DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES
IZA DP No. 15304
María Padilla-Romo
Cecilia Peluffo
Mariana Viollaz
ParentsEffective Time Endowment and
Divorce:
Evidence from Extended School Days
MAY 2022
Any opinions expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may
include views on policy, but IZA takes no institutional policy positions. The IZA research network is committed to the IZA
Guiding Principles of Research Integrity.
The IZA Institute of Labor Economics is an independent economic research institute that conducts research in labor economics
and offers evidence-based policy advice on labor market issues. Supported by the Deutsche Post Foundation, IZA runs the
world’s largest network of economists, whose research aims to provide answers to the global labor market challenges of our
time. Our key objective is to build bridges between academic research, policymakers and society.
IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper
should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author.
Schaumburg-Lippe-Straße 5–9
53113 Bonn, Germany
Phone: +49-228-3894-0
Email: [email protected] www.iza.org
IZA – Institute of Labor Economics
DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES
ISSN: 2365-9793
IZA DP No. 15304
Parents’ Effective Time Endowment and
Divorce:
Evidence from Extended School Days
MAY 2022
María Padilla-Romo
University of Tennessee
Cecilia Peluffo
University of Florida
Mariana Viollaz
CEDLAS, IIE-FCE, Universidad Nacional de La Plata and IZA
ABSTRACT
IZA DP No. 15304 MAY 2022
Parents’ Effective Time Endowment and
Divorce:
Evidence from Extended School Days
*
Policies that extend the school day in elementary school provide an implicit childcare
subsidy for families. As such, they can affect parents’ time allocation and family dynamics.
This paper examines how extending the school day affects families by focusing on
marriage dissolution. We exploit the staggered adoption of a policy that extended the
availability of full-time elementary schools across different municipalities in Mexico. Using
administrative data on divorces, we find that the extension in the school day by 3.5 hours
leads to a significant increase in divorce rates. Moreover, the effect grows with every year
of municipalities’ exposure to full-time schooling. Increased female employment due to the
availability of childcare is likely to be one of the mechanisms that relaxed restrictions to
marriage dissolution.
JEL Classification: J12, J13, J18
Keywords: divorce, childcare, full-time schools
Corresponding author:
Mariana Viollaz
CEDLAS-FCE-UNLP
Calle 6 777 e/47 y 48
Piso
Of. 312
CP(1900) La Plata
Buenos Aires
Argentina
* We thank Germán Bet, Celeste Carruthers, Seema Jayachandran, Jason Lindo, David Sappington, and Marianne
Wanamaker for helpful comments and suggestions. Any remaining errors are our own.
1 Introduction
Childcare availability aects families’ time allocation and family members’ opport u n i t i es to
conduct activities outside their households. Limited access to childcare coupled with gender
norms limiting female labor force participation restricts women’s opportunity to allocate their
time to market activities. Because the opportunity to earn income tends to be correlated
with intra-household bargainin g power, this situation directly aects families’ dynamics.
This paper sheds light on the connection between childcare availability and divorce, an
important and unexplored issue given that ear l y family environments are strong predictors
of short and long-run students’ outcomes (Heckman, 2006). Specificall y, we ex a mi n e how
extending the school day by 3.5 hours in public elementary schools in Mexico aects divorce.
In doing so, we provide the first evidence on the eects of access to full-time schools (FTS
hereafter) on marriage dissolut i o n and, to our knowledge, the first causal evidence regarding
the impact of the avail a bi l i ty of subsi d i zed childcare on divorce.
FTS aect families’ decisions due to the implicit childcare subsi d y they provide. A di-
mension in which FTS can aect famil i es is their eect on family structure, speci fi cal ly
through marriage dissolution . Most of the literature on FTS has focused on examining th e
eect of extensions in the school day on students’ learning, finding mixed results.
1
Recent
studies have found tha t the avai l a b i l i ty of FTS has signifi ca nt intra-household eects, in-
creasing the labor force partici p at i o n of mothers and extended family members (Contreras
and Sep´ulveda, 2017; Padilla-Romo and Cabrera-Hern´andez, 2019; Cabrera-Hern´andez and
Padilla-Romo, 2020; Kozhaya and Mart´ınez Flores, 2020).
2
However, litt l e is known about
how the increase in the availability of FTS aects other dimensions of household dynamics.
Considering a simple two-good model of labor supply decisio n s in which caregivers choose
1
See, for example, Cerdan -In fantes and Vermeersch (2007), Bellei (2009), Arzola Gonz´alez (2010), Pires
and Urzua (2010), Dias Mendes (2011), Xerxenevsky (2012), Llamb´ı (2013), Orkin (2013), Almeida et al.
(2016), Hincapie (2016), Cabrera-Hern´andez (2020), Ag¨uero et al. (2021), and Padilla-Romo (2022). For a
discussion on the eects for Latin American and Caribbean countries, see Holland et al. (2015).
2
Other important outcomes that have been studied are teenage pregnancy (Kruger and Berthelon, 2009)
and child labor (Kozhaya and Mar t´ınez Flor es , 2020).
1
between home time (that includes time spent caring for children) and consumpt i o n goods,
extensions in the school day provide school-age children’s main caregivers with a higher
eective time endowment, by freeing time that was previously spent providing child care.
3
Given that children’s main caregivers tend to be mothers or other female family members,
this allows for a highe r female labor force participation.
4
As intra-household bargaining
models suggest, the position of women in bargaining can inc re ase if the level of utili ty they
can independently achieve increases. In this case, women’s outside option can increase either
because of a hi gh e r female individual income (for women who increase their labor suppl y )
or due to the potential of increasing their income (for those women who do not adjust their
labor supply but can do so beca u se o f th ei r ex p an d e d ti m e endowment).
5
From a theoretical perspective, the direction of the expected eect of changes in barg a i n -
ing power and female economic indepe n d en ce that may result from the extension in FTS
on marriage stability is inconclusive. In line with the independence eect hypothesis (Ross
et al., 1975), divorce can increase due to the potential increase in independent sources of
income for women.
6
Moreover, female employment may lead to within househol d conflict or
higher intimate partner violence (Eswaran and Malhotra, 2011; Heath, 2014; Krishnan et al. ,
3
The simplifying assumption is that the consumption good s bundle doe s not inclu de childcare services
due (for example) to lack of availability. Supp os e we as su me that alternative paid sources of childcare are
available. In that case, the school day extension can be interpreted as in line with a model in which the
price of childcare services (included in the consumption bundle) declines.
4
For the particular case of the FTS program implemented in Mexico, there is evidence that this pol-
icy significantly increased female employment (Padilla-Romo and Cabrera-Hern´andez, 2019; Kozhaya and
Mart´ınez Flores, 2020; Cabrera-Hern´andez and Padilla-Romo, 2020). The connection between childcare and
female labor forc e participation (in countries dierent from Mexico) has been studied by Gelbach (2002),
Berlinski and Galiani (2007), Lefebvre and Merrigan (2008), Goux and Maurin (2010), Bauernschust e r an d
Schlotter (2015), Nollenberge r and Rodriguez-Planas (2015), Carta and Rizzica (2018), Eckho Andresen
and Havnes (2019), and Berthelon et al. (2022), amon g others.
5
Increases in labor force p ar t ic i pat i on (and improvements in the type of emp l oyment) have been iden-
tified as positively associated with women’s bargaining power (Anderson and Eswaran, 2009; Heath and
Jayachandran, 2018). Importantly, increasing women’s labor force participation is not a necessary condition
for hi gh er bargai n i ng power. For examp le , Majlesi (2016) shows that higher employment opportunities for
women in Mexico lead to inc r ease s in women’s bargaining power .
6
In the same direction, Becker (1981) explains that the gain s from marriage are reduced, and divorce
becomes more attractive when the re is an incre ase in fe mal e earn i ngs . An important related dimension that
