AMERICAN ENTERPRISE INSTITUTE 1
Should the Federal Reserve Issue a
Central Bank Digital Currency?
By Paul H. Kupiec August 2021
During Federal Reserve Chairman Jerome Powell’s July 2021 congressional testimony, several
elected members encouraged Powell to fast-track the issuance of a Federal Reserve digital cur-
rency. Chairman Powell indicated he is not convinced there is a need for a Fed digital currency.
But he also indicated that Fed staff are actively studying the issue and that his opinion could
change based on their findings and recommendations. In this report, I explain how a new Fed-
eral Reserve digital currency would interface with the existing payment system and review the
policy issues associated with introducing a Fed digital currency.
The Bank for International Settlements defines
central bank digital currency asa digital payment
instrument, denominated in the national unit of
account, that is a direct liability of the central
bank” (BIS 2020). In his semiannual appearance
before Congress, Federal Reserve Chairman Jerome
Powell indicated that the Fed was studying the idea
of creating a new dollar-based central bank digital
currency (USCBDC) (Lee 2021). The design of
USCBDC has important implications for the US finan-
cial system. To facilitate the policy discussion, I
discuss how a US digital currency relates to existing
forms of dollar-based money, the payments sys-
tem, competing privately issued stablecoins, and
the policy issues associated with USCBDC design.
Central Bank Money, Digital Money,
and Efficiency of Payments Systems
At present, the Federal Reserve issues two types of
central bank moneypaper Federal Reserve notes
and digital Federal Reserve deposits (Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System 2021b).
Digital deposits are money recorded in (electronic)
ledger entries with no physical form. Digital Fed-
eral Reserve deposits can only be held by financial
institutions (primarily banks) eligible for master
accounts at a Federal Reserve bank.
Most businesses and consumers are not eligible
to own Federal Reserve master accounts, so they
cannot own Federal Reserve digital deposits under
current arrangements. They can own central bank
money in the form of paper Federal Reserve notes
or hold “bank money”US dollar-denominated
digital currency in the form of bank deposits that
are exchangeable at par into paper Federal Reserve
notes. Unlike central bank digital money, bank-
issued digital deposits can be subject to default
losses if the bank issuing deposits fails. However,
bank deposits up to $250,000 per depositor are
fully insured by the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation (FDIC), and the maximum effective
AMERICAN ENTERPRISE INSTITUTE 2
insurance coverage on bank deposits can be increased
simply by keeping deposit accounts in multiple banks.
The infrastructure for settling domestic trans-
actions between financial institutions using cen-
tral bank digital deposits is well-developed, fast,
reliable, and inexpensive.
1
Domestic transfers of
central bank digital deposits can settle in real time
or end of day depending on the settlement system
used.
2
Settlement systems for international trans-
fers of central bank deposits are reliable if more
expensive than domestic transfers. However, efforts
are underway to reduce international transactions
costs (FSB 2020b).
1
For example, Fedwire, the Federal Reserve System for transferring bank master account balances, charges institutions a monthly fee
for access and transactions fees that depend on the volume of transactions. The FRB (2021) details the current Fedwire ACH fee schedule.
2
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2021a) explains the Federal Reserve’s Fedwire Fund Services.
3
Venmo is an example of a state-licensed money transfer service that offers settlement times faster than standard ACH transactions do.
The transfer of digital bank money is the primary
mechanism used to settle retail transactions in the
US. Transfers of bank retail digital deposits are
inexpensive but historically have taken longer to
settle than central bank digital deposit transfers.
Table 1 provides the fees and settlement times
associated with Automated Clearing House (ACH)
domestic deposit transfers for a sample of US
banks. New real-time processing systems are now
available (Clearing House 2021) for settling bank
retail digital transactions (Zelle 2021). In addition,
popular online money transfer services
3
linked to
bank accounts offer, for a fee, a faster settlement
Terminology
A short description of some industry-specific terminology is below.
Stablecoins. Stablecoins are a class of cryptocurrencies that attempts to maintain a fixed
exchange rate with a designated fiat currency or basket of fiat currencies by holding reserve
assets that can be used to buy and sell coins on cryptocurrency exchanges to maintain
the target exchange rate peg.
Federal Reserve Master Account. Eligible institutions may have one master account at
a designated Federal Reserve bank that is both a record of financial transactions that reflects
the financial rights and obligations of an account holder and of the Federal Reserve bank
with respect to each other and the place where opening and closing balances are deter-
mined (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System 2021c).
