Repatriation Taxes
Chadwick C. Curtis
University of Richmond
Julio Gar´ın
Claremont McKenna College
M. Saif Mehkari
§
University of Richmond
This Draft: April 1, 2019
Abstract
We present a model of a multinational firm to quantify the effects of policy changes
in repatriation tax rates. The framework captures the dynamic responses of the firm
from the time a policy change is anticipated through its enactment, including its long-
run effects. We find that failing to account for anticipatory behavior surrounding a
reduction in repatriation tax rates overstates the amount of profits repatriated from
abroad and underestimates tax revenue losses. We further show that policy changes
have a relatively small impact on hiring and investment decisions if firms have relatively
easy access to credit markets as is the case for most multinational firms. Finally,
by altering the relative price of holding assets abroad, news of a future reduction in
repatriation tax rates acts as an implicit tax on repatriating funds today. We capture
and quantify this “shadow tax.”
JEL Classification: F23; H25; E60.
Keywords: Tax Reform, Repatriation Taxes, Asset Holding, Corporate Tax.
We are grateful to David Agrawal, Juan Dubra, David Garraty, Erik Johnson, Marios Karabarbounis,
Rob Lester, Johannes Voget, Dave Wildasin, Ahmed Rahman, Mike Pries, Tim Hamilton, and seminar
participants at UC Santa Cruz, Banco Central del Uruguay, Bowdoin College, Federal Reserve Board, In-
ternational Monetary Fund, Instituto de Econom´ıa-FCEA, University of Alabama, Universidad Cat´olica del
Uruguay, University of Kentucky, University of Mississippi, the University of Notre Dame, University of
Richmond, dECON Facultad de Ciencias Sociales UDELAR, the 2018 Asian Meeting of the Econometric
Society, the 23rd Latin American Meeting of the Econometric Society, Virginia Association of Economists
Meeting, International Trade and Finance Association Meeting, Southern Economic Association Meetings,
Liberal Arts Macro Workshop, Asian Meetings of the Econometric Society, Georgetown Center for Economic
Research Conference, the North American Summer Meetings of the Econometric Society, and St. Louis Fed.
Previous versions of the paper circulated as “Uncertain Taxes and the Quantitative Effects of Repatriation
Tax Proposals.”
E-mail address: [email protected].
Corresponding Author: [email protected].
§
E-mail address: smehk[email protected].
1 Introduction
Prior to 2018, the U.S. government collected taxes on the worldwide profits of U.S. based
corporations. In addition to paying foreign taxes on profits earned abroad, corporations were
often also subject to U.S. taxes once these profits were repatriated to the U.S. This is known
as the repatriation tax. Many firms argued that these additional repatriation taxes deterred
them from repatriating foreign sourced income. Leading up to the enactment of U.S. tax
reforms in 2018, these foreign profits, not yet taxed by the U.S. government, stood at over $2
trillion. This large accumulation of assets abroad pushed changing repatriation tax policies
high on the legislative agenda. Motivated by long and ongoing policy discussions, as well
as past and recent repatriation tax policy reforms, we build a dynamic model to quantify
the effects of repatriation tax policy changes on firm-level variables and to understand the
mechanisms driving those responses. Can tax reforms lead to an increase in repatriated
assets? Do these reforms stimulate employment and investment? What are the associated
tax revenue costs? How are the costs and benefits of a reform influenced by protracted
legislative deliberations and policy uncertainty? The goal of this paper is to shed light on
these questions.
While the economic and tax revenue consequences of reforming repatriation tax policy are
potentially large and involve a non-trivial dynamic aspect, the literature, for the most part,
has abstracted from studying the dynamic behavior of the firm that accounts for expectations
of changes in repatriation tax policy. To the best of our knowledge, this paper presents the
first quantitative framework capturing the dynamic impacts of repatriation tax changes that
includes the anticipation effects of such reforms.
We find that accounting for the anticipatory behavior of a firm, along with the responses
after the policy change, is essential to fully understand the effects of repatriation tax policy
changes. In our model, firms respond to news of a repatriation tax policy change in advance
of the actual policy change. Conceptually, we consider news as any information that alters
the likelihood of future repatriation tax changes such as a policy proposal, the deliberation of
a policy, or the legislative lag. Receiving news of a potential future reduction in repatriation
tax rates leads to a reduction of repatriated income from abroad, an accumulation of foreign
assets untaxed by the U.S. government, and a fall in U.S. government tax revenue. At the
enactment of a repatriation tax policy change, firms repatriate back the assets withheld
during this news period the period between the arrival of news and the policy change.
As in our baseline experiment, modeled after the temporary repatriation tax reduction in
2004-2005, firms additionally bring forward the repatriation of assets that were planned to
be remitted at a future date to the time of the policy change, causing repatriations to once
1
again fall after the implementation of the policy. As a result, policy evaluations that do not
account for a firm’s anticipation of lower future repatriation tax rates overstate the amount
of income repatriated from abroad and the effects on labor and capital, while they understate
the losses in tax revenue.
One of the primary motivations for reforming repatriation tax policy is to incentivize firms
to repatriate assets to the U.S., thereby stimulating domestic employment and investment.
We find that the effects of a reduction in the repatriation tax rate on U.S. employment and
investment crucially depend on the firm’s ability to access external credit markets. When
the cost of accessing credit is high, the firm is more dependent on internal funds to support
production activities. For such a firm, a contraction in repatriations during the news period
corresponds with a large contraction in its U.S. production, and the influx of foreign income
at the time of the policy change leads to a sizable expansion of domestic activity. Since
most multinational firms are large and relatively unconstrained in their access to credit, our
analysis indicates that a repatriation tax rate reduction has a relatively minor impact on
domestic employment and investment. Firms that are not credit constrained are able to
operate close to their optimal scale independent of whether or not they access their foreign
assets. Thus, while a policy change may result in a large inflow of foreign assets, this change
in asset flows does not affect production but primarily affects the firm’s debt position and
shareholder payouts.
Our model consists of a firm that is incorporated in the U.S., but operates and holds
assets both domestically and abroad, with the objective of maximizing dividend streams
paid to U.S. shareholders. Within each country, the firm decides on the levels of capital and
labor required for production, its holdings of liquid financial assets, and the amount of debt
to carry in the U.S. Across geographies, profits originating from abroad and repatriated back
to its U.S. parent are subject to a repatriation tax levied by the U.S. government. Thus,
repatriation taxes play a key role in the across-geography allocation decision. We use this
framework to quantify the impact of repatriation tax changes on the firm’s decisions within
and across geographies.
Our baseline experiment studies the effects of a temporary repatriation tax rate reduction
that is anticipated a year in advance of its implementation. While we consider a range of
repatriation tax policies, this experiment is motivated and disciplined by the American Jobs
Creation Act of 2004 (AJCA), which granted a one-time “tax holiday” on repatriated assets
in 2005. In our model, during the news period the firm reduces the rate of repatriations from
abroad and accumulates foreign assets to maximize its tax savings from the tax holiday. This
reduced flow of assets into the U.S. leads to a small contraction in domestic production and
to losses in U.S. tax revenue. At the enactment of the policy, the accumulated foreign assets
2
flow into the U.S.; the firm then uses the additional inflow of assets to primarily pay U.S.
shareholders, and reduce its debt.
We show that during the period between when a proposal is presented and its (potential)
approval, there is a change in the relative cost of repatriating funds. The period of delibera-
tion can be thought of as a wedge that distorts the firm’s decision relative to the status quo
without these announcements. We capture and quantify this wedge, generated by the news
itself, which we refer to as a “shadow tax.” By altering the intertemporal cost of repatriating
foreign assets, news of a future tax reduction has both an income effect higher expected
future disposable income induces the firm to repatriate income for dividend payments today
and a substitution effect repatriating funds today is relatively more expensive than in
the future.
Prior to 2018, repatriation rates were set as the larger of zero and the difference between
U.S. and foreign tax rates, and by 2017 the top marginal U.S. corporate income tax was
the highest among OECD countries. U.S. repatriation taxes were recently eliminated from
legislation under the Tax Cut and Jobs Act of 2017. However, calls for repatriation tax reform
preceded these reforms by many years. Following the enactment of the AJCA, bills were
introduced to congress nearly every year requesting temporary and/or permanent reductions
in repatriation tax rates. To study the effects of changes in expectations about repatriation
tax reforms that such protracted discussions may introduce, we additionally model news
with uncertainty surrounding when and if a repatriation tax change will occur. We show
that uncertainty in the timing of the policy change generates a ‘wait-and-see’ effect. If the
firm deems that future repatriation tax reform is likely but they are unsure when it will
occur, they steadily accumulate foreign asset holdings, which can persist over a long time
horizon. Even though the intent of the many proposals was to attract offshore assets held
by U.S. firms, the discussions of such proposals arguably had the opposite effect of inducing
firms to further accumulate assets abroad while they await a resolution of policy.
An innovation of our dynamic analysis is the inclusion of the anticipation, or new effects,
of repatriation tax reform. In this regard, we complement models analyzing the impacts of
repatriation taxes such as the static analysis of repatriation/investment decisions from an un-
certain arrival of a tax holiday of De Waegenaere and Sansing (2008), Altshuler and Grubert
(2003)’s theory of tradeoffs between investment and repatriation decisions of multinational
corporations, and the structural model of the relationship between firm-level cash holding
and repatriation tax rates in Gu (2017). In an influential paper, Hartman (1985) argues that
if tax rates on multinational firms were constant across time, the level of repatriation tax
rates would have no impact on the repatriation decisions of mature firms because these taxes
would be unavoidable. In our model, in the absence of an actual policy change, a reduction
3
in repatriations and an increase in the stock of foreign asset holdings only occurs if firms
expect a future repatriation tax reduction.
1
Spencer (2017) investigates the aggregate ef-
fects of a permanent repatriation tax reform. Our papers complement each other in that his
equilibrium environment can draw conclusions on the aggregate and welfare consequences of
permanent repatriation tax changes, whereas our paper focuses on the dynamics surrounding
reforms, including firm level responses to news of a reform. Moreover, our study provides
a richer firm-level environment which allow us to focus on portfolio allocation cross and
within country and study the mechanisms and adjustments occurring at the firm level.
Our contribution can also be viewed as a counterpart to the empirical literature looking
at the effects of repatriation tax policy change from the AJCA such as Dharmapala, Foley,
and Forbes (2011), Blouin and Krull (2009) and Faulkender and Petersen (2012). As external
validation of our model, we find that our policy experiments of a one-time repatriation tax
reduction capture the salient features found in these empirical studies.
2
Our paper follows the large literature on fiscal policy news shocks such as House and
Shapiro (2006), Yang (2005), Leeper, Richter, and Walker (2012), and Beaudry and Portier
(2007). We investigate a specific fiscal policy shock – repatriation tax changes – and evaluate
the tax revenue consequences and firm-level responses to the shock across a set of variables.
In this regard, our analysis is closest to the news and uncertainty of future tax policy studied
in Mertens and Ravn (2011) and Stokey (2016). Stokey presents a model with tax uncertainty
that can generate an investment boom after the resolution of the policy. In that environment,
firms reduce investment in new projects and accumulate liquid assets as a ‘wait-and-see’
policy until the uncertainty is settled. We differ from Stokey in two ways. First, ours is
a quantitative study. This allows us to map some objects in our framework to the data.
Second, we allow for firms to access financial markets. Our framework generates similar
dynamics to Stokey but that behavior crucially depends on the firm’s ability to access credit
markets. In our model, allowing the firm to access external and internal financing dampens
the investment effects of news of a policy change. Specifically, in the news period, the
firm finances domestic operations with external financing while simultaneously accumulating
liquid assets abroad.
In the DSGE model of Mertens and Ravn (2011), the economy experiences a contraction
of output and investment in anticipation of a tax cut and then an expansion of these variables
1
Following this literature, we abstract from corporate inversions. We only consider the dynamic effects of
repatriation tax changes rather than long-term decisions of corporate headquarter relocation that, arguably,
may arguably arise from repatriation tax policy. See Gu (2017) for a model analyzing tax revenue estimates
from U.S. inversion law changes.
2
Further, to support our modeling strategy of accounting for policy news, we provide empirical and
narrative evidence suggesting that firms received and responded to information on the passage of the AJCA
prior to its introduction in Congress.
4
once the tax cut is implemented, regardless of whether it was anticipated or not. Whereas
firms in Mertens and Ravn (2011) adjust domestic inputs in response to a tax cut, our focus
on international firms provides an additional margin of adjustment. In our benchmark model,
responses to output and investment to either an anticipated or unanticipated reduction in
the repatriation tax rate are small due to the firm’s ability to borrow and alter asset flows
between domestic and foreign operations. This is consistent with the investment dynamics
found in the empirical literature of the most recent U.S. repatriation tax change under the
AJCA (Dharmapala, Foley, and Forbes, 2011; Faulkender and Petersen, 2012).
2 Model Economy
In this section, we present a dynamic model to capture the effects of changes in repatriation
tax policy. The model economy consists of a multinational firm that is owned by households
and a government that levies taxes on various income sources. The multinational firm is
incorporated in the U.S. but operates and holds assets both in the U.S. and overseas. The
firm faces corporate income taxes in both jurisdictions and repatriation taxes on any income
earned by its foreign operations that are remitted back to the U.S. Thus, a key decision for
the firm consists of a portfolio choice problem of optimally allocating assets between its U.S.
and foreign subsidiary. Since our focus is primarily on how a firm internally reallocates its
assets in response to repatriation tax changes, we do not model the debt vs. equity choice
for external financing. Instead, we assume that the firm only has direct access to one type
of external financing debt.
3
2.1 Firm
The multinational firm’s objective is to maximize the present discounted value of the stream
of utility from dividend payments, d
t
, to its infinitely lived shareholders. The firm’s objective
function is
E
0
"
X
t=0
β
t
U((1 τ
d
)d
t
)
#
where τ
d
is the capital gains tax on dividends, U(·) is the flow utility derived from the
after-tax dividend payments with U
0
(·) > 0, U
00
(·) 0, and β is the subjective discount
factor.
4
3
Furthermore, we focus on firms that already operate across geographies and focus instead on changes
in the scale of cross-border production activities.
4
The curvature in the utility function is important as it generates a motive to smooth dividend payments
over time rather than an erratic stream of payments. We could alternatively generate smooth dividends by
5
t
t+1
Observe the
repatriation tax
rate path, and
the technology
level (z)
Choose how
much to
transfer (T)
between
countries
Choose what fraction
of assets to allocate to
production/financial
assets (A
P
, A
B
)
Hire inputs
(K, L) and
produce
Pay dividends (d)
from gross returns on
production/financial
assets
Begin period
with asset
holdings
(AUS , AF)
End period
with asset
holdings
(A´US , F)
Figure 1: Timeline of Events
The firm enters each period with assets held in the U.S., A
US
, and abroad, A
F
. A
firm observes the current and expected time path of repatriation tax rates as well as the
exogenous total factor productivity level on its U.S. and the foreign subsidiary, z
US
and
z
F
, respectively. Within each period, the firm sequentially makes the following decisions
illustrated in Figure 1. i) First, the firm chooses how to allocate assets between production
and financial assets within each geographical location and decides its debt position. ii) Next,
using assets allocated to production, it hires labor, rents capital, and produces. iii) Finally,
the firm decides how many assets, T, to transfer between its U.S. and foreign operations and
pays dividends. Assets, A
0
US
and A
0
F
, are carried over into the next period. We continue by
formally introducing these decisions.