may aect marriage dissol u ti on is the relat i ve earnings of the spouses. In their analysis for the United States,
Bertrand et al. (2015) find that marriages in which the husband earns less than t h e wife are more likely to
get a divorce. Using variation in manufacturing plant openings in Mexico, Estefan avila (2018) shows that
a reducti on in the male-female earnings inequality increases divorce rates.
2
2010; Luke and Munshi, 2011; Guarnieri and Rainer, 2018)whicharelikelytoaect divorce
rates.
7
Yet, the increase in labor force participati on of women can lead to lower economic
stress for th e family and r ed u c e marital conflict, or to lower intimate partner violence due
to a reduction in exposure to the abusive partner (Chin, 2012).
8
Moreover, if childcare has
adeterrenceeect on divorce due to the burden it imposes on the parent receiving custody
of children (Ch er li n, 1977), the implicit reduction in childcare costs originated by this policy
can aect divorce rates directly.
9
Given the comp lex i ty of the mechanisms i n place and the
lack of con sen su s on their expected eect on divorce, empirical evidence is crucial to shed
light on the potential eects of access to subsidized childcare on d i vorce. In this paper, we fill
this gap in the literatur e by studying a policy that provides a large impli ci t childcar e subsidy
by extending the school day from 4.5 to 8 hours for students enrolle d in public elementary
schools in Mexico.
Our empirical approach relies on leveraging plau si b l y exogenous variation from a large-
scale expansion in FTS across Mexican municipalities from 2007 to 2016. To id e ntify the
dynamic eects of the extension in the school day on divorce rates over time, we combine
administrative records from all divorces in Mexico with annual school-level census data
on enrollment and participa ti o n in the FTS progra m . Our estimates are obtained using
the estimation method for intertemporal treatment eects proposed by de Chaisemart i n
and D’Haultfœuill e (2020) which prod u ces estimates that are robust to heterogeneous and
dynamic treatment eects across municipalities and years. We find that, as a result of
an average increase in FTS availability of 24 percentage points, the divorce rate incr ea sed
by 0.046 di vorces per 1,000 individuals (a 15% increment relative to divorces in treated
municipalitie s in the year prior to the openin g of the first FTS). The eect rises over time,
reaching an increase of 0.105 in the divorce rate after the municipalities provided extended
7
Domestic violence can also be aected by the gender wage gap. For the United States, Aizer ( 2010)
finds that declines in the gender wage gap lead to the reduction of violence against women.
8
See He at h and Jayachandran (2018) for an excellent discussion of the literature on female labor force
participation in developing countries, its causes, and consequences.
9
Cherlin (1977)describesthiseect for families with children in prescho ol in the United States.
3
school days for seven years (when the expansion i n FT S re ached 32 percentage points).
To assess the validity o f the estimated eects on divorce rates, we estimate placebo eects
by com p a r i n g the evolution of divorce rates in municipalities not exposed to the FTS pro g ra m
and municipalities implementing this program before the roll-out took place. We find that
the outcome variables for these two groups of municipalities evolved in a parallel way prior
to the program’s implementation, which supports our identification strategy. We also show
that our results are robust to using the interaction-weighted estimator developed by Sun and
Abraham (2021)andtheimputationestimatorproposedbyBorusyak et al. (2021). Finally,
we show that our estimates are robust to controlling for the state-level implementation of
unilateral divorce laws, which allow fo r non-fault un i l a t er a l divorce and have been shown to
increase divorce rates i n Mex i co (Ag u i rr e, 2019; Hoehn-Velasco and Penglase, 2021).
The ext en si o n in the avail a b i l i ty of childcare does not a ect divorce homogeneously acr oss
areas. The increased number of hours elementary school students spend in school leads
to a more pronounced rise in divorce rates in areas with higher initial divorce rates and
higher baseline fema l e employment. These results suggest t h a t women’s increased bargaining
power is likely to result in marriage dissolution in areas where social norms were initially
more favor a b l e to divorce and women’s economic independence. Con si st ent with t h e short-
term labor supply responses to FTS in Mexico do cu m ented in Padilla-Romo and Cabrera-
Hern´andez (2019), we find that childcare availability through extended school days leads
to a rise in female employment in the longer run. This finding indicates that the higher
eective ti me endowment women get due to the introducti on of full-time schooling is used
in the labor market, resulting in hi g h er fem a l e econ o m i c in d ependence.
We contribute to several strands of th e literature. We add to the literature on female eco-
nomic independence and divorce, which in cl u d es studies examining the connection between
female non-labor income, labor income, and potential earnings and marriage st ab i l i ty (Ross
et al., 1975; Becker et al., 1977; Homan and Duncan, 1995; Weiss and Willis, 1997; Jalovaara,
2003; Bobonis, 2011; Ha n ki n s and Hoekstra, 2011; Bergolo and Galv´an, 2018; Berniell et al.,
4
2020). We also contribute to the literature on the intra-household eects of (public) full-
time schools (Contreras and Sep´ulved a, 2017; Padilla-Romo and Cabrera-Hern´andez, 2019;
Kozhaya and Mart´ınez Flores, 2020; Cab r er a -Her n ´andez and Padilla-Romo, 2020; Berthelon
et al., 2022) and, more generally, to the literature on the conn ect i o n between public ex-
penditure and family outcomes (Dickert-Conlin, 1999; Halla et al., 2016; Dahl et al., 2016;
Bastian, 2017).
The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the institutional features related to
divorce in Mexico and the FTS progra m we study. Section 3 presents the data. Section
4 discusses the identification strategy. Section 5 presents the estimated results. Section 6
examines the robustness of our estimates and Sect i on 7 concludes.
2 Background
The FTS pr o gr a m expan s i on tha t we analyze extended the school day for students enrolled
in public Mexica n elementary schools from 4.5 to 8 hours. This federally funded program was
launched sta r t i n g in the 2007-2008 academic year, and it was aimed at improving education
quality by expanding learning opportunities through an extended school schedule. Each state
assigned schools to this program following broad guidelines established by the Secretariat of
Public Education. These guidelines include the requ i r em ent that the schools operate only
in one shift and provide serv i ces for vulnerable students.
10
The FTS program represents one
of the largest investments in education i n the past decad es in Mexico. In Figure 1, we show
the timing of implementation, considering the first year in which the first school in each
municipality was incorporated in the FTS program. In 2007, the pr og r am only covered 500
schools. Over time, the coverage increased , reaching m or e tha n 25 % of pu bl i c elem e ntary
schools in more than 80% of th e municipalities in Mexico.
The extension in the length of school days may aect marriage stability by impacting
10
See Padilla-Romo and Cabrera-Hern´andez (2019), Cabrera-Hern´andez (2020), Cabrera-Hern´andez and
Padilla-Romo (2020), and Padilla-Romo (2022) for a detailed description of the program.
5
female employment. How fem a l e labor market decisions and women’s independence more
generally evolve depends on the gender norms prevailing in society. Social norms aect female
labor mar ket participation because of their influence in the intra-household distribution
of time spent in childcare (Jayachandran, 2021). Like many developing countries, Mexico
exhibits signi ficant gender dierences in the prevalence of unpaid work. By 2019, women
spent 67% of their time carrying out unpaid work while men allocated 28% of their s. Looki n g
specifically at gender dierences in the time allocated to domestic work, women spent (on
average) 30.8 hours per week, and men spent 11. 6 hours in the same acti v i t i es. When
focusing on the care of children, women spent 24.1 hours per week and men spent 11.5 per
week taking care of children aged 14 years or younger.
11
The absence of aordable and high-
quality formal childcare options can exacerbate this issue since it often results in relying on
care by mothers and other female family members (Padilla-Romo and Cabrera-Hern´andez,