Automated Clearing House (ACH). The ACH is an electronic funds transfer system run
by NACHA, formerly called the National Automated Clearing House Association, since
1974. This payment system provides ACH transactions for use with payroll, direct deposit,
tax refunds, consumer bills, tax payments, and many more payment services in the US.
Blockchain. Blockchain is a decentralized, distributed, public digital ledger consisting of
historical transactions processed and recorded in uniform sequential groups of transac-
tions called blocks. Each block of transactions is processed across many computers using
cryptographic methods that make it difficult to falsify a record or alter records retroactively.
Permissioned Blockchain. This blockchain network has limited access to a shared dis-
tributed ledger. Controlling access to ledger transaction processing and record verifica-
tion allows ledger security to be maintained with more efficient cryptographic methods.
AMERICAN ENTERPRISE INSTITUTE 3
time than standard ACH transfers (Venmo 2021).
The volume of transactions settled in real time will
undoubtedly increase over time.
In contrast, the processing of cryptocurrency
transactions is costly in computing resources and
electricity consumption (McDonald 2021), and trans-
actions fees and settlement timing vary according
to the volume of transactions and the public
computing resources processing the distributed
ledger. Figure 1 shows the average daily cost of pro-
Table 1. Electronic Bank Deposit Transfer Fees and Settlement Times at Selected Banks
Financial Institution
Transfer Fee
Cost (Both Directions Unless Specified)
Approximate Delivery Times*
Alliant Credit Union
$0
One business day
Ally Bank
$0
Three business days
American Express National
Bank
$0
One to three business days; three or more
business days for transfers initiated at the
bank where the funds should
arrive
Axos Bank
$0
Three to five business days
Bank of America
To Bank of America account: $0
From Bank of America account (three busi-
ness days):
$3
From Bank of America account (next day):
$10
Three business days; option for next
-day
delivery
Bank5 Connect
To Bank5 Connect account: $0
From Bank5 Connect account (standard de-
livery): $0
From Bank5 Connect account (next day):
$3
Up to three business days; option
for next-
day delivery
Barclays
$0
Two to three business days
Boeing Emp
loyees Credit
Union
$0
Two to three business days; option for free
next
-day delivery
Capital One 360 Bank
$0
Two business days
Chase
$0
One to two business days
Citibank
$0
Three business days; option for free n
ext-
day delivery
Discover Bank
$0
Up to four business days
Navy Federal Credit Union
$0
Two to three business days
PNC Bank
$0
Three business days
Synchrony Bank
$0
Up to three business days
TD Bank
$0
One to three business days
US Bank
To US Bank account: $0
From US Bank account:
Up to $3
Three business days; option for free next
-
day delivery (incoming transfers only)
Wells Fargo
$0
To Wells Fargo account: Three business
days
From Wells Fargo acc
ount: Two business
days
Note: * These are typical outgoing and incoming transfer times when initiated through online banking, according to each financial institution’s
disclosures and general policies. Delays can occur due to holding periods, sending after daily cutoff times, initial service setup, and other reasons.
This list includes only personal accounts, not business accounts.
Source: Burnette and Tierney (2021).
AMERICAN ENTERPRISE INSTITUTE 4
cessing a stablecoin transaction on the Ethereum-
distributed blockchain ledger over the past year.
These costs, while much higher on average than
the costs of domestically transferring bank deposit
balances, are mostly lower than the cost of trans-
ferring bank deposits internationally.
USCBDC, Stablecoins, and Competing
Digital Currencies
One rationale for so-called stablecoin cryptocur-
rencies like Facebook’s proposed Diem is the claim
that they will bring down the cost of processing
transactions, especially when transactions are inter-
national and involve countries with less-developed
financial infrastructures (Libra Association Mem-
bers 2020). Reportedly, Diem balances will be
maintained and transactions processed using some
type of “permissioned” distributed ledger that
could make transactions processing more efficient
than bitcoin’s blockchain process (Auer, Monnet, and
Shin 2021). Diem’s transactions processing system
is still being developed, so Diem transactions costs
are yet to be determined.
Notwithstanding Diem representations regarding
transactions costs, any transaction cost reductions
achieved by privately issued stablecoins settled using
distributed ledger systems would likely be under-
cut by the cost savings achievable with centralized
USCBDC transactions processing. This presumes
of course that international ownership of USCBDC
would be legal and widely used.