Within-Geography Asset Allocation Decision
Within each geography, the firm enters the period with internally held assets carried over
from the previous period and decides how to allocate its assets between productive activities
and holding them as interest bearing financial assets. In the U.S., firms can hold financial
assets (A
B
US
> 0) or supplement its assets by taking on debt (A
B
US
< 0). The firm faces a
portfolio allocation problem with the aims of maximizing after tax returns. Formally, the
firm’s intra-period decision for its U.S. based operations is
Π
US
= max
A
P
US
,A
B
US
R
P
US
+
1 + (1 τ
US
)r
B
A
B
US
(1)
subject to
having risk-neutral investors who are subject to dividend adjustment costs.
6
A
P
US
+ A
B
US
A
US
(2)
A
P
US
0 (3)
A
B
US
(, −∞) (4)
The first term in Equation (1) gives the post-tax returns from assets allocated to production;
the second term is the after-tax returns to financial assets (if A
B
US
> 0) or debt (if A
B
US
< 0),
with r
B
as the interest rate and τ
US
as the U.S. corporate income tax rate. We assume that
the interest rate on borrowed funds, r
B
, is a function of the firm’s global debt-asset ratio. If,
however, financial asset holdings are positive then the interest rate is given by r. Formally:
r
B
=
(
r + ψ
h
exp
|A
B
US
|
A
US
+
˜
A
F
1
i
if A
B
US
< 0
r if A
B
US
0
(5)
where ψ > 0 is the elasticity parameter of debt. This debt-elastic interest rate allows
the firm to leverage its total (U.S. plus foreign) asset holdings to reduce domestic debt
costs. Including a debt-elastic interest rate serves two purposes. First, it ensures there is no
arbitrage opportunity as the firm always faces a debt-elastic interest rate of borrowing that
is higher than the returns it gets on financial assets. Second, it induces stationarity in this
type of model when interest rates are exogenous. Without this, the model’s steady state
depends on the initial debt position and the dynamics feature a random walk component.
5
The firm’s foreign subsidiary faces a nearly identical problem of allocating assets to
maximize gross returns net of the corporate taxes abroad. The only difference is, for clarity
in the analysis, we assume the foreign subsidiary cannot take on debt, i.e. the debt decision
of our model firm is confined to the U.S.
6
The foreign intra-period decision is
Π
F
= max
A
P
F
,
˜
A
B
F
R
P
F
+ [1 + (1 τ
F
)r] A
B
F
(6)
subject to
A
P
F
+ A
B
F
A
F
(7)
A
P
F
0 (8)
A
B
F
0 (9)
5
See, for instance, Schmitt-Groh´e and Uribe (2003).
6
In the Online Appendix, we relax this assumption and show that results are robust to relaxing this
assumption.
7
where the variables are defined similarly as before, but with F subscripts denoting the
decision of the foreign subsidiary.
Production Decisions
Within each geographical location, the firm uses the assets it allocates to production to
hire labor, L, and rent capital, K. The firm’s aim is to maximize the profits of its production
units:
R
P
i
= max
K
i
,L
i
(1 τ
i
)
Y
i
wL
i
r
K
K
i
+ A
P
i
(10)
subject to:
Y
i
= e
z
i
K
α
i
L
η
i
(11)
A
P
i
wL
i
+ r
K
K
i
(12)
z
0
i
= (1 ρ
z
i
)¯z
i
+ ρ
z
i
z
i
+
z
i
(13)
z
i
N
0, (σ
z
i
)
2
(14)
where i = {US, F }, τ
i
is the country-specific corporate income tax rate, and Y
i
denotes
output. The parameters z
i
, α, and η represent the level of technology, capital share in
production, and labor share in production, respectively. Finally, w is the constant wage rate
and r
K
= r + δ is the capital rental rate with depreciation rate δ.
7
Repatriation and Dividend Decisions
At the end of the period, the firm simultaneously chooses how many assets to transfer
between foreign and U.S. operations, T , the amount of dividends paid to shareholders, and
the amount of assets to carry over to the next period. Consistent with U.S. regulations, all
dividend payments by domestically based corporations must be paid through the U.S. parent
company.
The repatriation tax rate, τ
R
, consists of two components and it is given by
τ
R
= τ +
R
(15)
where τ is the repatriation tax rate set by the U.S. government and
R
is a stochastic
component measuring firm-level idiosyncrasies that may impact the tax rate. Consistent
with the legal environment of U.S. corporations, the repatriation tax rate set by the U.S.
government, τ, is the greater of 0 and the U.S. corporate income tax rate less tax credits
7
The assumption of constant input prices greatly simplifies our analysis. Including positively-sloped
labor supply curves as in Bloom (2009) would dampen the labor responses which would not significantly
change our main results.
8
for taxes paid to the foreign country on overseas earnings, τ = max{0, τ
US
τ
F
}. The firm-
level idiosyncratic component encompasses many firm-specific idiosyncrasies with respect to
the repatriation tax rate that we do not model, including special tax deductions, earnings
stripping, transfer pricing, R&D credits, income loss deductions, etc.
8
If the firm transfers assets from overseas to the U.S. (T > 0), it must pay repatriation
taxes which results in a net transfer of (1 τ
R
)T . However, if the transfer is from the U.S.
to overseas (T < 0), then there are no repatriation taxes due and the full amount T is
transferred abroad. This one-sided repatriation tax friction is consistent with: i) prior to
2018, on average U.S. corporate tax rates were higher than those abroad, and thus tax credits
overseas left transfers from the U.S. untaxed, and ii) many countries have a territorial tax
system whereby income earned abroad by domestic firms are not subject to domestic taxes.
9
Given the asymmetry of taxation on transferring assets across geographies, the stock of
assets carried over to the next period are
A
0
US
= Π
US
d +
e
T (16)
A
0
F
= Π
F
T (17)
where
e
T =
(
(1 τ
R
)T if T 0
T if T < 0
(18)
While the production-side profit maximization problem is a static one, the dividend
decision is dynamic. The multinational firm’s ultimate objective is to maximize the present
value of the stream of utility derived from dividend payments to its shareholders. The
problem can be written recursively:
V (A
US
, A
F
, τ, z
US
, z
F
) =
max
A
0
US
,A
0
F
,T,d
U((1 τ
d
)d) + βE [V (A
0
US
, A
0
F
, τ
0
, z
0
US
, z
0
F
,
0
R
) |τ, z
US
, z
F
,
R
] (19)
subject to (1)–(18).
8
The sources of heterogeneity are thus generated by idiosyncratic shocks
R
,
z
U S
, and
z
F
rather than,
say, industry competition.
9
For instance, leading up to 2018 the top U.S. marginal corporate income tax was the highest among
OECD countries, and in 2011, over 75 percent of OECD countries had a territorial tax system (Matheson,
Perry, and Veung, 2013).
9
3 Calibration and the Stochastic Steady State
This section first explains how we discipline the model’s parameters. It then describes some
of the model’s primary mechanisms by highlighting its properties in the stochastic steady
state.
3.1 Calibration
We parameterize the model so it matches moments of economic aggregates, country-specific
tax rates, and firm-level data for U.S.-based multinationals. The calibration characterizes the
model in the stochastic steady state where the time period is one quarter. We specify values
for 19 parameters. We begin by assigning preference parameters, common technological
parameters, and parameter values informed by U.S. aggregates. Of the remaining values, 5
are tax parameters and 8 are jointly calibrated.
We assume preferences are logarithmic
10
and the subjective discount factor is β = 0.993.
11
For simplicity, we set the common firm-level parameters to be the same across the two
countries. Since the ratio of labor to capital share in U.S. data is approximately 2, the labor
share, η, is set at 0.5, while the capital share, α, is set at 0.25. This gives an average marginal
cost markup of 33 percent.
The real interest rate on financial assets is set to match the quarterly real interest rate
on the 10 year U.S. T-bond for the period 2000Q1–2014Q4, r = 0.0045 (0.018 annually).
We calculate this as r =
1+i
T bond
1+E[π]
1 where the expected inflation rate, E[π], is the average
inflation in the previous 4 quarters based on the PCE core price index. The capital rental
rate is set as the real interest rate plus depreciation. Letting depreciation δ = 0.02, r
K
=
r + δ = 0.0245.
We are then left with 13 parameters that are more specific to our model economy, which
are set to match relevant moments in the data. These are shown in Table 1.
The values chosen for tax parameters in the model come from four sources: U.S. and
foreign corporate income taxes, taxes paid by households on dividends, and repatriation
taxes. The tax rate on dividends is set to τ
d
= 0.15. This is the U.S. capital gains tax on
long-term assets of the highest 4 tax income brackets in the 2010s (post 2003).
The remaining tax parameters are set to match firm-level data of U.S. multinationals.
We construct firm-level data by matching firm and year specific U.S. marginal corporate
income tax rates from Graham (1996) with corresponding observations in the Compustat
10
In the Online Appendix we perform sensitivity analysis on σ, including the case with linear utility
(σ = 0).
11
This implies a steady state interest rate on debt of 2.06 percent per year in our model.
10
Table 1: Parameter Values
Moments Data Model Parameter
Tax parameters
U.S. marginal corporate income tax rate 0.302 0.302 τ
US
= 0.302
Ave. foreign corporate income tax rate 0.171 0.171 τ
F
= 0.171
U.S. capital gains/dividends tax rate 0.15 0.15 τ
D
= 0.15
Ave. U.S. repatriation tax rate 0.131 0.131 τ = τ
US
τ
F
= 0.131
Across period variation in firm-level repatriation tax rates ±0.032 ±0.032
R
U(0.032, 0.032)
Jointly calibrated to firm-level multinational data
Debt to net asset ratio 0.32 0.32 ψ = 0.0009
Ave. number of employees (thousands) 10.22 10.22 w = 0.588
Foreign generated share of total income 0.41 0.41 z
F
= 0.095 (z
US
= 0)
Persistence of U.S. real income 0.76 0.76 ρ
z
US
= 0.889
Persistence of Foreign real income 0.66 0.66 ρ
z
F
= 0.705
Standard deviation of real U.S. output 0.104 0.104 σ
z
US
= 0.019
Standard deviation of real Foreign output 0.105 0.105 σ
z
F
= 0.026
Industrial Database.
12
We restrict our sample to the 2006–2013 period to avoid having the
tax policy changes from the AJCA affecting our estimate of repatriation tax rates absent a
temporary policy change. We further restrict our sample to firm-year entries with positive
foreign and domestic sales and positive foreign taxes.
For a firm i at time t we calculate the repatriation tax rate in the firm-level data as the
maximum of 0 and the difference between the marginal U.S. corporate income tax rate and
the average foreign corporate income tax rate.
13
For firms that face a positive repatriation
tax rate, that is
Repatriation T ax Rate
i,t
=
US Marginal T ax
i,t
F oreign Income T ax
i,t
F oreign P retax Income
i,t
.
The average repatriation tax rate in our sample is τ = 0.131. This value is similar to van’t
Riet and Lejour (2014) who estimate the U.S. repatriation tax rate to be between 14.6 and
16.7 percent. Further, splitting up the components of the repatriation tax rate, we have the
average U.S. marginal tax as τ
US
= 0.302 and the mean foreign corporate income tax rate
as τ
F
= 0.171.
Repatriation tax rates by firms in our sample are quite variable from one period to the
next. This may be due to various idiosyncrasies such as tax deductions from losses, various
tax credits, changes in a firm’s marginal tax bracket, and other factors affecting tax rates.
12
The marginal tax rate data is updated through 2013. These tax rates are reported after accounting for
interest deductions and accounts for the dynamics of the tax code such as net operating loss carry forwards
and back, alternative minimum taxes, and investment tax credits.
13
We argue this is an appropriate measure of the repatriation tax because the U.S. tax obligations are
determined by the worldwide averaging of the foreign tax rate. It is also important to note that this may not
necessarily be the repatriation tax rate firms effectively pay (they may choose to not repatriate any income,
for example), but an estimate of the tax rate they would pay if they were to repatriate foreign income.
11
We capture such idiosyncrasies in our model with the stochastic variable
R
. To parameterize
the distribution of
R
, we first assume it to be uniformly distributed. We then calculate the
difference of the 2
nd
highest and 2
nd
lowest repatriation tax rate for the 2006–2013 period
and divide it by each firm’s average repatriation tax rate in this interval.
14
The median value
across firms is 0.489. This gives the bounds on of ±0.032 (0.064/0.131 = 0.489). Formally,
τ
R
= 0.131 +
R
with
R
U(0.032, 0.032).
The remaining parameters are jointly calibrated to match firm-level cross-sectional and
time-series moments. We again draw upon the firm-level data used in calculating the tax
rate parameters above. Our approach is to discipline the technology shock processes at the
firm level. This requires a longer time-series, so we expand the sample to include 1990–2013.
To maintain consistency with the firms used in the sample to calculate tax rates, a firm again
must have positive U.S. and foreign sales and have a calculated repatriation tax rate. After
this selection, firms must have at least 15 observations. We then calculate real U.S. and
foreign income by firm, deflating the observations by the GDP deflator. Finally, we restrict
observations to have less than an absolute value of 25% change in real income from one-year
to the next to avoid relatively large outliers in our estimation.
Unfortunately, the Compustat data does not separate use of labor and capital by location,
so we infer the model technology processes in the U.S. and abroad by matching moments
of foreign and domestic income. We normalize the technology level in the U.S. to z
US
= 0
(e
z
US
= 1) and z
F
= 0.095 is calibrated to match the median share of foreign to total
income, 0.43. To find the persistence and standard deviation of the AR(1) shock processes,
we first separately normalize the U.S. and foreign firm-year income observations by the
average income in the sample. To remove the trend components and aggregate shocks from
our income series, for each firm and location U.S. and abroad we regress a firm-specific
time trend and a year dummy on (normalized) income. We then subtract the predicted from
the observed values to retrieve a stationary firm-level income series. Using this, ρ
z
US
= 0.889
and ρ
z
F
= 0.705 are calibrated to match the median of firm-specific autocorrelations in the
model with the median firm-level income autocorrelations in the data, being 0.76 and 0.66
respectively. We then calibrate the standard deviations of the technology shock processes
in the model as σ
z
US
= 0.019 and σ
z
F
= 0.026 which matches the corresponding median
firm-specific moments the model with the median firm-level standard deviation of income in
the data.