2019; Cabrera-Hern´an d ez a n d Padilla-Romo, 2020; Talamas, 2020).
Gender nor m s in terms of care are al so reflected in individuals’ views about female labor
force partici p at i o n . According to the World Values Survey 2017-2020 (Haerpfe r et al., 2020),
31.5% (21.4%) of individuals in Mexico agree (strongly agree) with the statement When
a mother works for pay, the children suer.” To put this inform a t i o n in context, the level
of agreement (strong agreement) in the U.S., Canada, and the U.K. is 17.4%, 16.6%, and
19.9% (3.3%, 4.4%, and 3.4%) respectively. In terms of intra-household dynamics, 28.8%
(24.2%) of individuals in Mexico agree (strongly agree) with the statement indicating If a
woman earns more money than her husband, it’s almost certain to cause problems. ” In the
case of t h e United States, only 10% (0%) of agreement (stro n g agreement) with the same
statement is reported. To examine how prevalent soc i al norms interact with the impact on
divorce, in Section 5.3, we separately examine how access to FTS aected divorces in areas
with dierent degrees of baseline female employment.
Before the implementation of the FTS progr a m , elementary schoo l days of 4.5 hours
11
Data from the 2019 Mexican Time Use S ur vey.
6
imposed additional constraints to the possibility that primary caregivers participate in the
labor market. While in Mexico, women’s labor force participation remains relat i vely low,
it has increased as a response to childcar e subsidies (Padilla-Romo and Cabrera-Hern´andez,
2019; Calderon, 2014).
12
Given the relevan ce of t h e wi t h in household income distribution
as a potential source of conflict, in Section 5.3, we analyze how th e reform aected female
employment in the long run.
Considering divorce regulation, Mexic o h a s l e ga l i zed divorce relatively earlier than other
Latin American countries, allowing for mutual consent divorce and divorce with a cause in
1917 (Brazil, Argentina, and Chile legalized divorce in 1977, 1987, and 2004, respect i vely).
Over time, the country implemented reform s that extended the possible causes for divorce
and allowed for non-fault unilateral divorce.
13
In Section 6, we show that our estima t es are
robust to control for the state-level implementation of unilateral divorce laws.
3Data
Data on divorce filings come from th e National Institute of Statistics and Geography (IN-
EGI). These administ r at i ve data contain individual divorce records and cover all divorces in
Mexico. We calculate divorce rates per 1,000 people using municipality-level popu l at i on pro-
jections from the National Population Council (CONAPO) for each academi c year (August
to July) and municipality.
To measure access to FTS , we rely on school-level census data on enrollment and partic-
ipation in the FTS program from the Secretariat of Publ i c Education. For each academic
year, we match the availability of FTS in each municipality with information on the munic-
ipality of residence of the divorcing wife to capture exposure to the extension in the school
day.
14
To examine long-run eect s on female econ om ic independence, we combine ad m i n is-
12
By 2016, only 43.92% of women older than 15 were economically active in Mexico (ILO S TAT).
13
For the case of Mexico, Aguirre (2019) and Hoehn-Velasco and Penglase (2021) describe the legal changes
over time and analyze the ee ct of unilateral divorce laws on divorce.
14
Information on the municipality in which marriages took place is also available. Given that the average
7
trative records on enrollment and school participation in the FTS prog ra m with census data
on female employment from IPUMS-International for years 2000, 2010, and 2015 for women
aged 15-65.
We restrict our sampl e to municipalities that h ave existed and maintained their geo-
graphic boundaries from 2000 to 2016. We also drop from the analysis municipalities that
experienced the first FTS expansion in the 2007/2008 academic year because many of the
500 school s that adopted the program were already full-time before 2007.
15
Table 1 shows
descriptive statistics for municipali t i es that by 2016 had implemented the FTS program
(Ever Treated)andmunicipalitiesthathadnotimplementedtheprogram(Never Treated).
Ever-treated municipalities had higher divorce rates than never-treated municipalities prior
to the roll-out of the FTS program. On average 58.3% of the municipalities that implemented
the FTS program by 2016 had pre-intervention divorce rat es above th e cross-municipalities
median. The percentage of women employed in 2000 is not significantly dierent between
ever-treated and never-treated municipalities. Still, the percentage of municipalities with
high female employment in 2000 (above the cross-municipalities median) is larg er among
the ever-treated. Ever-treated municipalities had (on average) more population than never
treated municipalities. Moreover, they ar e more likely to be located i n a state that allows
for unilateral divorce by 2016.
4 Identification Strategy
To identify the eects of FTS on divorce, we exploit municipality-level variati o n in the
availabil i ty of elementary FTS. We e st i m at e th e fol l owing fixe d eects model:
length of marriages in our sample is 13 years (with a median of 11 years), the municipality of residence is
likely t o provide a more accurate measure of e x posur e to the program than the municipality of marriage .
We provide evidence on the absence of endogenous migratory respon ses to t h e p rogr am in t h e popu l at ion of
individuals filing for divorce in Section 6.
15
After imposing these restrictions, our analytical sample includes 2, 178 out of the 2,456 existing munici-
palities in 2016.
8
DR
mt
=
m
+
t
+
7
X
k=0
k
FTS
m,tk
+
m
t + u
mt
(1)
where DR
mt
is the divorce rate in municipality m in academic year t,
m
are municipality
fixed eects,
t
are academic year fixed eects, and u
mt
is an error term that we allow to
be correlated wit h i n municipalit i es. Our variable of interest, FTS
m,tk
is an indicator equal
to one k years after the municipality open ed its first FTS, and zero otherwise. To allow for
the possibility of dierential divorce trends across municipalities, we include municipality-
specific linear time-trends as controls (
m
t). The coecients
k
identify the avera g e eect of
k + 1 years of imple m entation of the FTS program on municip a l i ti e s’ d i vorce rates.
Our empirical approach exploits the staggered adoption of the FTS program across munic-
ipalities. Estimation of Equation 1 using two-way-fixed-eects (TWFE) under ordinary least
squares (OL S ) including leads and lags of the implementation of the FTS pol i cy produces
estimates that are not robust to heterogeneous an d dynamic eects over time and across
groups (Goodman-Bacon, 2021; Sun, 2021; de Chaisemartin and D’Haultfœui l l e, 2020). To
overcome this concern, we estimate the regression in Equation 1 foll owing the methodology
developed by de Chaisemartin and D’Hau l t fœu i l l e (2020). This method produces estimates
that are robust to heterogeneous and dynamic treatment eects acro ss municipaliti es and
years under standard common-trends assump t i o n s. The estimates are computed by com-
paring the t k 1tot evolution of divorce rates in municipalities implementing the FTS
program for the first time in tk and municipalities that have not implemented the program
yet in period t.
16
Before presenting our m a i n r es u l ts , and to put our m ai n estimates in context, we examine
how the availability of FTS in a municip al i ty evolves over time once th e municipality s ta r t s
implementing the program. To do so, we follow Padilla-Romo and Cabrera-Hern´andez (2019)
and define ou r outcome variable as th e predicted capacity of FTS in municipali ty m and
16
Weighted averages of those dierence-in-dierences estimators across years are unbiased estimators for
the average eect of having changed treatment for the first time k periods ago (de Chai se mar t i n and
D’Haultfœuille, 2020).
9
academic year t using Equation 2:
FTS
mt
=
P
s2m
¯e
s
FT
st
P
s2m
¯e
s
(2)
where ¯e
s
is the average enrol l m ent at school s fr om 2001 to 2006 (prior to program imple-
mentation) and FT
st
is equal to one if elementary school s participates in the FTS p r o gr am
at academic year t and zero otherwise.
5 Results
5.1 Main Estimates
Panel (a) of Fi gu r e 2 presents the evolution of the predicted capacity of FTS in a municipal i ty
during the first year in which the first FTS was opened (k = 0) and for subsequent years
(k 2 [1, 7]). On average, during the first year in which a municipality implements the