Proponents of private stablecoin cryptocurren-
cies and USCBDC argue that both would provide
the unbanked with a new, more affordable way to
access to the banking and payment system. As dis-
cussed below, unless USCBDC pays interest,
USCBDC account holders will likely face costs to
maintain USCBDC accounts and transfer balances
to reimburse the costs intermediaries must expend
to maintain and transfer USCBDC balances. While
USCBDC payments processing will likely be less
expensive than the cost of maintaining and trans-
acting in private stablecoins, the unbanked would
still face costs unless subsidy programs were cre-
ated to defray the costs for targeted individuals.
Similar subsidy programs could be used to alleviate
the “unbanked problem” (FDIC 2012) using digital
bank deposit accounts, so it is unclear why a
USCBDC is a better solution for giving the unbanked
access to the payment system.
In sum, there is not a strong case for creating
USCBDC based on the cost and efficiency of domes-
tic payment transaction processing, especially con-
sidering the efficiency improvements that will
come with expanded real-time processing systems
for digital bank deposits. Moreover, the allure of the
anonymity once associated with privately issued
Figure 1. Average Daily Cost to Process a Stablecoin Transaction on the Ethereum-Distributed
Blockchain Ledger
Source: YCharts (2021).
AMERICAN ENTERPRISE INSTITUTE 5
cryptocurrencies such as bitcoin and Ethereum is
being eroded as private cryptocurrency users are
increasingly required to comply with antimoney
laundering and terrorist finance laws in the US and
other developed countries.
The Financial Stability Board has opined that,
unless they are properly regulated, privately issued
stablecoins can threaten financial stability (FSB
2020a). One argument favoring USCBDC is that it
would prevent privately issued stablecoins from
becoming systemically important pseudo-currencies.
When recently questioned about the Fed’s plans
regarding a USCBDC, Fed Chairman Powell
responded,You wouldnt need stablecoins, you
wouldnt need cryptocurrencies, if you had a digital
US currency. I think thats one of the stronger
arguments in its favor (US House Committee on
Financial Services 2021). Others (Adler and Pollock
2021) focus on digital currency competition among
central banks, arguing that the Fed will be forced
to issue its own digital currency to prevent China’s
digital currency from undermining the US dollars
international reserve currency status. Rightly or
wrongly, senior Fed officials (Quarles 2021) are,
however, skeptical of this argument.
USCBDC Demand
If the Fed were to issue USCBDC, current features
of our monetary system will likely generate demand
for this new digital currency. Many businesses
must maintain large uninsured bank deposit bal-
ances to meet payroll and other expenses. These
bank deposits are exposed to losses should the
bank holding the deposits fail. USCBDC may be an
attractive alternative for some uninsured deposi-
tors because USCBDC eliminates the risk of loss
due to bank failure.
Money market mutual funds (MMFs) are another
potential source of USCBDC demand. On behalf of
their account holders, MMFs invest large amounts
in short-term debt instruments such as Treasury
bills, commercial paper, and repurchase agreements.
Depending on MMF investments, account holders
can be exposed to losses from defaults or prema-
ture investment liquidations. During periods of
financial stress and elevated default risk, MMF
account holders will likely prefer the certainty of a
USCBDC deposit over an investment in a MMF.
A third source of potential USCBDC demand is
international investors. Currently, deposit insur-
ance protections for digital bank money only apply
to deposits in domestically chartered and insured
depository institutions and a few domestic
branches of foreign banks with “grandfathered
insurance coverage. Dollar deposits in foreign
banks are not protected by FDIC insurance and are
subject to loss should the foreign bank fail.
USCBDC Design
The framers of the Federal Reserve Act never envi-
sioned USCBDC, so it is an open issue whether the
Fed has the legal authority to issue a new Fed digi-
tal currency. In response to members of Congress
questions about the need for explicit authorizing
legislation, the chairman admitted he was unsure
of the Feds legal standing regarding USCBDC but
further stated that, under his chairmanship, the
Fed would not undertake such a step without strong
congressional support, even if the Fed’s legal staff
could justify USCBDC based on existing authorities.
Two designs could be used to issue USCBDC. In
one, the Fed would accept dollars and issue a digi-
tal dollar token with a unique digital identifier. The
digital token would then trade and settle using
some type of distributed public ledger technology.