15
Finally, the parameter regulating the elasticity of the interest rate with respect to debt,
14
In this calculation, we require each firm to have 8 continuous observations. We do not use the highest
and lowest observations to avoid potential outliers in our calculations.
15
The model is quarterly while the Compustat data is annual, so we convert the standard deviations to
a quarterly frequency.
12
ψ, is calibrated to match the mean ratio of debt to net assets minus debt, 0.32. We finish
by calibrating w = 0.588 which equates the median firm size in the model, defined as the
number of employees, with that in the data 10.22 (thousands in the data).
Because of the importance of capturing the non-linearities of the firm’s problem, we rely
on global solution methods. The Appendix discusses the solution method in detail.
3.2 Model in the Steady State
Many of the key insights emerging from our quantitative exercise are best understood by
looking into the steady state properties of the model. Here, we first highlight the impact of
repatriation taxes on asset allocation decisions. We show that foreign liquid asset holdings are
growing in the level of the repatriation tax rate, quantitatively matching previous empirical
findings. We then explore the role of asset holdings on firm-level production decisions which
provides a basis for understanding our dynamic exercises.
3.2.1 Repatriation Tax Rates and Foreign Assets
Many policymakers voiced concern that high repatriation tax rates encouraged firms to hold
onto foreign earnings particularly liquid assets as a vehicle for tax avoidance. Foley,
Hartzell, Titman, and Twite (2007) (henceforth FHTT) empirically document this relation-
ship and find that the amount of foreign liquid asset holdings by U.S. multinationals is
growing in the level of repatriation tax rates faced by the subsidiaries. Here, we compare
this empirical relationship in FHTT with the quantitative implications of our model.
FHTT use confidential firm-level BEA data on foreign subsidiaries of U.S. multinationals
in 4 benchmark surveys from 1982–1999. Their measure of liquid asset holdings by foreign
subsidiaries is the natural log of liquid assets (referred to as “cash”) held abroad divided by
the firm’s net assets (total assets less foreign cash), ln
Cash
Net Assets
. They regress this on the
employment-weighted-effective repatriation tax rate and firm-level controls. This repatriation
tax rate measure is calculated the same way we estimate it in our calibration, except it is
additionally weighted by the share of employees in foreign subsidiaries to total employees
of the firm. The coefficient estimate on the employment-weighted-effective repatriation tax
rate in their specification is 6.83.
16
To obtain the model counterpart of this empirical estimate, we simulate the model econ-
omy at its stochastic steady state at various repatriation tax rates between 0.05 and 0.35,
i.e. τ {0.05, 0.1, ..., 0.35}.
17
For each tax rate, we simulate 200,000 firms. Consistent with
16
This coefficient is significant at the 5 percent level; see Table 5, Column 3 in Foley, Hartzell, Titman,
and Twite (2007).
17
0.35 is the highest repatriation tax rate a firm could face prior to the U.S. tax reforms in 2017.
13
0 0.05 0.1 0.15
Effective Repatriation Tax Rate (Employment Weighted)
-0.5
-0.4
-0.3
-0.2
-0.1
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
Estimate from Foley et al. (2007)
Model predicted values
Figure 2: Foreign Liquid Asset Holdings and Effective Repatriation Tax
Rates (Employment Weighted)
Notes: We follow the estimation in Foley, Hartzell, Titman, and Twite (2007), regressing foreign
ln
Cash
Net Assets
on the employment-weighted-effective repatriation tax rate and controls using our
simulated model data at the firm-level. The predicted values are generated by holding the control
variables at their conditional means. All values are centered at zero by subtracting the mean predicted
value. The slope of the dashed line follows the corresponding coefficient estimate in Foley, Hartzell,
Titman, and Twite (2007) (Table 5, Column 3).
FHTT we calculate, for each firm, the employment-weighted-effective repatriation tax rate.
We then regress ln
Cash
Net Assets
on the this weighted repatriation tax rate and the firm-level
controls used in FHTT.
18
Using the regression estimates from our simulated data, we generate predicted values
of ln
Cash
Net Assets
, holding the control variables at their conditional means. Figure 2 plots
the predicted values of ln
Cash
Net Assets
against the employment weighted repatriation tax rate
at evenly spaced intervals. In the figure, the predicted values are centered around zero by
subtracting the mean predicted value of ln
Cash
Net Assets
from each estimate. For comparison,
the dashed line follows the slope coefficient estimate in FHTT.
Given we did not target this empirical relationship, this exercise (in addition to exercises
in forthcoming sections) provides confidence in the external validity of our framework. More-
over, it also highlights an important channel through which repatriation taxes in the model
provide firms with a motive to hold financial assets abroad. In the model, the stochastic
18
There are three control variables in FHTT for which our model does not have a counterpart: dividend
dummy (due to concave utility, firms always pay dividends in our model), R&D expenditures, and investment.
Details on this regression are in the Online Appendix.
14
element in repatriation tax rates,
R
, induces firms to accumulate foreign financial assets
to await tax saving from a lower realization of
R
(therefore a lower τ
R
). Given positive
borrowing costs, when the underlying repatriation tax rate τ is high, the marginal utility of
shareholders from dividends is also relatively high. In this case, the marginal benefit of tax
saving from a lower realization of
R
is likewise high, leading firms to defer repatriations to
await such a realization. Additionally, recall that in the model foreign asset holdings reduce
domestic debt costs. Repatriation taxes thus induce firms to hold assets up to the point
where the marginal returns on after-tax repatriations equals the marginal cost of debt.
3.2.2 Asset Allocation and Production
Next, we look at the policy functions to understand the production and debt decisions
of the firm. We numerically solve for the policy functions for various levels of the debt-
elastic interest rate parameter ψ, holding firm-level productivity parameters, z
US
and z
F
,
and foreign asset holdings, A
F
, at their mean levels. We interpret ψ as the ease of access to
external credit markets. Figure 3 plots the policy functions for U.S. operations of internally
held assets, A
US
, against assets devoted to production, A
P
US
, financial asset holdings, A
B
US
,
and U.S. profits. Here A
B
US
< 0 indicates debt.
We let A
US
denote the level of productive assets when the returns to production equal
the interest rate offered by financial asset holdings.
19
When A
US
< A
US
the firm allocates
all of its internally held assets to production as these offer a relatively higher return. Once
A
US
A
US
, production is at its maximum scale and, because of diminishing returns to scale
in production, all assets A
US
> A
US
are held in interest bearing financial assets.
Looking first at the baseline parameterization of ψ, the total amount of assets devoted
to production is relatively unaffected by the amount of internally held assets A
US
. This
is because the firm may borrow to supplement its productive assets when the returns to
production exceed its borrowing costs (i.e. A
B
US
< 0 when A
US
< A
US
). Profits, although
growing in A
US
, are not substantially impacted by the level of internally held assets due to
the firm’s ability to access debt. Contrast this to the cases when it is more costly to access
external credit (or impossible when ψ = ).
20
When internally held assets A
US
< A
US
the
amount of assets devoted to production – and thus profits – are lower than the baseline case.
This is because it is more costly to supplement the shortfall in assets devoted to production
with debt.
These policy functions are instructive when understanding the model exercises of a re-
19
See Equation (20) in the Appendix for the solution to A
U S
.
20
We note that the policy functions of foreign operations mirror the policy functions shown here when
ψ = .
15
0
0
0
0
Figure 3: Policy Functions and Access to External Credit
duction in repatriation tax rates, which, we will see, lend to an influx of foreign assets and
hence an increase in A
US
. As our policy functions illustrate, even large changes in A
US
in
our baseline case will have relatively small impacts on assets devoted to U.S. production
and, by extension, use of capital and labor.
4 Quantitative analysis
This section presents our model dynamics from a temporary repatriation tax rate reduction
a tax holiday where the firm receives news of the policy change in advance. We then
compare our model predictions with the empirical findings on the effects of the tax holiday
around the American Jobs Creation Act of 2004. We show that the model is consistent
with this empirical literature and that it can account for a substantial share of the observed
repatriated assets before, during, and after the policy change. Following this, we examine the
importance of news, uncertainty, and access to external credit markets on firm-level behavior
stemming from a repatriation tax policy change.
16
4.1 Baseline Exercise
Our baseline experiment considers a tax holiday that reduces the repatriation tax rate faced
by multinational firms for one period from a steady state level of τ
H
to τ
L
. We further
assume that firms receive news of the tax holiday T periods in advance of its enactment.
This choice for the baseline tax policy is motivated by the American Jobs Creation Act of
2004 (AJCA), the only repatriation tax holiday in U.S. history. The AJCA contained several
tax incentives, including a one-time allowance for firms to bring back assets from abroad at
a reduced repatriation tax rate. For our baseline exercise, consistent with the AJCA, we
reduce repatriation tax rates for one-period from τ
H
= 0.131 to τ
L
= 0.0643.
21
In this exercise, the firm knows with certainty that a tax holiday will occur 4 periods
in advance of the actual tax holiday occurring, i.e. T = 4. Such policy lags are typical for
fiscal policy changes and are crucial to quantifying the full effects of a tax holiday. In our
subsequent discussion, we refer to these policy lags the periods between when the firm
begins anticipating a future tax holiday and when it is implemented as the news periods.
Figure 4 presents the responses to news of, and implementation of, a tax holiday per
our baseline policy. The plots are the average responses of the multinational firms that we
model, and there is not economy-wide aggregation. Throughout, panels and results labeled
as “U.S.” refer to the average responses to U.S. variables. Panel A gives the firm-level
responses and panel B gives the responses for the U.S. government’s tax revenue collected
from these firms. The units are percentage deviations from the original stochastic steady
state with the exception of the repatriation tax rate graph, which shows the actual time-
path for the repatriation tax rate. The tax holiday is implemented at period 0 and the firm
receives news of it 4 quarters in advance (period -4).
It is most instructive to discuss our results by dividing the effects of our baseline repa-
triation tax holiday into three separate sub-intervals: the news period (pre-realization, from
periods -4 to -1), the period of the tax holiday (at-realization, period 0), and the periods
thereafter (post-realization, period 1 onwards). On receiving news about an imminent future
tax holiday, during the news period the firm cuts back on repatriations from their foreign
subsidiary as they await more favorable repatriation tax rates. This leads to an accumu-
lation of financial assets abroad. In the U.S., the firm compensates for this reduction in
transfers by issuing debt. However, since borrowing is not costless, the U.S. operations are
21
Under the AJCA, firms were allowed a maximum tax rate on overseas earnings of 5.25 percent on 85
percent of repatriated funds. The remaining 15 percent of funds faced their ‘normal’ repatriation tax rate,
0.131. The average repatriation tax rate on our model firms in the tax holiday is thus 0.85 × 0.0525 +
0.15 × 0.131 = 0.0643. Kleinbard and Driessen (2008) note that additional tax credits toward the effective
tax rate on funds receiving tax breaks under the AJCA was 3.65 percent rather than 5.25 percent. Since we
do not explicitly model additional foreign tax credits, we use the 5.25 percent rate in our calculation.
17
-4 0 4
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
Repatriation tax rate
-4 0 4
0
200
400
Repatriations
-4 0 4
-100
0
100
200
Foreign financial assets
-4 0 4
-100
-50
0
50
U.S. debt
-4 0 4
-5
0
5
Dividends
-4 0 4
-1
0
1
U.S. labor and capital
-4 0 4
-1
0
1
U.S. output
-4 0 4
0
0.5
1
Firm value (V)
-4 0 4
-20
0
20
All sources
-4 0 4
-100
0
100
200
Repatriations
-4 0 4
-1
0
1
Corporate income
-4 0 4
-5
0
5
Dividends
Panel A: Firm-level responses
Panel B: US tax revenue by source
Figure 4: Responses to an Announced Temporary Reduction in Repatriation Taxes
Notes: News of tax reduction is received 4 quarters in advance. Except for the repatriation tax rate, units are in percent
deviation from initial steady state.
unable to fully make up for the entire fall in assets and thus have to cut back on dividend
payments and assets devoted to production. The fall in U.S. capital and labor is quite small
at approximately 3/10 of 1 percent.
In the period of implementation, the firm takes advantage of the one-time tax holiday
and repatriates a large amount of foreign assets to the U.S. The amount of repatriated assets
contains not only the financial assets the firm accumulated abroad during the news period,
but to take maximum benefit of the tax holiday the firm also brings forward planned future
transfers to the period of implementation. The U.S. operations then use this large inflow of
funds from abroad to pay higher dividends, reduce debt, and increase production.
After the tax holiday period, the firm reduces transfers and reaccumulates assets abroad
toward returning to their steady state level. In the U.S., the firm uses the large influx of
assets from the tax holiday period to temporarily sustain higher dividend payments, higher
production, and debt reduction.
Next, with respect to share value and dividend payments, the announcement of a tax
holiday signals a lower tax obligation in the future, which causes an instant increase in the
firm’s value at the time of the news. The value of the firm continues to rise within the
18
news period up to the realization period, after which it slowly returns to steady state as
the tax-savings from the tax holiday are eventually paid out as dividends. Further, during
the news period, even though dividends are cut back they are still positive. When the firm
foresees a future tax reduction, they accumulate foreign financial assets while simultaneously
issuing domestic debt to smooth out dividend payments. This behavior is consistent with
the observation that several companies (Apple Inc., Ford Motor Co., Caterpillar Inc., for
instance) have relied on bond issuance to finance dividend payments while simultaneously
amassing large sums of untaxed assets abroad.
On the U.S. government side, in Panel B, the collection of tax revenues on repatriated
assets, corporate income, and dividends mirror the transition path of their respective tax
sources.
22
The responses of tax revenues from corporate income and dividends are small
relative to that of transfers. Since the firm uses debt to smooth out U.S. production and
dividend payments, the magnitude of the impact from transfers is the primary force governing
the changes in tax revenues from all sources.
4.2 The American Jobs Creation Act of 2004
Our baseline calibration was informed by the actual tax rate reduction from the AJCA,
leading to a natural benchmark from which to judge the validity of our framework. Here we
compare our baseline results directly with the main findings from the empirical literature
that evaluates the impact of the AJCA.
23
Our model is able to explain key empirical findings
surrounding the AJCA. We also present suggestive evidence that firms both anticipated
and reacted to the tax holiday provision in the AJCA well before it was signed into law.
Furthermore, the effects of policy lasted for several quarters after the end of the tax holiday.
This evidence lends support to the importance of accounting for the full dynamics in any
analysis of repatriation tax policy reform.
It is estimated that under the AJCA tax holiday approximately $312 billion of qualified
earnings were repatriated to the U.S. (Redmiles, 2008). Figure 5 shows net repatriated
dividends from foreign subsidiaries to U.S. based parent companies as a share of foreign
corporate profits in the years around the AJCA. The shaded area is the effective period of the
tax holiday
24
and the horizontal line - at 15% is the average from 1995-2003. Net repatriated
22
Our model does not incorporate profit shifting attributing U.S. value added to foreign affiliates for
tax purposes (see Guvenen, Mataloni Jr, Rassier, and Ruhl (2017)). If our model included opportunities for
profit shifting, profit shifting could increase if firms anticipate a repatriation tax rate reduction. While this
would not affect real variables, it may amplify the responses to tax revenues.