program, the predicted FTS availability increases by 18 percentage points. The eect reaches
its maximum of 32 percentage points six years after, when the municipality had implemented
the program for seven years.
Panel (b) of Figure 2 shows the estimated results of FTS on the aver a ge divorce rate .
In the first year of program implementation, the divorce rate is not aected by the (first)
expansion of the FTS program relative to municipalitie s that did not implement it yet; th e
estimated eect is close to zero and statistically insignificant. However, one year after (k =1)
the divorce rate significantly increases by 0.021 per 1,000 ind i v i d u als. The eects on divorce
increase with every year of municipalities’ exposure to the FTS program. This increasing
eect reflects a combination of increased length of exposure ( i n years since the first opening
of an FTS in a municipality) an d the expansion in the capacity that occurs over t i m e within
municipalitie s implementing this program, as shown in Panel (a). After the municipalities
have been providing extended school days for seven years and FTS avail a b i l i ty i n c re ase d (on
10
average) by 32 percentage points, this large expansion in the availability of implicit childcare
subsidies translates into an average incr eas e in the divorce rate of 0.105 divorces per 1,000
individuals.
To examine the validity of the underlying assumptions for identication, to the left of
zero, Figure 2 shows estimates of placebo eects. In Panel (a), estimates of placebo eects
are zero by construction because they measure the eects on the predicted capacity of FTS
in a municipali ty before the program rollout. Considering the estimates of the eects of the
extension in the school day on divorce, i n Panel (b), we fin d that placebo estimates are close
to zero and statistically insignificant, which provides support to our identification strategy
(we cannot reject the null hypothesis that all placebos are statistically insignificant).
17
5.2 Marriage Dissolution and the Role of Social Norms
Our main estimates show that the divorce rate significantly increases due to the availability
of implicit childcare subsidies. In this section, we analyze the extent to which lack of access
to free childcare constitutes a restriction on marriage dissolution in areas with dierent social
norms.
In particul ar, we examine how the eects on divorce vary by pre-intervention divorce
rates (i.e., average divorce rates for 2000-2007), which we consider as a proxy for social norms
about divorce. We group municipalities above and below the cross-municipality median of
the divorce rate over 2000-2007. Table 2 shows that extensions in the school day did not
result in an increase in divorces in areas with low initia l divorce rates (point estimates are
close to zero and statistically insignificant). In contrast, in areas where divorces were more
common prior to the roll-out of the FTS p r og r am , the implicit childcare subsidy positively
and significantly aects marriage dissolution. Our estimates suggest that while financial
constraints can impose sub stantial restrictions on divorce in municipalities where marriage
17
We estimate long-dierence placebos. While first-dierence placebo estimates test if common trends
hold over pairs of consecutive periods, long-dierence placebos test for the presenc e of common tr en ds
along several periods, where (if present) divergent trends in divorce rates are more likely to be detected
(de Chaise mar ti n and D’Haultfœuille, 2020).
11
dissolution is more accepta b l e to society, childcare subsidies are unlikely to aect marria g e
stability in areas where social norms agains t di vorce are mor e p r evalent.
Aseconddimensionweanalyzeishowtheeects vary with the prevalence of pre-
interventi on female employment (measured with 2000 census data from IPUMS). Intuitively,
gender norms may aect the participation of women in t h e labor market, makin g it dicult
for women to increase their labor supply on ce their eect i ve ti m e endowment has i n cr eased
due to the availability of extended scho ol days. In Table 3, we estim a t e our ma i n regression
for the sub-samples of municipalities where female empl oyment was above and below the
cross-municipality median before the implementation of the imp l i ci t childcare subsidy. The
estimated results show that the overall increase in divorces is mainly explained by the avail-
ability of childcare in municipalities with higher baseline female employment. This indicates
that gender roles and their potential eect on labor force partici p ation (and earnings) shape
how childcare subsidies aect mar r i a g e di sso l u t i o n .
18
5.3 Childcare Availability and Female Economic Independence
Availability of childcare subsi d i es can translate into in cr ea sed bargaining power and economic
independence of women, who are typically the pri m a ry caregivers for children. Increased fe-
male labor supply can ease couples’ financial restrictions and facilitate divorce when partner s
cooperatively make decisions. Higher female labor force participation can also lead to di -
vorce du e to within househol d conflict. Impo r ta ntly, highe r divorce risk can also lead to an
increase in the l a bor force participation of women (Bargain et al., 2012). This implies that
increases in labor force particip a t i o n ca n act as a mechanism that faci l i ta t es d i vorce and as
aresponsetoincreasesintheriskofdivorceanddivorcerates.
Using h o u seh o l d survey data, previous stud i es have documented a short - ru n increase in
18
Even though baseline divorce and employment rates are likely to be related to how traditional social
norms are, th ey exhibit a weak positive correlati on in the data (the correlation coecient between the
indicator var i abl es for being above the median of the baseline fe mal e employment rate and for bein g above
the median of the baseline divorce rate is 0.0657), which suggests they are capturing dierent dimensions
that shape how lack of childcare availability aects divorce rates.
12
labor supply as a response to the extension in FTS availability in Mexico (Padilla-Romo and
Cabrera-Hern´an d ez, 2019; Cabrera-Hern´andez and Padilla-Romo, 2020). We complement
this literature by providing evidence on longer-term eects on female employment relying
on census data. Focusing on the long-term also allows us to examine the impacts on fe-
male employment as an out co m e t h a t accompanies (and in some instances can med i a t e) the
estimated increase in divorce rates due to the extension in the school days.
We use census data on female employment for 2000, 2010, and 2015 from IPUMS. We
proceed by estimating TWFE models. In Tab l e 4, Co l u m n (1), we show that consist ent with
findings in other studies, longer school days lead to an increase in femal e employment (Contr-
eras an d Sep´ulveda, 2017; Padilla- Ro m o and Cabrera-Her n ´andez, 2019; Cabrera-Hern´and ez
and Padilla-Romo, 2020; Kozhaya and Mart´ınez Flores, 2020; Berthelon et al., 2022). Our
estimate indicates that the extension in t he scho ol day by 3.5 hours gen er ated a long-run
average increase of 1.8 percentage points in the share of employed women (6.8% relative to
the baseline in the ever-treated municipalities). However, th i s estimate masks substantial
heterogeneity across municipalities. The eects are close to zero and statistically insignif-
icant when restricting the sam p l e to municipalities with low baseline female employment
rates (female employment rate below the cross-municipality median in 2000). In contrast,
in municipalities where women were more likely to be employed prior to the intervention
(female employment rate above the cross-municipality median in 2000), the eects are large
and statistically significant, with an increase in female employment of 3.6 percentage points
(10.7% relative to the baseline).
Goodman-Bacon (2021) shows that standard TWFE models recover a variance-weighted
average of all two-by-two comparisons in the data. In our setting, in which im p l em entation
of the FTS was staggered, this implies that municipalities in which the policy starts being
implemented in year t are compared with other municipalities that adopted this program
earlier, leading to potentially biased estimates. We eval uat e the severity of this concern
by implementing a decomposition suggested by Goodman-Bacon (2021). Figure 3 sh ows
13
the dierence-in-dierences (DD) esti mates for dierent comparison groups (ever t r ea t ed
vs. never treated, early treated vs. later treated, and later treated vs. early treated)
in the vertical axi s and the associated weights in th e horizontal axis. In Panel (a), we