The integrity of this type of digital currency relies
on a large number of independent processors to
verify the authenticity of a transaction and ensure
that token owners cannot spend the same token twice.
Digital currencies of this design are not well suited for
retail transactions because transactions are expen-
sive to process in volume using a public distributed
ledger and payees may face significant delays and
uncertain fees to verify the transfer of funds.
An alternative USCBDC design is more suitable
for processing retail transactions. It uses a single
private ledger controlled by the Fed to process and
record USCBDC transactions. Under this approach,
USCBDC purchasers could have their own individ-
ual deposit accounts at a Federal Reserve bank, or,
more likely, USCBDC accounts would be issued by
financial intermediaries who would in turn have a
USCBDC account at the Fed. Retail accounts
would be established and managed by qualified
financial intermediaries who would be required to
AMERICAN ENTERPRISE INSTITUTE 6
back each dollar of USCBDC they issue with a dol-
lar deposit in the intermediary’s Federal Reserve
USCBDC account. In other words, USCBDC inter-
mediaries would have to back their USCBDC accounts
with a 100 percent investment in Federal Reserve
master account balances.
If individuals were allowed to open USCBDC
accounts held directly at a Federal Reserve bank,
the Fed would be responsible for complying with
all the regulations associated with retail deposit
accounts, such as meeting know-your-customer
antimoney laundering and terrorism finance
requirements and maintaining an internet portal in
which perhaps millions of customers could view
their account balances and transfer funds. If, alter-
natively, USCBDC is issued using intermediaries,
the intermediary will interface with the retail cus-
tomer and be responsible for enforcing all regula-
tions associated with deposit intermediaries, pro-
cessing transactions, and maintaining customer
balance information while only reporting the inter-
mediaries’ net USCBDC transactions to the Fed for
processing. Financial intermediaries will almost
certainly be involved should the Fed decide to issue
USCBDC.
Every dollar of USCBDC created is a liability of
the Fed and must be matched by assets of equiva-
lent value on the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet.
In the case of Federal Reserve notes and central
bank reserve balances, the offsetting liabilities are
US Treasury securities, agency mortgage-backed
securities, collateralized loans to depository insti-
tutions, and loans to other financial intermediaries
made through crisis-related special purpose lend-
ing programs. The proceeds of USCBDC deposits
could be used to purchase similar assets unless
Congress intervenes to restrict or expand the assets
the Fed is allowed to purchase using USCBDC
receipts.
USCBDC issuance will directly affect banks and
MMFs. The bulk of the dollar balances used to pur-
chase USCBDC will come directly from bank deposit
accounts and MMF accounts. Deposits are typically
a bank’s cheapest source of funding and the pri-
mary instrument banks use to fund loans and other
investments. If USCBDC are purchased using bank
deposits, banks will have to contract their loans
and security investments or replace lost deposits
with a more expensive source of funding. Either
way, the cost of bank credit could substantially
increase should USCBDC prove popular with bank
depositors.
Similarly, MMF account holders may withdraw
balances to purchase USCBDC. Withdrawals will
affect MMFsability to purchase commercial paper
and other short-term liabilities that are an important
source of funding for many large business and cor-
porations. Should a significant volume of USCBDC
purchases come at the expense of MMF account
balances, interest rates could increase on short-term
marketable paper issued by private-sector firms.
One of the most important issues surrounding
USCBDC design is the payment of interest. Should
the Fed be permitted to pay interest on USCBDC,
and, if so, at what rate?
One option is to prohibit USCBDC from paying
interest. Paper moneyFederal Reserve notes
pays no interest, and before the passage of the
Dodd-Frank Act, bank transaction account balances
were prohibited from paying interest. At present,
only depository institutions are allowed to earn
interest on balances held in Federal Reserve mas-
ter accounts. Government-sponsored enterprises
and primary dealers can have Fed master accounts
but do not earn interest on these account balances.
If USCBDC intermediaries were given the same
status as other non-depository master account
holders, the no-interest convention would be con-
sistent with current practice. However, prohibiting
interest would limit the retail demand for
USCBDC, as USCBDC account holders would
likely be required to pay intermediaries to main-
tain USCBDC accounts and process transactions.