23
A summary of this literature is in the Online Appendix. This literature, surprisingly, generally does
not consider the anticipatory effects of repatriation tax policy changes.
24
Due to misalignment of fiscal to calendar years, some firms were allowed tax breaks on repatriated
income extending into 2006Q1.
19
Figure 5: Transfers: Net Repatriations of U.S. Incorporated Companies
as a Share of Foreign Profits
Notes: Constructed using Balance of Payments data from the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis
dividends as a share of corporate profits had never exceeded 26% prior to the enactment of
the law, but reached 130% in the final quarter of the tax holiday before sharply falling below
its average level just following the repatriation tax holiday. The fall in repatriations after the
tax holiday was anticipated by policy makers. The Joint Committee on Taxation predicted
firms would shift repatriated earnings they would otherwise have repatriated in future years
to the tax-holiday period to get more favorable rates (Kleinbard and Driessen, 2008). This
is the same mechanism that causes repatriations to fall after the tax holiday in our model.
Despite the influx of liquidity during the tax holiday, the general consensus in the lit-
erature is that the AJCA’s objective of stimulating employment and investment were not
met. Dharmapala, Foley, and Forbes (2011) find that repatriations had no significant im-
pact on U.S. investment or employment, as did Clemons and Kinney (2008) with regards to
investment.
25
Faulkender and Petersen (2012) echo these findings and show that financially
unconstrained firms, which repatriated 73% of all qualified funds, did not alter domestic
employment or investment.
26
Additionally, under the AJCA, funds receiving tax breaks were prohibited from being
used for shareholder payouts (dividends and share buybacks). However, in an evaluation of
the proposed tax holiday released a year prior to the AJCA, a Congressional Research Service
report noted that due to the fungibility of internal funds, firms could channel the repatriated
25
Further, of the top 15 repatriating corporations, 10 actually reported a decrease in U.S. jobs from
2004-2007 (Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations, 2011).
26
However, Faulkender and Petersen (2012) also document that financially constrained firms did increase
investment, but still not employment, in response to the act. We return to this point in Section 4.5.
20
funds from a tax holiday to investment while switching domestic funds to shareholder payouts
(Brumbaugh, 2003). Studies on the AJCA have, in fact, found that the tax holiday was
associated with an increase in payments to shareholders (Blouin and Krull, 2009; Clemons
and Kinney, 2008). Dharmapala, Foley, and Forbes (2011) estimate that a $1 increase
in repatriation during the AJCA tax holiday corresponded with a $0.60–$0.92 increase in
shareholder payouts. In our model we can do a similar calculation. Relative to the steady
state, in the five-year window around the tax holiday (including the news period) in our
model, a $1 increase in after tax repatriations corresponds with a $0.74 increase in dividend
payouts. This is in the middle of the range found by Dharmapala, Foley, and Forbes (2011).
Studies on the impacts of the AJCA have primarily focused on its impact only at and
after its enactment. However, we argue that to correctly quantify the effects of the AJCA,
one must also account for any anticipatory effects that may have occurred, i.e. the impacts
during the news period. In the case of the AJCA, there were a series of earlier bills beginning
in February 2003 that did not pass through congress but contained the tax holiday provisions
that were later incorporated in the AJCA.
27
In the time leading up to the AJCA, there is evidence that these earlier bills did lead
to anticipation of the tax holiday. For example, in 2003 Lehman Brothers’ tax accounting
analyst Robert Wilkens indicated that legislation allowing companies to repatriate foreign
earnings was “gaining momentum” and was likely to be passed into law in early 2004 (Cor-
porate Financing Week, 2003). Other examples of anticipation of the tax holiday include
Simpson and Wells (2003) who discuss firms’ lobbying efforts for a tax holiday in 2003 citing
provisions that would eventually be enacted in the AJCA and Sullivan (2004) who question
if foreign income shifting in the years leading up through 2002 are related to tax holiday
proposals in congress. Oler, Shevlin, and Wilson (2007) find that in 2003, well before the
introduction and passage of the AJCA but when a future tax holiday seemed likely, stock
prices had started reflecting potential tax savings from a tax holiday. This is a result that is
mimicked by our model; stock prices rise in the news period in anticipation of a future tax
holiday (see Figure 4).
In our model, expectations of a reduction of repatriation tax costs lead firm to reduce
repatriations until the policy’s resolution. We find that the behavior of firms, in the period
before the AJCA, was consistent with that anticipatory effect. Returning to Figure 5, the
27
Lobbying efforts had long called for tax breaks on repatriated income, but the call for a tax holiday
gained legitimacy in February 2003 with the introduction of the Homeland Investment Act of 2003 to the
House of Representatives, the Invest in America Act of 2003 presented to the House in March, and the Invest
in the USA Act of 2003 introduced in the Senate in the same month. These bills included similar provisions
for the tax holiday included in the AJCA of 2004. Under the AJCA of 2004, 85 percent of repatriated
earnings would qualify for tax exemptions, the same as in the Invest in the USA Act of 2003. A later bill
introduced in November 2003, The American Jobs Creation Act of 2003, also contained similar language.
21
Table 2: Cumulative Percent Deviation from Average Net
Repatriations as a Share of Foreign Profits (Quarterly Rate)
Sub-Period
News Period AJCA Post-AJCA
(2003Q2-2004Q3) (2004Q4-2006Q1) (2006Q2-20017Q1)
Data -63.65 258.08 -53.43
Model -49.72 106.02 -61.89
notes: Figures are percent deviation of net repatriations as a share of foreign profits relative
to their average. In the data, this is the average from 1995Q1-2003Q1. In the model the
average is the steady state level of the corresponding measure. Figures are expressed as
quarterly rates.
vertical line in 2003Q1 marks the time the first bill leading up to the AJCA was introduced
(the Homeland Investment Act of 2003 ). The following quarter, net repatriated dividends
fell to their lowest point in the 13 year sample.
Table 2 compares our model findings with repatriation behavior in the data. We calculate
– in both the empirical and in the simulated data – the percent deviation of net repatriations
as a share of foreign profits from its average level. We then cumulate it into 3 sub-periods:
6 quarters of the news period beginning with the introduction of the Homeland Investment
Act of 2003, 6 quarters of the effective period of the AJCA, and 4 quarters after the policy.
All of the numbers are expressed as quarterly rates. For consistency in the comparison, we
rerun our baseline model but alter its timing to be consistent with the AJCA a 6 quarter
news period and a 6 quarter tax holiday.
Quantitatively, the model matches the data very closely in the news period and in the time
following the tax holiday. During the tax holiday, in both the data and model, repatriations
are significantly higher with the model capturing over 40 percent of this observed increase
during the AJCA. Overall, even though not constructed to explain the AJCA, our model is
able to account for various features of the data and the empirical results surrounding the
AJCA.
4.3 Discussion On General Equilibrium
While our focus is to understand the mechanisms driving within and cross-country asset
allocation of the firm in response to a change in repatriation taxes, before proceeding it
is important to note the limitations of our study when drawing aggregate implications.
Specifically, by lacking general equilibrium, our model economy does not capture indirect
effects that may occur via price adjustments and/or changes in resource allocation.
In our model, as firms adjust their demand for inputs in response to the policy change,
22
input prices would adjust from changes in economy-wide demand. Likely, these price adjust-
ments in factor inputs would also serve to dampen the responses to labor/capital and output
in comparison to the already relatively small responses in our baseline model. Moreover, in
general equilibrium the asset flows into the U.S. in response to a tax holiday would make
consumers wealthier – from an influx of dividends and/or higher factor payments – and result
in an increase in demand for goods and services. Again, we would argue changes in factor
payments due to repatriations would be relatively small, causing the income and demand
change from this channel to be small. Dividend payments in our model, on the other hand,
fall in anticipation of, and increase at the time of, the tax change. The total effects from this
channel would rely on how large the tax saving on dividends is and how large of a portion
dividend payments from multinational firms make up of total household income.
In the end, the aggregate responses would also depend on the extent to which wealth
effects are assumed in household preferences. What is clear, however, is that the aggregate
and welfare effects of repatriation taxes would necessitate a general equilibrium to be prop-
erly quantitatively evaluated. When we consider a permanent reduction in repatriation tax
rates, the general equilibrium effects would be more important to incorporate as there may
exist long-run efficiency gains following a permanent reduction in distortionary taxes.
28,29
Our framework, nevertheless, highlights important mechanisms at the firm level that are
consistent with the empirical literature that such a framework should capture.
4.4 News Effects
Policy analysis generally focuses on the effects of a repatriation tax policy change only at
and after its enactment. For example, assessments of the AJCA such as the Joint Committee
on Taxation (2004) estimated the tax holiday provision in the AJCA would result in $2.8
billion in revenue gains during the holiday and over $6 billion in losses over the next 9 years.
The news period was not included in the assessment of the AJCA. In this section, we show
that the responses in the news period are large and, to ensure an accurate assessment of
any policy change, the entire dynamics surrounding the policy change should be taken into
account.
Figure 6 reports the cumulative responses of a tax holiday for several variables of interest.
Each plot also subdivides the cumulative responses into three sub-periods: pre-realization,
at-realization, post-realization. Additionally, we also report just the post-news cumulative
28
See, for example, Spencer (2017) for a general equilibrium model with permanent repatriation tax
changes.
29
Section OA5 of the Online Appendix considers a permanent reduction in repatriation taxes (and a
further discussion of general equilibrium effects from this permanent change) as well as the permanent tax
reform from the Tax Cut and Jobs Act of 2017.
23
Repatriations
Pre At Post Post-news Total
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
Realization period Cumulative
U.S. labor and capital
Pre At Post Post-news Total
-0.005
0
0.005
0.01
0.015
0.02
Realization period Cumulative
U.S. repatriation tax revenue
Pre At Post Post-news Total
-3
-2
-1
0
1
2
3
Realization period Cumulative
U.S. tax revenue: all sources
Pre At Post Post-news Total
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
Realization period Cumulative
no news news period=1 news period=4 (baseline)
Figure 6: Cumulative Responses to a Tax Holiday
Notes: The cumulative effects are shown news periods for when there is no news period and when the news period is 1 and 4
quarters long. The figures subdivide the cumulative responses in the three realization periods: Pre-realization, At-realization,
and Post-realization. This also shows the Post-news cumulative (sum of At- and Post-realization periods) and the total response
(sum of all subperiods). Units are quarterly gain/losses to that variable relative to the steady state at the time of the news.
response (the sum of the at-realization and post-realization responses) to highlight the im-
plications of a policy analysis that focuses only on the responses at and after a policy change.
For the figure, the units are quarterly gains/losses to that variable relative to the steady state
at the time of the news. For example, a cumulative value of -1 to tax revenues indicates
that total tax revenue losses are equal to 1 quarter’s worth of steady state tax revenues.
We further show the results for three simulations differing in the length of the news period:
when there is no news period and when the news period is 1 and 4 quarters long.
Consider first the cumulative impacts in the baseline case, i.e. news period is equal to 4.
On net, repatriations fall in the news period, rise during the tax holiday, and fall thereafter. If
an assessment of the tax holiday on repatriations only considers the total effects at and after
its implementation, it shows a net gain of over 2 quarter’s worth of steady state repatriations.
When all periods are taken into account, including the news period, cumulative repatriations
are negligible: the policy change merely shifts the timing of transfers, which would have been
repatriated anyway, to the time of the tax holiday.
In the baseline case, there are cumulative gains to U.S. capital and labor. The total gains
to these variables are 1.3 percent of their quarterly steady state levels. If the news period
24
is not taken into account, these gains are overstated. On the government side, there are
net losses to U.S. tax revenues. However, looking at this set of firms, the tax holiday would
appear to be approximately revenue neutral if the news period were not taken into account.
Furthermore, we find that the longer the news period the larger the losses to U.S. tax
revenue. A longer news period allows the firm to take maximum advantage of the tax holiday
by holding back a large amount of assets during the news period and then repatriating a
large amount during the tax holiday. This larger repatriation in turn leads to an overall
larger cumulative gain in the U.S. capital and labor, but at the same time also leads to
a larger revenue loss by the government. Thus, there is a tradeoff between the length of
advanced notice and policy outcomes: a longer news period leads to higher cumulative gains
to employment but at the expense of larger tax revenue losses – although it should be noted
that the gains for labor and capital are quantitatively small while the losses in U.S. tax
revenue are relatively large. Put differently, if news periods are not taken into account
when analyzing the behavior of firms taking advantage of the tax holiday, policymakers may
overestimate the stimulative effects of the policy and underestimate the costs in terms of tax
revenue losses by multinational firms.
4.5 Access to External Credit Markets
In this section we show that the magnitude of the response in a firm’s production activities,
given by firm-level capital and labor, is highly dependent on the level of access they have to
external credit.
Figure 7 shows the cumulative impacts of a one-period tax holiday under various values of
the parameter governing the ease with which firms can access to credit markets, ψ. Each fig-
ure subdivides the responses into the pre-realization, at-realization, and the post-realization
periods. The cumulative response is the sum of the three sub-periods. Again, the units are
in quarterly gains/losses of that variable relative to the steady state. As in the baseline, the
temporary tax holiday reduces τ from 0.131 to 0.0642.
When the firm cannot access credit markets or the cost of borrowing is high, it relies
heavily on internal funds and thus the marginal value of an additional dollar in tax saving
from the upcoming tax holiday is high. Consequently, during the news period a credit
constrained firm aggressively cuts back transfers in order to take the maximum benefits of
the tax holiday. The curtailing of transfers, in combination with the lack of access to cheap
credit, causes U.S. labor and capital to fall much more during the news period than in the
baseline case. On the other hand, a firm that has access to less costly borrowing also reduces
transfers in order to take advantage of the tax holiday. However, because they can borrow to
25
offset this fall in transfers, there is little net effect on U.S. labor and capital for these firms
during the news period. In comparison, there are large fluctuations in labor and capital for
a credit-constrained firm at and after the tax holiday. These results are easy to understand
within the intuition provided by the policy functions shown in Section 3.2.2. In the presence
of low costs to external credit, firms are able to use debt to keep production close to its
optimal scale when internally held domestic assets (A
US
) fall due to the withholding of
transfers in the news period. Likewise, the scale of production is largely unchanged once the
policy change is implemented and foreign assets flow into the U.S. (A
US
increases).
The labor and capital responses from our baseline model follow the empirical literature of
the AJCA. The majority of the firms receiving tax benefits from the act were not financially
constrained and therefore did not alter the scale of their U.S. operations (Dharmapala, Foley,
and Forbes, 2011; Faulkender and Petersen, 2012). Our baseline results reinforce these
findings. However, Faulkender and Petersen find that a subset of firms that were financially
constrained at the time of the AJCA did increase investment (but not employment) because
of the act. When analyzing the periods at and after the tax holiday, our model likewise
predicts that financially constrained firms increase capital use after the holiday to a larger
degree than financially unconstrained firms.