report estimates for the overall sample. In Panels (b) and (c), we show estimates for the
sub-samples of municipalities wit h baseline female employment rates below and above the
median, respectively. The results of the decomposi t i on suggest that our main conclusions
remain valid. When comparing ever-treated and never-treated municipalities, we find an
eect close to zero for municipalities w i th low initial female employment and positive and
large for the rest of the municipalities.
6 Robustness
Our main results rely on the estimatio n method proposed in de Chaisemartin and D’Haultfœuil l e
(2020), which is one of several estimators available to address issues related to staggered
treatments and heterogeneous eects. However, each method relies on dierent sources of
variation and set of identifying assumptions. To examine th e robustness of our estimates
to alternative estimators, i n Panels (a) th r o u gh (d) of Figure 4, we compa r e the estimated
eects of FTS availab i l i ty on divorce rates using de Ch a i sem a rt i n and D’Haultfœu i l l e (2020)
with other three estimatio n methods: the OLS-TWFE estimator, the interaction-weighted
estimator (Sun and Abraham, 2021), and the imputation estimator ( Borusyak et al., 2021).
Overall, the estimated eects across all four methods increase with every year of exposure
to FTS wi t h point est i m a t es of between 0 . 1 05 and 0. 13 8 after seven years of implementation
of the extension in the school day. Moreover, in all cases, the estimates for the years prior
to treatment are close to zero and statistically insignificant, supporting the parallel trends
assumption.
Because Mexico implemented state-level reforms introdu cin g unilateral divorce laws, we
also examine the robustness of our results (that leverage municipality-level variation in the
14
extension of the FTS program) to controlling for state-level changes in divorce l aws. Becaus e
controlling for addition al treatments imposes empir ical challenges, we star t by stu d y in g
this issue relying on a traditi o n al fixed eects model, which provides more flexibility in
terms of empirical implementation. In Panel (a) of Figure A.1, we show the estimated
eects on divorce using a tradition al OLS fix ed -eect s model adding an indicator for the
implementatio n of unilateral divorce laws as control.
19
A caveat for these resu l t s is that in
TWFE with multi p l e treatment i n d i cat o r s, the estimated coecient in a particul ar treatment
(i.e., availability of FTS in our context) is contaminated by a weighted sum of the eects of
the other treatments in each municipality and year (de Chaisemartin and D’Haultfoeui l l e,
2020). Considering this concern, in Panel (b), we control for the implementation of unilateral
divorce laws using the imputation estimator developed by Borusyak et al. (2021). The
estimated results on divorce rates are robust to using this altern at ive approach.
Finally, because the average duration of marriages in the sam p l e of divorcing individuals
is 13 years (with a median durat i o n of 11 years), we use the municipali ty of residence of
the wife to capture exposur e to the FTS program. A potential concern is that endogenous
migratory responses induced by the program may aect our estimates. We examine the
extent to which FTS explain s the share of divorces in which the municipality of residence of
the wife diers from the municipality of marriage in total divorces (in the municipality of
residence). In Figure 5 we show that FTS expansion is not corr el a te d with changes in this
share, indicating that endogenous mig r at i o n i s u n l ikely to bi a s ou r e st i m at es.
7 Conclusion
This study provides the first causal evidence on the eects of implicit childcare subsidies,
through longer school days, on marriage dissolution. We find that the availa b i l i ty of FTS in
amunicipalityincreasesthedivorcerateper1,000peopleby0.021twoyearsafterthefirst
19
For most of the states, we rely on informati on from Garc´ıa-Ramos (2021) to identify the timing of the
introduction of these laws. In addition, we combine information from Hoehn-Velasco and Penglase (2021)
with information from alternative sources for the cases in wh i ch the date is mi s si ng in Garc´ıa-Ramos (2021).
15
FTS opened and that the eect increases over time, reaching 0.105 divorces per 1,000 people
after seven years. Our main estimates su gg est that the ava i l a b i l i ty of FTS led to 23 , 3 14
additional divorces between 2009 and 2016, or approximately 5 percent of the total number
of divorces filed during this time frame.
20
Mothers and other female family members spend a disp r oportionate fraction of their time
caring for children. Longer school days provided them with an increase in their eective time
endowment that resulted in improved opportunities to acquire individual income. As a result,
the intra-household barg a i n i n g p osi t i o n s are likely to b e mo d i fi ed . Our results sugges t that
these changes in bargaining power translated into h i gh er divorce rates in areas with social
norms more favorable to divorce and to female employment, where lack of access to childcare
was more likely to impose restrictions on marriage dissolution.
20
These numbers are calculated using the est im at ed eects in Column 1 of Table 2.
16
References
Ag¨uero, J., Favara, M., Porter, C. , and anchez, A. (2021). Do More School Resourc es
Increase Learning Outcomes? Evidence from an Extended School-Day Reform.
Aguirre, E. (2019). Do Changes in Divorce Legislation Have an Impact on Divorce Rates?
The Case of Unilateral Divorce in Mexico. Latin American Economic Review, 28(1):1–24.
Aizer, A. (2010). The Gender Wage Gap and Domestic Viol en ce . American Economic
Review,100(4):184759.
Almeida, R., Bresol i n , A., Pugialli Da Silva Borges, B., Mendes, K., and Menezes-Filho,
N. A. (2016). Assessing the Impacts of Mais Educacao on Educational Ou t com e s: Evidence
between 2007 and 201 1 . World Bank Policy Research Working Paper,(7644).
Anderson, S. and Eswaran, M. (2009). What Determin es Female Autonomy? Evidence from
Bangladesh. Journal of Development Economics,90(2):179191.
Arzola Go n z´alez, M. (20 10) . Impacto de la Jornada Escolar Completa en el Desempno de los
Alumnos, Medido con la Evoluci´on en sus Pruebas SIMCE. Santiago: Pontificia Univer-
sidad Catolica de Chile. Obtenido de http://www. economia. puc. cl/docs/tesis mparzola.
pdf.
Bargain, O., Gonz´alez, L., Keane, C., and
¨
Ozcan, B. (2012). Female Labor Supply and
Divorce: New Evidence from Ireland. European Economic Review,56(8):16751691.
Bastian, J. (2017). Unintended Consequences? More Marriage, More Children, an d the
EITC. In Proceedings. Annual Conference on Taxation and Minutes of the Annual Meeting
of the National Tax Association, volume 110, pages 1–56.
Bauernschuster, S. and Schlotter, M. (2015). Public Child Care and Mothers’ Labor Sup-
ply—Evidence from Two Quasi-Experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 123(C):1–16.
17
Becker, G. (1981). A Treatise on the Family. National Bureau of Economic Res ear ch, Inc.
Becker, G. S., Landes, E. M., and Michael, R. T. (1977). An Economic Analysis of Marit al
Instability. Journal of Political Economy,85(6):11411187.
Bellei, C. (2009). Does Lengthening the School Day Increase Students’ Academic Achieve-
ment? Results from a Natural Experiment in Chile. Economics of Education Review,
28(5):629–640.
Bergolo, M. and Galv´an, E. (2018). Intra-household Behavioral Responses to Cash Trans-
fer Programs. Evidence from a Regression Discontinuity Design. World Development,
103:100–118.
Berlinski, S. and Galiani, S. (2007). The Eect of a Large Expansion of Pre-Primary
School Facilities on Preschool Attendance and Maternal Employment. Labour Economics,
14(3):665–680.
Berniell, I., de la Mata, D., and Pinto Machado, M. (2020) . The Impact of a Permanent
Income Shock on the Situation of Women in the Hou seh o l d : The Case of a Pension Reform
in Argentina. Economic Development and Cultural Change,68(4):12951343.
Berthelon, M., Kruger, D., an d Oyarz´un, M. (2022). School Schedules and Mothers’ Em-
ployment: Evidence from an Education Reform. Review of Economics of the Household,
pages 1–41.
Bertrand, M., Kamenica, E., and Pan, J. (2015). Gender Identity and Relative Income
within Households. The Quarterly Journal of Economics,130(2):571614.
Bobonis, G. J. (2011). The Impact of Conditi on al Cash Tran sfe rs on Marriage and Divorce.
Economic Development and Cultural Change,59(2):281312.
Borusyak, K., Jaravel, X., and Spiess, J. (2021). Revisiting Event Study Designs: Robust
and Ecient Estimation.
18
Cabrera-Hern´an d ez, F. (2 0 20 ) . Does Lengthening the School Day Increase Scho o l Value-