The Federal Reserve may prefer paying interest
on USCBDC balances if the Fed is allowed to vary
the interest rate on these balances and the rate is
allowed to differ from the rate the Fed pays on
depository institution master account balances.
Under this design, the Fed would acquire a new
instrument that could be used to control MMF bal-
ances and bank reserves. This additional instru-
ment could enhance the Fed’s ability to attain its
monetary targets, but it would also disrupt the tra-
ditional business models of banks and MMFs.
The interest rate earned on USCBDC will likely
be an important factor that determines institutional
investor interest in USCBDC under normal condi-
tions. If USCBDC pays no interest, institutional
AMERICAN ENTERPRISE INSTITUTE 7
balances will likely remain bifurcated between unin-
sured bank deposits and MMF accounts because it
will be costly to maintain USCBDC balances and
process transactions, whereas uninsured bank
deposits typically generate nonpecuniary benefits
for account holders and MMF balances generate
marginal account holder returns. Other things
equal, higher USCBDC interest rates will draw
larger balances from MMFs and uninsured bank
deposits into USCBDC.
Suppose the Fed were to issue USCBDC and set
the interest rate above the overnight reverse repur-
chase rate (0.05 percent as of July 30, 2021, according
to the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis) but below
the interest rate it pays banks on bank reserves
held at the Fed (currently 0.15 percent). This
USCBDC interest rate would likely attract some
institutional money and drain account balances
from both MMFs and large uninsured bank depos-
its. This in turn would reduce the volume of Fed
overnight reverse repurchase agreements and
reduce bank reserves, reducing banks’ and MMFs
capacity to fund private-sector credit. Conversely,
negative USCBDC interest rates or any rate below
the overnight reverse repurchase rate would signif-
icantly diminish the appeal of USCBDC.
On issues of financial stability, the availability of
USCBDC could cause panicked uncontrolled disin-
termediation in a financial crisis. Facing an elevated
risk of default losses, uninsured bank depositors
and MMF account holders would likely pull their
balances from banks and MMFs to purchase
USCBDC regardless of interest rates because
USCBDC has no default risk. In a financial crisis,
private-sector financial institutions would likely
hemorrhage funds as investors ran to the safety of
USCBDC.
Conclusion
The dominant form of money in the US is digital
money in the form of bank deposits. Fast, reliable,
and inexpensive systems are in place to process
domestic digital bank deposit transactions. Inter-
national digital deposit transfers are more expen-
sive, but plans are underway to improve the effi-
ciency of these systems. There are no compelling
reasons to believe that USCBDC would increase
the speed and reduce the cost of domestic transac-
tions processing relative to the systems used to
process bank digital deposits.
The design of a USCBDC has
important implications for the finan-
cial system and private-sector credit
availability.
The international availability of a USCBDC
would undermine the competitiveness of privately
issued stablecoins and likely prevent them from
becoming a financial stability threat. Federal Reserve
officials discount arguments that a USCBDC is
necessary to defend the reserve currency status of
the US dollar, but competition among central bank
digital currencies could become an important con-
sideration in the future.
The design of a USCBDC has important impli-
cations for the financial system and private-sector
credit availability. If issued, USCBDC almost cer-
tainly will use a private central ledger controlled by
the Fed and employ regulated intermediaries to
interact with USCBDC retail accounts.
Decisions regarding USCBDC interest payments
are a crucial design issue. Prohibiting USCBDC
from paying interest, while consistent with the lack
of interest earned on paper currency, will limit the
appeal of USCBDC under normal conditions.
USCBDC balances will entail transactions fees that
may make USCBDC appear to be the most expen-
sive form of dollar-denominated “money.” If
USCBDC is allowed to earn interest, the USCBDC
interest rate will be a new monetary policy instru-
ment that the Fed can use to regulate the level of
reserves in the financial system. Regardless, the
availability of USCBDC will introduce a new finan-
cial stability concern: In a financial crisis, the finan-
cial disintermediation caused by an uncontrolled
run into USCBDC will severely disrupt the availa-
bility of private-sector credit.
AMERICAN ENTERPRISE INSTITUTE 8
About the Author
Paul H. Kupiec is a senior fellow at the American Enterprise Institute, where he studies economic issues
related to banking and financial services.
References
Adler, Howard, and Alex Pollock. 2021. “Why a Fed Digital Dollar Is a Bad Idea.” RealClearMarkets. July 22. https://www.realclear-
markets.com/articles/2021/07/22/why_a_fed_digital_dollar_is_a_bad_idea_786639.html.
