in Office Sales Prices to Asking Rents: A Critical Ratio, Real Estate Forefront:
Emerging Developments in the NYC Marketplace (Eastern Consolidated, March 2010).
27
Based on numerous telephone interviews with tax certiorari attorneys, realtors, assessment office staff, staff in
the New York State Office of Real Property Services, and others.
28
See Estimated Effective Property Tax Rates 2001-2010: Selected Municipalities in Northeastern Illinois (The
Civic Federation, January 28, 2013).
29
7 Cristobal Young, Charles Varner, and Douglas S. Massey, Trends in New Jersey Migration: Housing,
Employment, and Taxation (Policy Research Institute for the Region, Princeton University, September 2008).
30
Andrew Lai, Roger Cohen, and Charles Steindel, The Effects of Marginal Tax Rates on Interstate Migration in
the US (New Jersey Department of the Treasury, October 2011).
31
The report says the models also included interstate differences in per-capita income, but the reported results
do not show this.
32
Cristobal Young and Charles Varner, “Millionaire Migration and State Taxation of Top Incomes: Evidence from
a Natural Experiment,” National Tax Journal 64, no. 2 (2011): 255–284.
33
Andrew Lai, Roger Cohen, and Charles Steindel, The Effects of Marginal Tax Rates on Interstate Migration in
the US (New Jersey Department of the Treasury, October 2011).
Tax Policy Choices and New York City’s Competitive Position
31
34
13 Charles Varner and Cristobal Young, “Millionaire Migration in California: The Impact of Top Tax Rates”
(2012), http://www.stanford.edu/group/scspi/_media/working_papers/Varner-Young_Millionaire_Migration_in_
CA.pdf.
35
The data are from Tables 37, 38, 41, 42, 43, and 46 of the Department of Taxation and Finance’s Analysis of
2010 Personal Income Tax Returns, September 2013, available at http://www.tax.ny.gov/pdf/stats/stat_pit/pit/
analysis_of_2010_personal_income_tax_returns.xls.
36
The state produces an annual county of residence study, the latest of which is for 2009: Department of Taxation
and Finance, New York Adjusted Gross Income and Tax Liability: Analysis of 2009 State personal income tax
returns by place of residence, June 2012.