In general, our analysis shows why the ability of a firm to borrow can be very important
when understanding the effects of future policy changes. For instance, Stokey (2016) shows
that tax uncertainty can generate an investment boon after the resolution of the uncertainty.
In her model, firms cannot borrow but can accumulate liquid assets. In the main exercise, a
Repatriations
Pre At Post Cumulative
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
U.S. capital and labor
Pre At Post Cumulative
-0.1
-0.05
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
No borrowing
=9 10
-2
=9 10
-4
(baseline) =9 10
-6
Figure 7: Cumulative Responses for Variations in Debt-Elastic Interest Rate Parameter, ψ
Notes: In the left panel a tax holiday is announced 4 periods in advance and in the right panel it is immediately and unexpectedly
implemented. The figures subdivide the cumulative responses in the three realization periods: Pre-realization, At-realization,
and Post-realization. The cumulative response is the sum of all subperiods. Units are quarterly gain/losses to that variable
relative to the initial steady state.
26
tax reform on revenue is announced that will be implemented at a known future date, but
the size of the tax rate change is uncertain. At the announcement of this future change, firms
reduce investment in new projects and accumulate liquid assets as a “wait and see” policy
until the uncertainty is resolved. When the tax reform is implemented, firms develop the
tabled projects and an upsurge in investment follows. Even though the exact characterization
of the tax reform and economy in Stokey (2016) differs from our model, we can generate
similar investment dynamics. In our model, however, a reduction in domestic capital usage in
the news period and an upswing at the implementation of the tax holiday crucially depends
on restricting a firm’s access to credit markets. When firms can freely access external credit,
the domestic operations are already operating close to their optimal scale and a repatriation
tax rate reduction, or news surrounding such tax changes, has a negligible impact on domestic
production.
4.6 Policy Uncertainty
In the baseline simulations, firm know with certainty that a repatriation tax holiday is going
to occur at a known future date. However, in reality the legislative process is ripe with
uncertainty firms are regularly uncertain about both if and when a policy being discussed
will be passed. In this section, we investigate the impacts of a tax holiday when there is
uncertainty in these dimensions.
4.6.1 When a Tax Holiday will Happen
Following the AJCA, firms steadily increased foreign asset holdings that were untaxed by
the U.S. government (Brennan, 2010). The AJCA was penned as a one-time event, but its
use as a stimulus measure may have altered expectations of the ability of policymakers to
enact a future repatriation tax holiday (Clausing, 2005; De Simone, Piotroski, and Tomy,
2017). Some have hypothesized that the accumulation of foreign assets after the AJCA was
due to expectations of another tax reduction at some point in the future (Levin and Coburn,
2011; Brennan, 2010). In our model, we find if the firm believes a tax holiday will occur but
is uncertain about when it will occur, they steadily accumulate assets abroad.
Suppose the model firm receives news that a repatriation tax rate reduction will happen
at an unknown date between the time of the news and a given time T in the future. Further,
in each time period the firm assigns an equal probability that the tax change will occur in
each remaining period through period T .
30
We set T = 20 and in Figure 8 plot the foreign
financial asset holdings during the news period. The size of the tax rate reduction is the
30
See the Online Appendix for a transition graph outlying this experiment.
27
-24 -22 -20 -18 -16 -14 -12 -10 -8 -6 -4
-20
0
20
40
60
80
100
120
140
160
% deviation from steady state
News
Figure 8: Response to Foreign Financial Assets to a Temporary Reduction in the Repatriation
Tax Rate When the Date of Implementation is Uncertain
Notes: The firm receives news that a tax holiday will occur in the next 20 quarters but are unsure of the arrival date. The tax
holiday is arbitrarily chosen to occur after 18 periods. The expectations in the timing of the tax holiday are uniform across all
remaining periods if the tax holiday has not yet occurred. The figure shows up to two periods before the tax holiday occurs to
highlight the accumulation of foreign financial assets prior to the holiday.
same as in the baseline. In these simulations, we arbitrarily let the implementation of the
tax reform to occur 18 quarters after receiving the news (t = 2). We do not show the
periods at and after the tax reductions to highlight the run up of foreign assets in the news
periods.
At the time of the news, the firm begins gradually accumulating foreign financial assets.
After 17 quarters, these asset holdings are nearly 150 percent higher than their steady state
level. Since the timing of the policy change is unknown, the firm accrues these assets to take
advantage of tax gains that will occur once the tax holiday is implemented in the future.
Our model suggests that there may be merit to the conjecture that firms began accumu-
lating assets abroad in anticipation of a future repatriation tax reduction after the AJCA.
This relates to De Simone, Piotroski, and Tomy (2017) who find that many multinational
firms accumulated foreign liquid assets in anticipation of a proposed, but failed, 2008 tax
holiday. Arguing that the AJCA changed expectations of the likelihood of similar policy
change, proposed legislation in 2008 for another tax holiday that never materialized may
have been a catalyst for many multinationals to accumulate assets abroad. In this regard,
our model suggests that at least part of the asset buildup abroad following the AJCA may not
be from a high steady state repatriation tax rate, but may be the direct result of discussions
and anticipation of a future repatriation tax rate reduction.
28
Repatriations
Pre At Post Cumulative
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
U.S. labor and capital
Pre At Post Cumulative
-0.01
-0.005
0
0.005
0.01
0.015
0.02
Baseline If (news materializes) If (news does not materialize)
Figure 9: Cumulative Responses When There is a 50 Percent Probability of the Tax Holiday
Occurring in 4 Quarters in Advance of the News
Notes: The figure shows the cases when the tax holiday does materialize and when it does not materialize along with the
baseline when the tax holiday occurs with certainty. The figures subdivide the cumulative responses in the three realization
periods: Pre-realization, At-realization, and Post-realization. The cumulative response is the sum of all sub-periods. Units are
quarterly gain/losses to that variable relative to the initial steady state.
4.6.2 If a Tax Holiday May Happen
Next, let us consider the case where the firm is unsure if a tax holiday will occur. In this
example, the firm receives news that in 4 quarters a one-period repatriation tax reduction
might occur. After 4 quarters of receiving the news, two outcomes are possible: the news
materializes whereby the repatriation tax rate is reduced as in the baseline, or the news
does not materialize and the firm realizes a tax holiday will not occur. In the following
simulations, the firm assigns a 50/50 likelihood of either outcome occurring.
Figure 9 shows the cumulative responses in each sub-period – pre, at, and post realization
and the sum of all periods. The cases of uncertainty of if the tax holiday will occur (and
if it does or not happen) are compared against the baseline where the tax holiday occurs
with certainty. If the news materializes, the firm repatriates additional funds by transferring
assets that would otherwise be repatriated in future periods to the time of the tax holiday.
In contrast, when the tax holiday does not occur the firm has no such motive. Instead,
they simply repatriate the funds they accumulated in the news period. Overall, if the firm
anticipates the possibility of a future tax holiday and it does not occur, the cumulative effects
are negligible. However, the mere prospect of a repatriation tax holiday disrupts the timing
of repatriation decisions.
29
4.7 Quantifying News and Uncertainty Effects: the Shadow Tax
The prospect of a future repatriation tax reduction allows firms to take advantage of the
tax holiday by holding assets abroad and reducing repatriations. Thus, news of a possible
repatriation tax reduction actually generates an implicit tax or shadow tax on repatriating
funds during the news period. In our model, we can measure this shadow tax as the subsidy
rate the government will have to pay the firm in the period of receiving the news to encourage
them to not hold back repatriations in this period, and keep them at the original steady state
level. That is, how much would the U.S. government have to subsidize transfers by to induce
the firm to keep their level of transfers unchanged in response to news of a tax holiday?
We calculate the shadow tax under various scenarios and show that this implicit tax
depends on both the length of the news period and the degree of certainty of if and/or
when a tax holiday will occur. In panel A of Table 3, the firm receives news of a one-time
repatriation tax holiday that may occur in exactly T quarters from the news. We consider
two cases: one in which there is a 50 percent probability the tax holiday will happen and the
other where the tax holiday will happen with certainty. If the tax holiday is implemented,
the repatriation tax rate reduction is the same as the baseline.
Our shadow tax measure quantifies the degree to which news of a repatriation tax reduc-
tion induces firms to accumulate foreign assets. It is growing in the likelihood of the passage
of a tax holiday and shrinking in the time until the realization of the news. The motive to
increase foreign asset holdings by reducing transfers at the time of the news is higher when
the passage of the tax holiday is likely and when firms have less time to amass these assets
in preparation for the possible tax holiday.
Table 3: Shadow Tax
Panel A: Certainty when news materializes Panel B: Uncertainty when news materializes
News material-
izes in T quar-
ters
P (if tax holiday)
News material-
izes within T
quarters
P (if tax holiday)
0.5 1 0.5 1
T = 1 2.67 5.49 T = 1 2.67 5.49
T = 2 2.08 4.58 T = 2 2.73 4.68
T = 3 1.47 3.61 T = 3 2.67 4.51
T = 4 0.90 1.95 T = 4 2.24 3.72
Notes: Units are in percent. The shadow tax is the subsidized rate on a firm’s repatriations at the time they receive news of a
potential tax holiday that would keep transfers constant at their original steady state level in that period. In panel A the firm knows
with certainty that a tax holiday will occur with a probability of 0.5 and 1 in exactly T periods. In panel B, the firm knows that a
tax holiday will occur with a probability of 0.5 and 1 at some period within T periods.
30
Turning next to panel B of Table 3, the firm receives news of a one-time repatriation tax
holiday that may occur with an unknown arrival date between the time of the news and T
quarters from the news. At each time period, the firm assigns an equal probability that the
tax change will occur in each of the remaining periods. We consider two cases, one where
there is a 50/50 chance the tax holiday will occur and one where the tax holiday will occur
with certainty. When T = 1, the exercises in panels A and B are identical. Comparing
pairwise with panel A for T > 1, the shadow tax with uncertainty in when the news will
materialize is always larger. When there is certainty that the arrival date is more than one
quarter out, the firm can wait to accumulate foreign assets right before the tax holiday. On
the other hand, when the firm is uncertain when the news will materialize, the motive of the
firm to accumulate foreign assets at the time of the news is larger as they prepare for the
chance the tax holiday may occur at any time.
In summary, news of a potential tax change is akin to levying an additional tax on
repatriated earnings in the periods leading up to the possible policy change. Our model shows
that, conditional on the probability that a repatriation tax holiday will occur, uncertainty
in the timing of when the tax holiday may be implemented increases the shadow tax on
repatriated foreign earnings. More generally, if discussions or proposals in congress alter the
probability distribution of the tax environment, then the news itself may act as an implicit
tax, with uncertainty about when the actual policy change will occur increasing this implicit
tax.
5 Conclusion
This paper presents a model of a multinational firm to understand how changes in repatria-
tion tax policy impact firm-level behavior. We discipline our framework with both aggregate
and firm-level data and use the American Jobs Creation Act of 2004 to test its external
validity. Our analysis serves to highlight the importance of understanding the dynamics
around, and timeliness in, resolving repatriation tax policy.
We find that a policy evaluation that does not account for firm-level behavior before the
policy change overestimates the benefits of reducing repatriation tax rates by overstating
both the gains to domestic production activity and the amount of assets transferred from
abroad and underestimates its costs by understating tax revenue losses. Additionally, the
length of the news period and policy uncertainty of when and if a tax change will occur
all have significant effects on the impact of a policy change. Furthermore, we show that
a firm’s access to external financing plays an important role in determining the impact of
repatriation tax changes on domestic activity. Firms that have low costs of accessing external
31
credit markets can operate at their efficient scale independent of access to foreign funds, and
are thus not materially affected by changes in the repatriation tax rate. In other words, the
less credit constrained the firm is, the more muted the responses of real variables are to both
expected and realized changes in repatriation taxes.
In the time leading up to and after the AJCA, lawmakers actively discussed policies
to lower repatriation tax rates. A widely stated aim of these reforms was to encourage
U.S. based firms to repatriate foreign asset holdings. News of a potential reduction in
repatriation tax rates, which may arise from policy discussions, generates a wedge that
distorts the intertemporal cost of repatriating foreign assets. This wedge, or “shadow tax,”
on repatriating foreign earnings discourages firms to transfer income back to the US, thereby
leading to an accumulation of assets abroad. The shadow tax is further magnified with
uncertainty regarding the timing of the policy’s resolution.
Even though lawmakers’ goals of lowering the repatriation tax rate was to encourage the
transfer of assets from abroad, expectations and uncertainty generated by their discussions
can have the opposite effect by decreasing the incentives for firms to repatriate earnings until
the resolution of the policy discussion. Although unexplored in this paper, it may be that
revenue losses during this period are sufficiently large such that lawmakers have the incentive
to implement a tax reduction. In other words, public discussions that indicate the intention
of changing repatriation tax policy could be self-fulfilling.
Appendix: Solution Method
In this section we outline the solution method. We proceed in three steps:
Step 1: Value Function
To solve the firm’s problem, we begin by using value function iteration to numerically con-
struct the value function given by (19). Our value function is defined on a 6-dimensional
discrete grid that represents the state space, (A
US
, A
F
, τ,
R
, z
US
, z
F
). To interpolate values
of the value function along the A
US
×A
F
dimensions we use a combination of shape-preserving
Schumacher quadratic splines and linear splines on a 61×121 point discrete grid.
31
For the
shocks
R
, z
US
, and z
F
we define a 7×9×9 grid and only consider values on the grid. We
set
R
to be a discrete uniform random variable, while the discrete versions of the AR(1)
processes for z
US
and z
F
are calculated using Tauchen (1986)’s method. Finally, the grid
points for τ depend on the structure of the policy being evaluated. For example, for our
31
See Judd (1998).
32
baseline model where the news occurs after N = 4 periods, τ is defined on N = 6 grid
points, corresponding to the 6 states of the economy – the pre- and post-policy steady-state
state, a state each for the 4 news periods, and a state for the period is which the policy is
implemented. In total, for our baseline model our value function is numerically represented
by approximately 25 million grid points.
The value function iteration requires a maximization step. After substitution, the four
dimensional maximization step, {A
0
US
, A
0
F
, T, d}, can be reduced to a maximization step in
just two dimensions, {A
0
US
, T }. We numerically maximize over these two variables using
two-dimensional Golden-section search.