Auer, Raphael, Cyril Monnet, and Hyun Song Shin. 2021. “Permissioned Distributed Ledgers and the Governance of Money.” Working
Paper. Bank for International Settlements. January 27. https://www.bis.org/publ/work924.htm.
BIS (Bank for International Settlements). 2020. “Central Bank Digital Currencies: Foundational Principles and Core Features.”
October 9. https://www.bis.org/publ/othp33.pdf.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2021a. “Fedwire Funds Services.” May 7. https://www.federalreserve.gov/
paymentsystems/fedfunds_about.htm.
———. 2021b. “Financial Accounting Manual for Federal Reserve Banks. July 2021.” July. https://www.federalreserve.
gov/aboutthefed/files/BSTfinaccountingmanual.pdf.
———. 2021c. https://www.federalreserve.gov/.
Burnette, Margarette, and Spencer Tierney. 2021. “What It Costs to Transfer Money Between Banks.” NerdWallet. June 10.
https://www.nerdwallet.com/article/banking/ach-transfer-costs.
Clearing House. 2021. “The RTP Network: For All Financial Institutions.” https://www.theclearinghouse.org/payment-
systems/rtp/institution.
Diem. 2020. “White Paper v2.0.” April. https://www.diem.com/en-us/white-paper/#cover-letter.
FDIC (Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation). 2012. “2011 FDIC National Survey of Unbanked and Underbanked Households.”
September. https://www.fdic.gov/householdsurvey/2012_unbankedreport.pdf.
FRB (Federal Reserve Banks). 2021. “FedACH Services 2021 Fee Schedule.” https://www.frbservices.org/resources/fees/ach-2021.html.
FSB (Financial Stability Board). 2020a. “Addressing the Regulatory, Supervisory and Oversight Challenges Raised by ‘Global
Stablecoin’ Arrangements.” April 14. https://www.fsb.org/wp-content/uploads/P140420-1.pdf.
———. 2020b. “FSB Delivers a Roadmap to Enhance Cross-Border Payments.” Press Release. October 13. https://www.fsb.org/
2020/10/fsb-delivers-a-roadmap-to-enhance-cross-border-payments/.
Khatwani, Sudhir. 2020. “Bitcoin Transaction Fees: A Beginner’s Guide for 2020.” Money Mongers. May 30. https://themoney-
mongers.com/bitcoin-transaction-fees/.
Lee, Isabelle. 2021. “Fed Chair Jerome Powell Says Cryptocurrencies and Stablecoins Won’t Be Needed Once the US Has a Digital
Currency.” Business Insider. July 14. https://www.msn.com/en-us/money/markets/fed-chair-jerome-powell-says-cryptocurrencies-
and-stablecoins-wont-be-needed-once-the-us-has-a-digital-currency/ar-AAM9YJ7.
McDonald, Oonagh. 2021. Cryptocurrencies: Money, Trust and Regulation. Newcastle upon Tyne, UK: Agenda Publishing. October 7.
Quarles, Randal K. 2021. “Parachute Pants and Central Bank Money. Utah Bankers Association Convention. Sun Valley, Utah. June 28.
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/quarles20210628a.htm
US House Committee on Financial Services. 2021. “Virtual Hearing: Monetary Policy and the State of the Economy.” YouTube. July 14.
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=gj9ygZHNemY.
AMERICAN ENTERPRISE INSTITUTE 9
Venmo. 2021. “Fees.” https://venmo.com/about/fees/.
YCharts. 2021. “Ethereum Average Transaction Fee.” https://ycharts.com/indicators/ethereum_average_transaction_fee.
Zelle. 2021. “What Is Zelle?” https://www.zellepay.com/support/what-is-zelle.
Robert Doar, President; Michael R. Strain, Director of Economic Policy Studies; Stan Veuger, Editor, AEI Economic Perspectives
AEI Economic Perspectives
is a publication of the American Enterprise Institute (AEI), a nonpartisan, not-for-
profit, 501(c)(3)
educational organization. The views expressed in AEI publications are those of the authors. AEI does not take institutional p
os
itions
on any issues.
© 202
1 by the American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research. All rights reserved. For more information on
AEI Economic
Perspectives
, please visit www.aei.org/feature/aei-economic-perspectives/.