Added? Eviden c e from a Mid-Inco m e Country. The Journal of Development Studies,
56(2):314–335.
Cabrera-Hern´an d ez, F. and Padilla-Romo, M. (2020). Women as Caregivers: Full-Time
Schools and Gr an dm o t h er s’ Labor Sup p l y .
Calderon, G. (2014). The Eects of Ch i ld Care Provision in Mexico. Working Paper, Banco
de Mexico.
Carta, F. and Rizzica, L. (2018). Early Kindergarten, Maternal Labor Supply and Children’s
Outcomes: Evidence from Italy. Journal of Public Economics, 158(C):79–102.
Cerdan-Infantes, P. an d Vermeersch, C. (2007). More Time is Better: An Evaluation of
the Full Time School program in Uruguay. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper,
(4167).
Cherlin, A. (1977). The Eect of Children on Mar i t al Dissolution. Demography,14(3):265
272.
Chin, Y.-M. (2012). Male Backlash, Bargaining, or Exposure Reduction?: Women’s Work-
ing Status and Physical Spou sa l Violence in India. Journal of Population Economics,
25(1):175–200.
Contreras, D. and Sep´ulveda, P. (2017). Eect of Len gt h en i ng the School Day on Mother’s
Labor Supply. World Bank Economic Review,31(3):747766.
Dahl, G. B., Løken, K. V., Mogstad, M., and Vea Salvanes, K. (2016). What Is the Case for
Paid Maternity Leave? The Review of Economics and Statistics,98(4):655670.
de Chai sem a rt i n , C. and D’Hault fœ u i l l e, X. (2020). Dieren ce-i n-D ier en ces Estimators of
Intertemporal Treatment Eects. Available at SSRN 3731856.
19
de Chaisemartin, C. and D’Haultfoeuille, X. (2020). Two-way Fixed Eects Regressions with
Several Treatments. Papers 2012.10077, arXi v. o rg.
Dias Mende s, K. ( 2 01 1) . O Impacto do Programa Mais Educa ca o no Desmpenho dos Alunos
da Rede Publica Brasileira. ao Paulo: Universidad de ao Paulo.
Dickert-Conlin, S. (1999). Taxes and Transfers: Their Eects on the Decision to End a
Marriage. Journal of Public Economics,73(2):217240.
Eckho Andresen, M. and Havnes, T. (2019). Child Care, Parental Labor Supply and Tax
Revenue. Labour Economics,61:101762.
Estefan avi l a, M. A. (2018). Male-Female Earnings Inequality and Di vorce Decisions.
Unpublished Manuscript.
Eswaran, M. and Malhotra, N. (2011) . Dom est i c Violence and Women’s Autonomy in De-
veloping Countries: Theory and Evidence. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue cana-
dienne d’´economique,44(4):12221263.
Garc´ıa-Ramos, A. (2021). Divorce Laws an d Intimate Partner Vio l en ce : Evidence from
Mexico. Journal of Development Economics,150:102623.
Gelbach, J. B. (2002). Publ i c School i n g for Young Children and Matern a l Labor Supp l y .
American Economic Review,92(1):307322.
Goodman-Bacon, A. (2021). Dierence-in-Dierences with Variation in Treatment Timing.
Journal of Econometrics, 225(2):254–277. Themed Issue: Treatment Eect 1.
Goux, D. and Maurin, E. (2010). Publ i c School Availability for Two-Year Ol d s and Mothers’
Labour Supply. Labour Economics,17(6):951962.
Guarnieri, E. and Rainer, H. (2018). Female Empowerment an d Male Backlash. CESifo
Working Paper Seri es.
20
Haerpfer, A., Inglehart, R., C., Moreno, A., Welzel, C., Kizilova, K., Diez-Medrano, J.,
Lagos, M., Norris, P., Ponarin, E., and et al. (eds.), B. P. (2020). World Values Survey:
Round Seven - Cou ntry-Pooled Datafile. Madrid, Spain & Vienna, Austria: JD Systems
Institute & WVSA Secretariat. doi:10.14281 / 18 24 1 . 13 .
Halla, M., Lackner, M., and Scharler, J. (2016). Does the Welfare State Destroy the Fam-
ily? Evidence from OECD Member Countries. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics,
118(2):292–323.
Hankins, S. and Hoekstra, M. (2011). L u cky in Life, Unlucky in Love? The Eect of Random
Income Shocks on Marr i age and Divorce. The Journal of Human Resources, 46(2):403–426.
Heath, R. (2014). Women’s Access to Labor Market Opportuniti es, Control of House-
hold Resources, and Domestic Violence: Evidence from Bangladesh. World Development,
57(C):32–46.
Heath, R. and Jayachandran, S. (2018). The Cau ses and Consequences of Increased Female
Education and Labor Force Participation in Developing Countries. In S. Averett, L. A.
and Homan, S., editors, , Oxford Handbook of Women and the Economy.
Heckman, J. J. (2006). Skill Formation and the Economics of Investing in Disadvantaged
Children. Science,312(5782):19001902.
Hincapie, D. (2016) . Do Longer School Days Improve Student Achievement? Evidence from
Colombia. IDB Working Paper Seri es.
Hoehn-Velasco, L. and Penglase, J. (2021). T h e impact of no-fault unilateral divorce laws
on divorce rates in mexico. Economic Development and Cultural Change,70(1):203236.
Homan, S. D. and Duncan, G. J. (1995). The Eect of Incomes, Wag es, and AFDC Benefits
on Marital Disruption. Journal of Human Resources,30(1):1941.
21
Holland, P. A., Alfaro, P., and Evans, D. (2015). Extending the School Day in Latin America
and the Caribbean. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper,(7309).
Jalovaara, M. (2003). The Joint Eects of Marriage Partners’ Socioeconomic Positions on
the Risk of Divorce. Demography,40(1):6781.
Jayachandran , S. (2021). Social Norms as a Barri e r to Women’s Employment in Developing
Countries. IMF Economic Review,69:576595.
Kozhaya, M. and Mart´ınez Flores, F. (2020). Schooling and Child Labor: Evidence from
Mexico’s Full-Time School Program. Ruhr Economic Papers 851, RWI - Leibniz-Institut
f¨ur Wirtschaftsforschung, Ruhr-University Bochum, TU Dortmund University, University
of Duisburg-Essen.
Krishnan, S., Rocca, C. H., Hubbard, A. E., Subb i ah , K., Edmeades, J., and Padian, N. S.
(2010). Do Changes in Spousal Employment S t at u s Lead to Domestic Violence? Insights
from a Prospective Study in Bangalore, India. Social Science & Medicine,70(1):136143.
Kruger, D. and Berthelon, M. (2009). Delaying t h e Bell: The Eects of Longer School
Days on Adolescent Mo t h er h ood in Chile. IZA D i scu s si on Paper s 4553, Ins ti t u t e of Labor
Economics (IZA).
Lefebvre, P. and Merrigan, P. ( 2 00 8 ). Child-Care Policy and the Labor Supply of Mothers
with Young Children: A Natural Experiment from Ca n ad a . Journal of Labor Economics,
26(3):519–548.
Llamb´ı, M. C. (2013). El Efecto Causal de la Pol´ıtica de Tiempo Completo sobre los Resulta-
dos Educativos en la Ense˜nanza Media: Aplicaci´on de Cuatro M´et odos no Experimentales
eIdenticaci´ondePosiblesSesgos.Unpublished working paper.
Luke, N. an d Mun sh i , K. (2011). Women as Agents of Change: Female Income and Mobil i ty
in India. Journal of Development Economics,94(1):117.
22
Majlesi, K. (2016). Labor Market Opportunities an d Women’s Decision Making Power within
Households. Journal of Development Economics, 119(C):34–47.
Nollenberger , N. and Rodriguez-Planas, N. (2015). Full-Time Universal Childcare in a Con -
text of Low Maternal Employment: Qua si -Ex perimental Evidence from Spain. Labour
Economics, 36(C):124–136 .
Orkin, K. (2013). The Eect of Lengthening the School Day on Children’s Achievement in
Ethiopia. Working Paper.
Padilla-Romo, M. (2022). Full-Tim e Schools, Policy-Induced S chool Switching, and Aca -
demic Performance. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,196:79103.
Padilla-Romo, M. and Cabrera-Hern´andez, F. (2019). Easing th e Constraints of Motherhood:
The Eects of All-Day Schools on Mothers’ La bor Supp l y . Economic Inquiry,57(2):890
909.
Pires, T. and Urzua, S. (2010). Longer School Days, Better Outcomes? Northwestern
University.
Ross, H., Sawhill, I., and MacIntosh, A. ( 19 7 5) . Time of Transition: The Growth of Families
Headed by Women. Th e Urb an Institute.
Sun, L. (2 02 1 ). Eventstudyinteract: Stata module to implement the interaction weighted
estimator for an event study.
Sun, L. and Abraham, S. (2021). Estimating Dynamic Treatment Eects in Event Studies
with Heterogeneous Treat m ent Eects. Journal of Econometrics,225(2):175199.
Talamas, M. (2020). Grandmothers and the Gender Gap in the Mexican Labor Market. IDB
Working Paper Seri es.
Weiss, Y. and Willis, R. J. (1997). Match Quality, New Information, and Marital Dissolution.
Journal of Labor Economics,15(1):S293S329.
23
Xerxenevsky, L. L. (2012). Programa Mai s Educa¸ao: Avalia¸ao do Impacto da Educa¸ao
Integral no Desempenho de Alunos no Ri o Gr an d e do Sul.
24
Figure 1: Municipalities with and without Full-time Schools by Academic Year
(a) 2008/09 (b) 2010/11
(c) 2012/13 (d) 2015/16
Notes: Each panel shows all 2,456 municipalities in Mexico and the staggered adoption of the Full-time Schools program. Overall, 220 municipalities
had FTS in 2008/09, 495 in 2010/11, 891 in 2012/13, and 1527 in 2015/16.
25
Figure 2: Estimated Ee ct s on Municipalities’ Predicted Full-time Schools Availability and Divorce Rate
(a) Average Ee ct s on Predicted Full-time Schools Avail-
ability