Finally, to construct the value function we must also find Π
US
and Π
F
. Whereas a closed
form solution exists for Π
F
, no closed form solution exists for Π
US
. The closed-form solution
to Π
F
is as follows:
Π
F
=
ξ
1,F
A
α+η
F
+ τ
F
A
F
if A
F
< A
F
ξ
2,F
+ [1 + (1 τ
F
)r] (A
F
A
F
) if A
F
A
F
where
ξ
1,F
= (1 τ
F
) e
z
F
η
w
η
α
r
k
α
1
α + η
α+η
ξ
2,F
= {(1 τ
F
) (1 α η) (1 + r) + [1 + (1 τ
F
)r] (α + η)}
e
z
F
1 + r
η
w
η
α
r
k
α
1
1αη
A
F
= (α + η)
e
z
F
1 + r
η
w
η
α
r
k
α
1
1αη
.
Here A
F
gives the level of assets where if all the firm’s assets were allocated to production
then the returns on them would equal the interest rate offered by financial asset holdings.
Due to diminishing returns, assets in excess of A
F
allocated to production will earn a return
lower than that offered on financial assets, thus when A
F
A
F
the firm allocates (A
F
A
F
)
to financial holdings and A
F
to production.
For Π
US
, as no closed form solution exists, we construct numerical solutions for the grid
points in the A
US
, A
F
, and z
US
dimensions. This solution is constructed as follows:
Π
US
=
˜
Π
US
if A
US
< A
US
ξ
2,US
+ [1 + (1 τ
US
)¯r] (A
US
A
US
) if A
US
A
US
33
where
ξ
2,US
= {(1 τ
US
) (1 α η) (1 + r) + [1 + (1 τ
US
)r] (α + η)}
e
z
US
1 + r
η
w
η
α
r
k
α
1
1αη
A
US
= (α + η)
e
z
US
1 + r
η
w
η
α
r
k
α
1
1αη
. (20)
As before, A
US
gives the level of assets where if all the firm’s assets were allocated
to production the returns on them would equal the interest rate offered on financial asset
holdings. Due to diminishing returns, assets in excess of A
US
allocated to production will
earn a return lower than that offered on financial assets, thus when A
US
A
US
the firm
allocates (A
US
A
US
) to financial holdings and A
US
to production.
Next, to find
˜
Π
US
we simplify and write Π
US
in terms of a maximization problem in L
US
and K
US
only.
˜
Π
US
= max
L
US
,K
US
(1 τ
US
)e
z
US
K
α
US
L
η
US
+ (1 + r
B
)(A
US
wL
US
r
K
K
US
) + τ
US
A
US
where,
32
r
B
= r + ψ
exp
|A
US
wL
US
r
K
K
US
|
A
US
+
˜
A
F
1
.
We can solve this maximization problem by first substituting in K
US
= (
w
η
)(
α
r
K
)L
US
, which
we get from the first-order conditions, and then use golden-section search to numerically find
the optimal L
US
and thus
˜
Π
US
itself.
Step 2: Policy Functions
We use the value function found in the previous step to find the policy functions:
A
0
US
= g
US
(A
US
, A
F
, τ,
R
, z
US
, z
F
)
A
0
F
= g
F
(A
US
, A
F
, τ,
R
, z
US
, z
F
).
Finding the policy functions, similar to the value function iteration, requires a maximization
step. As before, we reduce the four dimensional maximization step {A
0
US
, A
0
F
, T, d} to a
maximization step in just two dimensions, {A
0
US
, T } and use two-dimensional Golden-section
search.
32
We know this because in this case A
U S
< A
U S
, which means the returns to assets allocated to production
are higher than r leading the firm to borrow (i.e. A
B
U S
< 0).
34
Our policy functions is defined on a 6-dimensional discrete grid that represents the state
space, (A
US
, A
F
, τ,
R
, z
US
, z
F
). At 501×501, this grid is finer than the value function in
the A
US
and A
F
dimensions. We do not interpolate between these points and impose the
condition that A
0
US
and A
0
F
must also lie on the grid. Thus, for our baseline model our
policy functions are numerically represented by approximately 850 million grid points that
map onto a roughly 250 thousand grid point values for (A
0
US
, A
0
F
).
Step 3: Simulations
Finally, we use the policy functions constructed in Step 2 to simulate the economy. To
construct the response of the economy to various policies we simulate our environment for
700 periods with the tax news arriving in period 600. We repeat this 700 period simulation
200,000 times keeping the tax news the same but allowing the idiosyncratic shocks
R
, z
US
,
and z
F
to vary. We then average across these 200,000 simulations. We include 600 period
before the tax news to allow the economy to settle into its stochastic steady state.
References
Altshuler, R. and H. Grubert (2003): “Repatriation Taxes, Repatriation Strategies
and Multinational Financial Policy,” Journal of Public Economics, 87, 73–107.
Beaudry, P. and F. Portier (2007): “When Can Changes in Expectations Cause Busi-
ness Cycle Fluctuations in Neo-Classical Settings?” Journal of Economic Theory, 135,
458–477.
Bloom, N. (2009): “The Impact of Uncertainty Shocks,” Econometrica, 77, 623–685.
Blouin, J. and L. Krull (2009): “Bringing it Home: A Study of the Incentives Sur-
rounding the Repatriation of Foreign Earnings Under the American Jobs Creation Act of
2004,” Journal of Accounting Research, 47, 1027–1059.
Brennan, T. J. (2010): “What Happens After a Holiday? Long-term Effects of the Repa-
triation Provision of the AJCA,” Northwestern Journal of Law and Social Policy, 5, 1.
Brumbaugh, D. (2003): “Tax Exemption for Repatriated Foreign Earnings: Proposals and
Analysis,” Congressional Research Service, Library of Congress.
Clausing, K. A. (2005): “Tax Holidays (and other escapes) in the American Jobs Creation
Act,” National Tax Journal, 331–346.
35
Clemons, R. and M. Kinney (2008): “An Analysis of the Tax Holiday for Repatriation
Under the Jobs Act,” Tax Notes, 120.
Corporate Financing Week (2003): “Repatriation Bill Gathers Momentum,” October
27.
De Simone, L., J. D. Piotroski, and R. E. Tomy (2017): “Repatriation Taxes and
Foreign Cash Holdings: The Impact of Anticipated Tax Reform,” The Review of Financial
Studies.
De Waegenaere, A. and R. C. Sansing (2008): “Taxation of International Investment
and Accounting Valuation,” Contemporary Accounting Research, 25, 1045–1066.
Dharmapala, D., C. F. Foley, and K. J. Forbes (2011): “Watch What I do, Not What
I Say: The Unintended Consequences of the Homeland Investment Act,” The Journal of
Finance, 66, 753–787.
Faulkender, M. and M. Petersen (2012): “Investment and Capital Constraints: Repa-
triations Under the American Jobs Creation Act,” Review of Financial Studies, 25, 3351–
3388.
Foley, C. F., J. C. Hartzell, S. Titman, and G. Twite (2007): “Why Do Firms
Hold So Much Cash? A Tax-Based Explanation,” Journal of Financial Economics, 86,
579–607.
Graham, J. R. (1996): “Proxies for the Corporate Marginal Tax Rate,” Journal of Finan-
cial Economics, 42, 187–221.
Gu, T. (2017): “US Multinationals and Cash Holdings,” Journal of Financial Economics,
125, 344–368.
Guvenen, F., R. J. Mataloni Jr, D. G. Rassier, and K. J. Ruhl (2017): “Off-
shore Profit Shifting and Domestic Productivity Measurement,” NBER Working Paper
No. 23324.
Hartman, D. G. (1985): “Tax Policy and Foreign Direct Investment,” Journal of Public
Economics, 26, 107–121.
House, C. L. and M. D. Shapiro (2006): “Phased-in Tax Cuts and Economic Activity,”
The American Economic Review, 96, 1835–1849.
36
Joint Committee on Taxation (2004): “Estimated Budget Effets of the Conference
Agreement for H.R. 4520, The ‘American Jobs Creation Act of 2004’,” JCX-69-04, Joint
Committee on Taxation, Washington D.C.
Judd, K. L. (1998): Numerical Methods in Economics, MIT press.
Kleinbard, E. D. and P. Driessen (2008): “A Revenue Estimate Case Study: The
Repatriation Holiday Revisited,” Tax Notes, 120.
Leeper, E. M., A. W. Richter, and T. B. Walker (2012): “Quantitative Effects of
Fiscal Foresight,” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 4, 115–144.
Levin, C. and T. Coburn (2011): “Repatriating Offshore Funds: 2004 Tax Windfall for
Select Multinationals,” United States Senate Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations,
11.
Matheson, T., V. Perry, and C. Veung (2013): “Territorial vs. Worldwide Corporate
Taxation: Implications for Developing Countries,” IMF Working Paper: Territorial vs.
Worldwide Corporate Taxation-Implications for Developing Countries, 13.
Mertens, K. and M. O. Ravn (2011): “Understanding the Aggregate Effects of Antici-
pated and Unanticipated Tax Policy Shocks,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 14, 27–54.
Oler, M., T. Shevlin, and R. Wilson (2007): “Examining Investor Expectations Con-
cerning Tax Savings on the Repatriations of Foreign Earnings Under the American Jobs
Creation Act of 2004,” Journal of the American Taxation Association, 29, 25–55.
Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations (2011): Repatriating Offshore Funds:
2004 Tax Windfall for Select Multinationals, U.S. Senate Committee on Homeland Security
and Governmental Affairs, October 11.
Redmiles, M. (2008): “The One-Time Dividends Received Deduction,” IRS Statistics of
Income Bulletin, 27, 102–114.
Schmitt-Groh
´
e, S. and M. Uribe (2003): “Closing Small Open Economy Models,”
Journal of international Economics, 61, 163–185.
Simpson, G. R. and R. Wells (2003): “Firms Accused of Using Shelters Lobby
U.S. to Repatriate Funds,” The Wall Street Journal, accessed June 20, 2016:
http://www.wsj.com/articles/SB105329431199082400.
37
Spencer, A. (2017): “Policy effects of international taxation on firm dynamics and capital
structure,” Working Paper.
Stokey, N. L. (2016): “Wait-and-See: Investment Options Under Policy Uncertainty,”
Review of Economic Dynamics, 21, 246–265.
Sullivan, M. (2004): “Data Show Dramatic Shift of Profits to Tax Havens,” Tax Notes,
13, 1190–1200.
Tauchen, G. (1986): “Finite state markov-chain approximations to univariate and vector
autoregressions,” Economics letters, 20, 177–181.
van’t Riet, M. and A. Lejour (2014): “Potential Benefits of Tax Inversion Remain
(Huge): with the model and full country rankings,” CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic
Policy Analysis Backround Document.
Yang, S.-C. S. (2005): “Quantifying Tax Effects Under Policy Foresight,” Journal of
Monetary Economics, 52, 1557–1568.
38
Online Appendix for “Repatriation Taxes”
(Not For Publication)
This not-for-publication appendix contains additional analysis of our framework.
Contents
OA1 Transition Probabilities for Experiments 2
OA1.1 Baseline . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2
OA1.2 Uncertainty: When a Tax Holiday May Occur . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2
OA1.3 Uncertainty: If a Tax Holiday May Occur . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
OA1.4 Uncertainty in If and When a Tax Holiday May Occur . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
OA2 Model Comparison with Foley, Hartzell, Titman, and Twite (2007) 5
OA3 Additional Evidence of News: Permanently Reinvested Earnings and the
AJCA 6
OA4 AJCA Literature and Model Comparison 8
OA5 Sensitivity Analysis 10
OA5.1 Shareholder Preferences . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
OA5.2 Foreign Borrowing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
OA5.3 Permanent Repatriation Tax Cut . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12
OA5.4 Discussion On General Equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
OA6 Tax Cut and Jobs Act of 2017 15
1
OA1 Transition Probabilities for Experiments
This appendix describes the firm’s expectations of future policy from the period of receiving news
through the resolution of the news.
OA1.1 Baseline
In the baseline simulations, the firm unexpectedly receives a tax news shock that notifies them
that there will be a one-period repatriation tax rate reduction 4 quarters in the future. Figure A1
shows the transition graph for the general case when the time from the news to the tax holiday is
T quarters. After the tax holiday, the repatriation tax rate returns to its original steady-state rate
indefinitely.
Steady State
Tax
News
Tax
Holiday
Prob = 1
Period 1 Period 2
Period T–2
Steady
State
Prob = 1 Prob = 1 Prob = 1 Prob = 1
Prob = 1
Period T–1
Figure A1: Transition Graph for Baseline Simulation: Tax Holiday Occurring T Periods From
the Arrival of the News
OA1.2 Uncertainty: When a Tax Holiday May Occur
Figure A2 shows the transition graph for the case when firms receive news of a one-period temporary
repatriation tax reduction that will occur at an unknown time between the arrival of the news and
T periods from the arrival of the news. This corresponds to the simulations in Section 4.5.1 in the
main text. If the tax holiday has not occurred in a given period, the firm places an equal likelihood
that the tax holiday will occur in any given future period. For example, if T = 8, then in the first
period of the news firms will place a P
1
= 1/8 probability that it will occur in the next period,
and if it doesn’t occur in the next period then in period 2 they place a P
2
= 1/7 probability of it
occurring in the following period, and so on. Once the tax holiday occurs, the repatriation tax rate
returns to its original steady-state rate indefinitely.
2
Steady State
Tax
News
Tax
Holiday
Prob =
1 – P
1
Prob =
1 – P
2
Prob =
1 – P
T-2
Prob = 1
T-2
Prob = P
2
Prob = P
1
Prob = P
Period 1 Period 2
Steady
State
Prob = 1
Prob = 1
Period T–2 Period T–1
Figure A2: Transition Graph With Uncertainty of When a Tax Holiday May Occur Between
the Arrival of the News and T Periods Afterwards
OA1.3 Uncertainty: If a Tax Holiday May Occur
Figure A3 shows the transition graph for the case when firms receive news of a one-period temporary
repatriation tax reduction that may or may not occur T periods in the future. This corresponds
to the simulations in Section 4.5.2 in the main text. The firm unexpectedly receives a tax news
shock that notifies them there may be a temporary repatriation tax rate reduction T quarters in
the future. At time T 1, the firm knows that the tax news will be resolved with a probability
of the tax holiday occurring as P (Occur) and probability 1 P (Occur) that it will not occur. If
the tax holiday does occur, the firm will receive a one-period repatriation tax reduction before the
repatriation tax rate returns to the original steady-state rate indefinitely. If it does not occur, the
repatriation tax rate returns to its original steady-state rate indefinitely.
Steady State
Tax
News
Tax
Holiday
Prob = 1
Period 1 Period 2
Steady
State
Prob =
P(Occur)
Prob = 1 Prob = 1 Prob = 1
Prob = 1
Prob = 1 – P(Occur)
Period T–2 Period T–1
Figure A3: Transition Graph With Uncertain Tax Holiday Occurring T Periods From Arrival
of the News
3
OA1.4 Uncertainty in If and When a Tax Holiday May Occur
Section 4.6 in the main text reports the shadow tax on repatriated earnings at the period the
firm receives news of a possible repatriation tax holiday. Figure A4 shows the general case of the
transition graph used in calculating these shadow taxes. The firm receives news of a temporary
repatriation tax reduction that may or may not occur between the arrival of the news and T periods
from the arrival of the news. If the tax holiday has not occurred in a given period, the firm places
an equal likelihood that the tax holiday may occur in any given future period. They additionally
place a probability that the holiday will occur at all (P (Occur) = P
T 1
). For example, if T = 4
and firms place a 50 percent probability a tax holiday will occur, then in the first period of the
news firms place a
1
4
× 0.5 probability it will occur in the next period and in each remaining period.