    

(b) Average Eects on Divorce Rate







    

Notes: Panel (a) shows the evolution of the predicted share of Full-time Schools seats in a municipality
after its first expansion of the Full-time Schools program. Panel (b) shows the estimated eects of the
availability of Full-time Schools on divorce rates. All estimates are obtained using the de Chaisemartin
and d’Haultfoeuille (2020)’s estimator and include municipality fi x ed eects, academic year fixed eects,
and municipality-specific linear time trends. Standard errors for confide nc e intervals are clustered at the
municipality level and bootstrapped based on 1,000 repetit i on s.
26
Figure 3: Bacon Decompositi on : Eects on Female Employment
(a) Overall






    




(b) Municipali t i es with Low Female Employment





    




(c) Municipalit i es with High Female Employment





    




Notes: Panel (a) shows the resu l t s of a decomposition of the eect of the availability of Full-time Schools
on female employment considering all municipalities. Panel (b) and (c), present estimates for municipalities
with fem ale employment below and above the median in 2000, respectively. Estimates are obtained using
the method developed by Goodman-Bacon (2021) . In each panel, the das he d line shows the ATT from the
TWFE estimation and each triangl e corresponds to a dierent 2x2 TWF E estimate (treated in 2010 or 2015
versus never treated).
27
Figure 4: Alternative Estimation M et hods for the Eects of Full-time Schools on Divorce Rate
(a) OLS-TWFE







    

(b) de Chaisemartin and D’Haultfœuille (2020)







    

(c) Borusyak et al. (2021)







    

(d) Sun and Abraham (2021)







    

Notes: All estimates include municipality fixed eects, academic year fixed eects, and municipality-specific time trends. St an dar d errors for confidence
intervals are clustered at the municipality level. Coecients and confidence intervals in panels (a) through (d) are estimated using the Stat a commands
reghdfe, did multiplegt, did imputation, and eventstu dy in teract, respectively, and are plotted using the event plot command.
28
Figure 5: Eects on Migration






    