At time T 1, firms know that the tax news will be resolved with a probability of the tax holiday
occurring as P
T 1
and probability 1 P
T 1
that it will not occur. If the tax holiday does occur,
the firm receives a one-period repatriation tax reduction before the repatriation tax rate returns to
its original steady-state rate indefinitely. If it does not occur, the repatriation tax rate returns to
its original steady-state rate indefinitely.
Steady State
Tax
News
Tax
Holiday
Prob =
1 – P
1
Prob =
1 – P
2
Prob =
1 – P
T-2
Prob = 1 – P
T-1
Prob = 1
T-1
Prob = P
T-2
Prob = P
2
Prob = P
1
Prob = P
Period 1 Period 2
Steady
State
Prob = 1
Period T–1Period T–2
Figure A4: Transition Graph With Uncertainty if and When a Tax Holiday May Occur
Between Arrival of the News and T Periods Afterwards
4
OA2 Model Comparison with Foley, Hartzell, Titman, and Twite
(2007)
This appendix describes how we compare the relationship between foreign liquid asset holdings and
repatriation tax rates from the model with the empirical results from Foley, Hartzell, Titman, and
Twite (2007) (hereon FHTT) in Section 3.2.1 in the main text. FHTT use confidential firm-level
BEA data on foreign subsidiaries of U.S. multinationals in 4 benchmark surveys from 1982-1999 to
estimate the relationship between liquid asset holdings and repatriation tax rates. We focus on the
specification in Table 5, column 3 as this provides the closest mapping with our model. Specifically,
it is the only specification that considers i) only foreign liquid asset holdings, which we have in our
model; ii) repatriation tax rates calculated in the exact way we calibrate it in our model, and iii)
weights on repatriation tax rates (all are weighted in FHTT) by the foreign employment share, the
only weight where we have a 1-to-1 correspondence in our model.
Their dependent variable ln
Cash
Net Assets
is the natural log of foreign liquid assets (“cash”)
divided by net assets, total assets-cash. The primary explanatory variable is the employment-
weighted-effective repatriation tax rate which is calculated in the same way as in our calibration
(see Section 3.1 in the main text) but then weighted by the share of employees in foreign sub-
sidiaries to total employees by the firm. They regress ln
Cash
Net Assets
on employment-weighted-
effective repatriation tax rate and controls. The control variables are Domestic Income/Assets,
Foreign Income/Assets, Log of Assets, Book/Market Value, Debt/Debt+Market Value, St. Dev.
Income/Assets, Dividend Dummy, R&D/Assets, and Capital Expenditures/Assets.
To compare our model results to FHTT, we simulate 200,000 firms at the stochastic steady
state for τ = {0.05, 0.1, ...0.35}. We then calculate ln
Cash
Net Assets
, employment-weighted-effective
repatriation tax rate, and the control variables for each firm observation. We do not have a model
counterpart for the last three control variables in the list above so they are not included. We regress
ln
Cash
Net Assets
on employment-weighted-effective repatriation tax rate and the control variables in
our model generated data as in FHTT. The range of employment-weighted-effective repatriation
tax rate spans from 0.007 to 0.155 in our model generated data. We then find the means of all
the control variables in intervals of 0.02 of employment-weighted-effective repatriation tax rate,
0.01 ± 0.01, 0.03 ± 0.01, ..., 0.15 ± 0.01. Using these conditional means, we generate the predicted
5
values of ln
Cash
Net Assets
at employment-weighted-effective repatriation tax rate= 0.01, 0.03, ..., 0.15,
based on the regression estimates. These predicted values are plotted in Figure 2 in the main text.
The predictions are centered at 0 by subtracting the average predicted value from each predicted
value. The reference line is also centered at 0 and its slope is the coefficient on employment-
weighted-effective repatriation tax rate from FHTT.
OA3 Additional Evidence of News: Permanently Reinvested Earn-
ings and the AJCA
In this appendix we present additional evidence of firms’ responses to anticipation of the AJCA.
Prior to 2018, firms could avoid paying U.S. taxes on foreign income by declaring these assets as
Permanently Reinvested Earnings (PRE); these are earnings that are claimed to be indefinitely
held by foreign affiliates.
1
To illustrate the accumulation of PRE leading up to the AJCA, we hand
collect the disclosed PRE from firms’ 10-K filings with the SEC for those that received tax breaks
on over $500 million under the AJCA. We choose $500 million dollars as the cutoff for repatriated
earnings in order to correlate firms’ PRE leading up to the AJCA. Under the AJCA firms could
receive tax breaks on repatriated earnings of the larger of $500 million or the dollar amount of PRE.
That is, the amount of a firms PRE could be independent to the amount of tax breaks received if
the repatriated money was less that $500 million. We then link our PRE data with foreign earnings
data from the annual Compustat Industrial Database. We require firms in our sample to have a
minimum of 5 PRE observations leading up to the AJCA. Our sample contains 58 firms which, as
a group, represents 57% of the estimated $312 billion repatriated under the act.
PRE is a stock measure of all earnings held permanently abroad that are not subject to U.S.
taxes. To measure a firm’s annual accumulation of PRE to show how it changed in the time
leading up to the AJCA, we define P RE share
i,t
as the dollar change in PRE for a firm i in time
t divided by its net foreign income (pre-tax foreign income minus foreign income taxes). This gives
the implied share of net foreign income designated as PRE that year. We restrict P RE share to
be between 0 and 1. If P RE share > 1, we set it equal to 1 (i.e. all of a firm’s foreign income
1
There were no deferred tax liability on PRE as firms declared these assets would not return to the U.S., although
under the AJCA these assets were permitted to be repatriated with the reduced tax rate.
6
is assigned as PRE). If P RE share < 0 we let P RE share = 0 (i.e. none of a firm’s income
is assigned as PRE). Additionally, if net foreign income is negative and PRE share < 0, we set
P RE share = 0.
We then measure how firms’ accumulation of PRE changed before and after 2003. We pick 2003
as this is the year in which the precursor bills leading up to the AJCA were first introduced. We
do this by comparing a firm’s P RE share by its average P RE share from 1996-2002. This is
given by
^
P RE share
i,t
=
P RE share
i,t
,
P RE share
i,19962002
!
1
where P RE share
i,19962002
is the firm’s average P RE share from 1996-2002.
^
P RE share
i,t
gives the percentage point deviation of a firm’s accumulation of PRE as a share of foreign income
relative to its 1996-2002 average accumulation of PRE as a share of foreign income.
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005
−1
−0.8
−0.6
−0.4
−0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
Mean
Median
Figure A5:
^
P RE share 1996–2005
Notes: The figure shows the percentage point deviation of the share of foreign income retained abroad and un-
taxed by the US (PRE) relative to the average share from the period 1996–2002.
^
P RE share is defined as
(∆P RE share)/(∆P RE share)
19962002
1 where P RE share is the implied share of after tax foreign income
designated as PRE and P RE share is the average ∆P RE share from 1996-2002.
Figure A5 plots the across-firm mean and median percentage point deviation of P RE share
from its 1996-2002 average P RE share,
^
P RE share. This gives a measure of how firms’
accumulation of PRE changed before versus after 2003, the year the precursor bills leading up to
the AJCA were first introduced. Prior to 2003,
^
P RE share was relatively stable. From 2002-2003
7
and 2003-2004, this measure of changes in foreign asset holdings by U.S. firms increases sharply
relative to its long-run average. In 2004-2005,
^
P RE share substantially declined as firms ran
down their holdings of PRE by repatriating a large share of these assets during the tax holiday. We
note that the sharp increase in the accumulation of PRE in 2002-2003 occurred before the AJCA
was officially introduced and enacted. This is once again suggestive that firms anticipated the tax
holiday and acted on this anticipation by changing the amount of assets held overseas leading up
to the AJCA.
OA4 AJCA Literature and Model Comparison
In the early 2000’s policymakers were concerned that U.S. tax laws were disincentivizing U.S.
based multinationals from repatriating foreign income back to the U.S. They felt that if they
could convince firms to repatriate more foreign income it would lead to greater investment and
job creation in the U.S., thereby spurring further economic growth. Thus, in October 2004 they
passed the AJCA which reduced the maximum repatriation tax rate on qualified funds from 35
to 5.25 percent on 85 percent of repatriated earnings in a one-year window. Further, under the
AJCA guidelines, firms were required to use any funds that received tax breaks from the act on
U.S. employment, investment, research and development, and other uses related to job creation
and retention.
There is a large empirical literature that aims to tease out the effects of the AJCA tax holiday on
a number of firm-level and fiscal policy variables. Table A1 summarizes the comparison between our
model findings and this empirical literature. The table shows our model is remarkably consistent
with the results documented in the empirical literature.
8
Table A1: AJCA Literature and Model Predictions
Study Period Study Findings Our Model Predictions
Transfers: Joint Committee on Taxation
(2004)
At/After Predicted transfers rise during the AJCA and fall after-
ward
Transfers rise during the tax holiday and
fall afterward.
U.S. Tax Revenue: Joint Committee
on Taxation (2004)
At/After An estimate of the budget impacts of the AJCA predicted
rise in tax revenue at the AJCA and fall thereafter for a
net loss in tax revenue.
Tax revenue rises during the tax holiday
and falls afterward for a net loss of U.S.
tax revenue.
Employment and Investment (Finan-
cially Unconstrained): Faulkender and
Petersen (2012), Dharmapala, Foley,
and Forbes (2011)
At/After No significant change. Negligible total response.
Employment and Investment (Finan-
cially Constrained): Faulkender and Pe-
tersen (2012)
At/After Increase in investment and no change to employment. Increase in both variables (see Section 4.4
in main text).
Shareholder Payouts: Blouin and Krull
(2009), Dharmapala, Foley, and Forbes
(2011), Clemons and Kinney (2008)
At/After Increase in shareholder payouts (dividends and share re-
purchases). Dharmapala, Foley, and Forbes (2011) es-
timate a $1 increase in repatriation during the AJCA
correspond to a $0.60 to $0.92 increase in shareholder
payouts.
Increase in dividend payments approxi-
mately equaling the tax saving from hol-
iday.
Debt Reduction: Faulkender and Pe-
tersen (2012), Dharmapala, Foley,
and Forbes (2011), Graham, Hanlon,
Shevlin et al. (2010)
At/After Graham, Hanlon, Shevlin et al. (2010) finds firms with
foreign sourced earnings reported paying down domes-
tic debt as one of the most common uses of repatriated
earnings using survey data from tax executives from these
firms. The other papers find no impact of the AJCA on
debt reduction.
Firms repay debt but the debt reduction is
short lasting.
Firm Value: Oler, Shevlin, and Wilson
(2007)
Pre Stock value increased proportionately to the expected tax
savings from the holiday. Increases occurred beginning
in 2003 when the passage of the AJCA seemed likely, but
the AJCA was not enacted until October 2004.
Increase in firm value V at the time of the
news of the tax holiday.
Notes: This table summarizes the impacts from the AJCA of 2004 from the literature and compares it with our model findings. The second column reports the sub-periods of the
analysis in the empirical literature in which the empirical studies focus on: Pre (news period) and At/After the enactment of the AJCA.
9
OA5 Sensitivity Analysis
OA5.1 Shareholder Preferences
In this section, we perform sensitivity analysis on the coefficient of relative risk aversion σ in our
utility function. In our baseline simulation, we use log utility (σ = 1). Here we also show the case
when shareholders have risk neutral preferences (σ = 0).
-4 0 4
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
Repatriation tax rate
-4 0 4
0
200
400
600
800
Repatriations
-4 0 4
-100
0
100
200
Foreign financial assets
-4 0 4
-100
-50
0
50
U.S. debt
-4 0 4
-100
0
100
200
300
Dividends
-4 0 4
-1
-0.5
0
0.5
1
U.S. labor and capital
-4 0 4
-1
-0.5
0
0.5
1
U.S. output
-4 0 4
-2
0
2
4
Firm value (V)
-4 0 4
0
50
100
All sources
-4 0 4
0
200
400
Repatriations
-4 0 4
-1
-0.5
0
0.5
1
Corporate income
-4 0 4
0
100
200
300
Dividends
Baseline
=1 (linear utility)
Panel A: Firm-level responses
Panel B: US tax revenue by source
Figure A6: Responses to Temporary Reduction in Repatriation Taxes Where News of Reduction is
Received 4 Quarters in Advance
Notes: Except for the repatriation tax rate, units are in percent deviation from initial steady state. The figure plots the baseline
(σ = 1) and with risk neutral preferences (σ = 0).
Figure A6 shows the responses to news and the implementation of a tax holiday. The top
panel gives the firm-level responses and the bottom gives the responses for the U.S. government
tax revenue. The units are percentage deviations from the original stochastic steady state with the
10
exception of the repatriation tax rate graph which shows the actual time-path for the repatriation
tax rate. The tax holiday is implemented at period 0 and the firm receives news of it 4 quarters in
advance (period -4). The repatriation tax rate reduction is the same as in the baseline.
When we consider the case with linear utility, the results differ quite substantially. Without
curvature in the utility of dividends, the firm does not have a motive to smooth out dividend
payments. Thus, there are wide swings in many variables at the announcement of the news. For
example, the firm cut off repatriations almost completely during the news period. The large swings
in foreign transfers, dividend payments, and U.S. tax revenue are at odds with the variation of
these variables for multinational firms in the data. In particular, with linear utility firms do not
have an incentive to smooth dividends over time. We thus, incorporate curvature in out utility
function.
OA5.2 Foreign Borrowing
Here we relax the restriction that foreign operations cannot access external credit markets and allow
them to borrow as they can domestically. The firm therefore faces a worldwide interest rate on
borrowing – i.e. the interest rate on debt is the same across both jurisdictions. Figure A7 shows the
model results from the baseline exercise (no foreign borrowing) and with foreign borrowing. The
top panel gives the firm-level responses and the bottom gives the responses for the U.S. government
tax revenue. The units are percentage deviations from the original stochastic steady state, with the
exception of the repatriation tax rate graph, which shows the actual time-path for the repatriation
tax rate. The tax holiday is implemented at period 0 and the firm receives news of it 4 quarters in
advance (period -4). The repatriation tax rate reduction is the same as in the baseline.
When there is foreign borrowing, increases in foreign financial asset holdings rise much more
sharply than in the baseline during the news period. However, we note that although the percentage
change is larger, the steady state level of foreign asset holdings is smaller than in the baseline. In
fact, a large part of the transferred assets during the tax holiday when there is foreign borrowing
comes from assets used to finance production abroad. Immediately after the transfer, foreign
operations overcome this shortcoming with a rapid increase in foreign debt.