Notes: Estimated eects on the share of divorces in a municipality and academic year in which the munici-
pality of marriage is dierent from the municipality of residence of the wife relative to the overall number of
divorces in the municipality of residence. Estimates come from a single regression that includes municipality
fixed eects, academic year fixed eects, and municipality-specific linear time trends, and are es ti m ate d
using the de Chaisemartin and d’Haultfoeuille (2020)’s method. Standard errors for confidence intervals are
clustered at the municipality level and bootstrapped based on 1,000 repetitions.
29
Table 1: Descript i ve Statistic s by Treatment Intensity
Ever Treated Never Treated Dierence
Mean Std Dev Mean Std Dev
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Divorce Rate (pre-intervention) 0.258 (0.359) 0.123 (0.262) -0.135***
Municipality with High (pre-2008) Di vorce Rate 0.583 (0.493) 0.306 (0.461) -0.277***
Femal e Labor Force Participation (2000) 0.265 (0.108) 0.266 (0.133) 0.000
Municipality with High FLFP (2000) 0.509 (0.500) 0.477 (0.500) -0.033***
Population (in 1,000) 41.788 (112.352) 7.964 (11.185) -33.825***
Municipality with Unilateral Divorce Law 0.454 (0.498) 0.344 (0.475) -0.110***
Notes: The table shows descriptive statistics at the municipality level. Divorce rates are reported for 2000-
2007, prior implementation of the Full-time Schools Program. Municipality with High (pre-2008) Divorce
Rate is an indicator equal to one if the municipality divorce rate in 2000-2007 is above t h e cross-municipalities
median. Female employment is reported for 2000. Municipality with High female employment (2000) is an
indicator equal to one if the municipality female employment in 2000 is above the cross-municipalities median.
Municipality with Unilateral Divorce Law is an indicator equal to one if the municipality is l ocat e d in a State
that passed unilateral divorce l aws by 2016. Never Treated are municipalities that were not covered by the
FTS program by 2016 (N=651). Ever Treated are municipalities that implemented the program by 2016
(N=1,527). Data sources: divorce data from INEGI; Population from CONAPO; and female employment
from 2000 Mexican Population Census (IPUMS). *, **, *** Signi fic ant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% l evels,
respectively.
30
Table 2: Estimated Eects on Divorce Rate by Pre-Intervention Divorce Rates
Overall Low Pre-2008 High Pre-200 8
Divorce Rates Divorce Rates
(1) (2) (3)
Initial Eect 0.013 0.013 0.016
(0.010) (0.010) (0.016)
Years After = 1 0.021
0.009 0.040
(0.012) (0.012) (0.021)
Years After = 2 0.047
⇤⇤⇤
0.022 0.075
⇤⇤⇤
(0.013) (0.015) (0.022)
Years After = 3 0.060
⇤⇤⇤
0.008 0.099
⇤⇤⇤
(0.019) (0.014) (0.031)
Years After = 4 0.076
⇤⇤⇤
0.024
0.122
⇤⇤⇤
(0.020) (0.014) (0.035)
Years After = 5 0.076
⇤⇤⇤
0.020 0.126
⇤⇤⇤
(0.024) (0.018) (0.043)
Years After = 6 0.105
⇤⇤⇤
0.025 0.177
⇤⇤⇤
(0.028) (0.022) (0.048)
Years After = 7 0.090
⇤⇤
0.016 0.172
⇤⇤⇤
(0.036) (0.028) (0.061)
Average Eect 0.046
⇤⇤⇤
0.015 0.077
⇤⇤⇤
(0.012) (0.010) (0.021)
Notes: All estimates in each column come from the same regression that includes municipality fixed eects,
academic year fixed eects, and municipality-specific linear time trends. All specifications are estimated using
the de Chaisemartin and d’Haultfoeuille (2020)’s est i mat or . Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at
the municipality level and bootstrapped based on 1,000 repetitions. Columns ( 2) and (3) show the estimated
eects of the availability of Full Time Schools on divorce rates for municipalities with pre- intervention divorce
rates below and above the cross-municipality median, respectively. *, **, *** Significant at the 10%, 5%,
and 1% levels, respectively.
31
Table 3: Estimated Eects on Divorce Rate by Pre-Intervention Female Employment
Overall Low Femal e High Female
Employment Employment
(1) (2) (3)
Initial Eect 0.013 0.012 0.014
(0.010) (0.013) (0.015)
Years After = 1 0.021
0.013 0.028
(0.012) (0.017) (0.018)
Years After = 2 0.047
⇤⇤⇤
0.022 0.071
⇤⇤⇤
(0.013) (0.018) (0.019)
Years After = 3 0.060
⇤⇤⇤
0.011 0.103
⇤⇤⇤
(0.019) (0.021) (0.029)
Years After = 4 0.076
⇤⇤⇤
0.015 0.128
⇤⇤⇤
(0.020) (0.026) (0.029)
Years After = 5 0.076
⇤⇤⇤
0.032 0.116
⇤⇤⇤
(0.024) (0.033) (0.036)
Years After = 6 0.105
⇤⇤⇤
0.049 0.151
⇤⇤⇤
(0.028) (0.033) (0.042)
Years After = 7 0.090
⇤⇤
0.020 0.154
⇤⇤⇤
(0.036) (0.047) (0.055)
Average Eect 0.046
⇤⇤⇤
0.018 0.071
⇤⇤⇤
(0.012) (0.015) (0.018)
Notes: All e st i mat es from each column come from the same regression that includes municipality fixed eects,
academic year fixed eects, and municipality-specific linear time trends. All specifications are estimated using
the de Chaisemartin and d’Haultfoeuille (2020)’s est i mat or . Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at
the municipality level and bootstrapped based on 1,000 repetitions. Columns ( 2) and (3) show the estimated
eects of the availability of Full Time Schools on divorce r at es for municipalities with female employment
below and above the median in 2000, respec t i vely. *, **, *** Significant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels,
respectively.
32
Table 4: Estimated Eects on Female Employment - Census Data
(1) (2) (3)
Overall Low Female High Female
Employment Employment
Full Time Schools availability 0.018*** 0.004 0.036***
(0.003) (0.003) (0.005)
N6,5283,2643,262
Municipality FE yes yes yes
Year FE yes yes yes
Baseline Female Employment:
All Ever Treated Municipalities 0.266
(0.107)
Ever Treated Mun i ci pal i t i es with Low Female Employment 0.195
(0.066)
Ever Treated Mu n i ci p a l i t i es with High Female Employment 0.336
(0.092)
Notes: Each column represents a dierent regress i on. All estimations include year and municipality fixed
eects. FTS is an indicator for the presence of Full Time Schools in the municipality. Standard errors
in parentheses are clustered at the municipality level. Information from IPUMS for years: 2000, 2010, and
2015. Baseline female employment is reported for Treated Municipalities in each group prior implementation
of the Full Time S cho ol s Program.
*, **, *** Significant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
33
Appendix A Additional Results
Figure A.1: Estimated E ec t s on Divorce Rate- Controlling for Unilateral Divorce Laws
(a) OLS -TWFE controlling for unilateral divorce laws







    

(b) Borusyak et al. (2021)’s estimator







    

Notes: Panel (a) shows the estimated eects using TWFE-OLS regression incorporating an indicator for
the implementation of unilateral divorce laws. In Panel (b), we control for the implementation of u n il at e ral
divorce laws using the imputation estimator developed by Borusyak et al. (2021). All estimates from each
panel come from the same regression that includes municipality fixed eects, academic year fixed eects,
and municipality-specific linear time trends. Standard errors for confide nc e intervals are clustered at the
municipality level and bootstrapped based on 1,000 repetit i on s.
34