11
-4 0 4
0.05
0.1
0.15
0.2
Repatriation tax rate
-4 0 4
0
200
400
Repatriations
-4 0 4
0
200
400
600
Foreign financial assets
-4 0 4
-4
-2
0
2
4
Dividends
-4 0 4
-100
-50
0
50
100
U.S. debt
-4 0 4
-100
-50
0
50
100
Foreign Debt
-4 0 4
-2
-1
0
1
U.S. labor and capital
-4 0 4
-1
-0.5
0
0.5
1
U.S. output
-4 0 4
-20
-10
0
10
20
30
All sources
-4 0 4
-100
0
100
200
300
Repatriations
-4 0 4
-1
-0.5
0
0.5
1
Corporate income
-4 0 4
-4
-2
0
2
4
Dividends
Baseline with foreign borrowing
Panel A: Firm-level responses
Panel B: US tax revenue by source
Figure A7: Responses to Temporary Reduction in Repatriation Taxes Where News of Reduction is
Received 4 Quarters in Advance when Firms can Borrow both in the U.S. and Abroad.
OA5.3 Permanent Repatriation Tax Cut
Here we consider the case when the repatriation tax changes is implemented as a permanent reduc-
tion. Figure A8 shows the transition graph for the case of a permanent reduction in repatriation
tax rates. The firm unexpectedly receives a tax news shock that notifies them there will be a
permanent tax policy change T quarters in the future. Once the tax reform is implemented, the
tax rate remains at this new level indefinitely.
12
Steady State
Tax
News
Tax
Reform
Prob = 1
Prob = 1
Period 1 Period 2
Steady
State
Prob = 1 Prob = 1 Prob = 1 Prob = 1
Period T–2
Period T–1
Figure A8: Transition Graph Where a Permanent Change in Tax Policy Occurs T Periods
From Arrival of the News
Figure A9 shows the responses to a permanent repatriation tax reduction announced 4 periods
in advance plotted alongside the baseline results for comparison. The size of the repatriation tax
reduction is the same as in the baseline.
-4 0 4
0.05
0.1
0.15
Repatriation tax rate
-4 0 4
0
200
400
600
Repatriations
-4 0 4
-100
0
100
200
Foreign financial assets
-4 0 4
-50
0
50
100
U.S. debt
-4 0 4
-4
-2
0
2
4
Dividends
-4 0 4
-1
0
1
U.S. labor and capital
-4 0 4
-1
0
1
U.S. output
-4 0 4
-2
0
2
4
Firm value (V)
-4 0 4
-10
0
10
20
All sources
-4 0 4
-100
0
100
200
Repatriations
-4 0 4
-1
0
1
Corporate income
-4 0 4
-4
-2
0
2
4
Dividends
Temporary tax cut (Baseline) Permanent tax cut
Panel A: Firm-level responses
Panel B: US tax revenue by source
Figure A9: Responses to a permanent reduction in the repatriation tax rate were news of reduction is
received 4 Quarters in Advance. Units are in percent deviation from initial steady state.
In the news period, firms reduce transfers at approximately the same rate as the baseline. At
the policy change, the firm repatriates the assets accumulated during the news period, but the total
amount repatriated in this period is less than the baseline. When the tax change is temporary,
13
firms have incentive to shift foreign income that would otherwise be transferred in future periods
to exploit the one-time tax saving on these assets. When the change is permanent, firms have
no such motive since these repatriated assets will indefinitely face a lower tax rate. This is why
repatriations at the time of the policy change is less responsive for a permanent than a temporary
tax reduction.
After the permanent repatriation tax reduction, U.S. output and capital and labor use is per-
manently higher in the steady state, albeit is very small (approximately 1/20 of 1 percent). Addi-
tionally, the permanent tax rate reduction leads to a perpetual loss to U.S. tax revenues: a lower
tax rate yields lower tax revenues. In sum, gains to U.S. output and factor input use is small and
U.S. tax revenue losses are large from this permanent repatriation tax reduction. In comparison,
Arena and Kutner (2015) study the empirical impacts of permanent repatriation tax reductions
from the 2009 reforms in Japan and the United Kingdom. They do not find evidence of increases
in domestic investment. Again, in our model domestic capital use increases by 1/20 of 1 percent.
OA5.4 Discussion On General Equilibrium
For the case of a permanent reduction in repatriation tax rates, we believe our framework is
informative to understand the dynamics around a local period from the time of the news period
to after the policy change. In the long run, however, there may general equilibrium effects from a
permanent repatriation tax change that we do not capture as firms and households adjust to a new
tax environment.
2
Our model, for one, does not capture the additional production and the subsequent effects
that could emerge from efficiency gains following a reduction in distortionary taxes. From a tax
revenue perspective, this would imply that when the repatriation tax rates are lower, the taxable
base may be larger. If the efficiency gains are large enough, it could be that tax revenue does not
decrease much during the announcement and after the holiday. At the firm level, the substitution
effect from the reduction in taxes on repatriations – or its announcements – may remain unchanged:
taxes in the present became relatively higher. The income effect, however, would be heighten as
the value of the firm increases. The latter would dampen the reduction in dividend payments in
the news period. Depending on the level of dividends, it could be that the marginal increases are
2
See, for example, Spencer (2017) for a general equilibrium model of permanent repatriation tax rate changes.
14
devoted to production during the time of the announcement which could imply that, even if firms
are financially constrained, labor and capital does not contract.
Second–as mentioned in the main text in more detail as firms adjust their demand for inputs
in response to the policy change, input prices would respond accordingly. Most likely, these price
adjustments in factor inputs would also serve to dampen the responses to labor/capital and output
in comparison to the relatively small responses in our baseline model. As the asset flows into the
U.S. in response to the tax reduction, this would make consumers wealthier from an influx of
dividends and/or higher factor payments and result in an increase in demand for goods and
services from the firms.
In both cases efficiency gains and price changes the income effect would be larger and there
would be no substitution effect of tax rates (i.e. in the case of an announcement, future repatriation
tax rates became cheaper). These would arguably dampen the responses we find at the firm level.
The response of labor would hence depend on the extent to which wealth effects are assumed in
the household’s preferences. What is clear, however, is that the aggregate and welfare effects of
repatriation taxes would necessitate a general equilibrium to be properly quantitatively evaluated
in the case of permanent changes in repatriation taxes. Our framework, nevertheless, highlights
important mechanisms at the firm level that are consistent with the empirical literature and that
such a framework should capture.
OA6 Tax Cut and Jobs Act of 2017
Here, we use our framework to analyze the periods leading up to, and implementation of, the
most recent tax reforms: the Tax Cut and Jobs Act of 2017 (henceforth the TCJA17 to clearly
distinguish the acronym from the AJCA). The TCJA17 includes comprehensive tax reforms that
include, but are not exclusive to, changes in the taxation of foreign activity of U.S. multinationals.
Our analysis strictly focuses on the aspects that impact the taxation of multinationals.
Calls for changes in the taxation of U.S. based multinationals were continuously proposed by
both Democrats and Republicans in the years leading up to the TCJA17. This included President
Obama’s White House Budgets for 2015, 2016, and 2017, and The Blueprint – a leading Republican
tax reform plan introduced in the House of Representatives in 2016. Expectations of a heightened
15
possibility of tax reform took hold after the elections of 2016 which aligned Republican majorities
in both houses of congress and in the presidency. President Trump’s administration unveiled their
outline for tax reform in April 2017 where Treasury Secretary Mnuchin stated that they would
move as fast as they can on passage and implementation. The TCJA17 was brought to congress
later that year was signed into law on December 2017 and went into effect at the beginning of 2018.
The act reduced U.S. corporate income tax from a top marginal tax rate of 35% to a flat tax of
21%. Second, the TCJA17 moved the U.S. to a territorial tax system – a 100 percent tax exemption
on all income generated abroad by U.S. multinationals, i.e. an elimination of repatriation taxes.
Finally, it implemented a one-time “deemed repatriation tax” bridging the former international tax
regime to a new one. This is a one-time retroactive tax on the sum of foreign income held abroad
that was untaxed by the U.S. government at the time of the implementation date. Following this
one-time tax, these assets were able to be repatriated with no additional U.S. tax costs.
Within our model, we can implement the changes of the TCJA17. Letting the date of imple-
mentation be time t = J, U.S. corporate income taxes in the model are given by
τ
US
= 0.302 if t < J (OA6.1)
τ
US
= 0.21 if t J. (OA6.2)
The model repatriation tax rate is similarly given as
τ = 0.131 if t < J (OA6.3)
τ = 0.0 if t J. (OA6.4)
Under the TCJA17, the deemed repatriation tax applies to all foreign assets yet to be taxed by
the U.S. government and accumulated since the enactment of the Tax Reform Act of 1986. In the
model, the transition tax is applied to all foreign assets, A
F
, at the period of the tax reform minus
the initial transfer from the U.S. parent to set up the foreign operation. Assuming the foreign
operation was established at time t = 0 and the tax reform is initiated at time t = J, then the
16
assets facing the transition tax is
A
F,J
T
0
=
J
X
t=0
π
F,t
(1 τ
F
)
J
X
t=1
T
t
where T
0
is the initial transfer from the firm’s U.S. operations and π
F
are the sum of pre-tax
foreign income from operations and interest on bank assets. In the model, we assume the seed
money from the U.S., T
0
, is small relative to the total assets at time T . Thus, tax revenues from
the transition tax τ
T T
is τ
T T
A
F,T
. The TCJA levies the deemed repatriation tax rate of 15.5%
on cash and cash equivalents (liquid assets) and 8% on remaining assets. Given the fungibility of
internal funds, in our model the differential taxation on liquid vs. non-liquid assets is problematic
as firms can immediately change the composition of asset holdings particularly if the tax change
is anticipated. For this reason, we impose the transition tax to be τ
T T
= 0.104 which is calculated
by weighting the two tax rates by the relative shares of liquid and non-liquid assets to total foreign
assets in the model steady state.
In this exercise, the firm knows with certainty that the TCJA17 will occur 4 periods in advance
of its implementation. This corresponds with a news period over the 2017 calendar year with
implementation in 2018Q1. The solid lines in Figure A10 present the responses to news of and
implementation of the provisions in the TCJA17. We additionally include a simulation with all of
the tax changes in the TCJA17 except the deemed repatriation tax (dashed line) to highlight the
role deemed repatriation taxes play on the dynamics. We note that although from the Figure it is
clear the dynamics differ, both simulations eventually converge to the same steady state.
During the news period, firms that face the deemed repatriation tax withhold fewer repatriations
and accumulate less foreign financial assets as this tax reduces the incentives for firms to accumulate
assets abroad. From a policy perspective, if lawmakers wanted to draft a tax policy change that
mitigates the incentives for firms to accumulate foreign assets in expectation of tax reform, including
a deemed repatriation tax is a better option in this dimension than just purely permanently changing
the tax rates. The size of the deemed repatriation tax, however, still results in tax gains for the
firm.
In the short run, the TCJA17 leads to short run losses in labor/capital and output before and in
the periods after the policy change. The deemed repatriation tax drives this result because this tax
17
removes a portion of the firm’s stock of assets and, since the cost of debt is a function of its assets,
higher borrowing cost reduce the firm’s ability to finance production with debt. However, if the
timeline were extended we would see that in the final steady state labor/capital are just 1/2 percent
larger than before the policy change. At the time of the policy change, U.S. tax revenues spike
from the one-time deemed repatriation tax. All of the tax revenue losses after the enactment period
come solely from reductions in repatriation tax receipts. In the short run, the deemed repatriation
tax results in sizable tax revenues for the U.S. government.
-4 0 4
0
0.05
0.1
0.15
Repatriation tax rate
-4 0 4
-100
0
100
200
300
Repatriations
-4 0 4
-100
0
100
200
Foreign financial assets
-4 0 4
-50
0
50
U.S. debt
-4 0 4
-5
0
5
10
15
Dividends
-4 0 4
-1
0
1
U.S. labor and capital
-4 0 4
-1
0
1
U.S. output
-4 0 4
0
5
10
Firm value (V)
-4 0 4
-20
0
20
40
60
All sources
-4 0 4
-100
-50
0
50
Repatriations
-4 0 4
-0.5
0
0.5
1
Corporate income
-4 0 4
-5
0
5
10
15
Dividends
TCJA17 TCJA17 without deemed repat. tax
Panel A: Firm-level responses
Panel B: US tax revenue by source
Figure A10: Response to News and Implementation of the Tax Cut and Jobs Act of 2017
Notes: Firms receive news of the TCJA17 4 quarters in advance. The policy change includes a deemed repatriation
tax of 10.4 percent at the time of the policy change only, and permanent reductions of U.S. corporate income tax
rate to 21% and a removal of repatriation taxes (τ
R
= 0). The solid line has all of the policy changes and the
dashed line has all of the policy changes except the deemed repatriation tax.
18
OA References
Arena, M. P. and G. W. Kutner (2015): “Territorial Tax System Reform and Corporate
Financial Policies,” Review of Financial Studies, hhv005.
Blouin, J. and L. Krull (2009): “Bringing it Home: A Study of the Incentives Surrounding the
Repatriation of Foreign Earnings Under the American Jobs Creation Act of 2004,” Journal of
Accounting Research, 47, 1027–1059.
Clemons, R. and M. Kinney (2008): “An Analysis of the Tax Holiday for Repatriation Under
the Jobs Act,” Tax Notes, 120.
Dharmapala, D., C. F. Foley, and K. J. Forbes (2011): “Watch What I do, Not What I
Say: The Unintended Consequences of the Homeland Investment Act,” The Journal of Finance,
66, 753–787.
Faulkender, M. and M. Petersen (2012): “Investment and Capital Constraints: Repatriations
Under the American Jobs Creation Act,” Review of Financial Studies, 25, 3351–3388.
Foley, C. F., J. C. Hartzell, S. Titman, and G. Twite (2007): “Why Do Firms Hold So
Much Cash? A Tax-Based Explanation,” Journal of Financial Economics, 86, 579–607.
Graham, J. R., M. Hanlon, T. Shevlin, et al. (2010): “Barriers To Mobility: The Lockout
Effect Of US Taxation Of Worldwide Corporate Profits,” National Tax Journal, 63, 1111–1144.
Joint Committee on Taxation (2004): “Estimated Budget Effets of the Conference Agreement
for H.R. 4520, The ‘American Jobs Creation Act of 2004’,” JCX-69-04, Joint Committee on
Taxation, Washington D.C.
Oler, M., T. Shevlin, and R. Wilson (2007): “Examining Investor Expectations Concerning
Tax Savings on the Repatriations of Foreign Earnings Under the American Jobs Creation Act of
2004,” Journal of the American Taxation Association, 29, 25–55.
Spencer, A. (2017): “Policy effects of international taxation on firm dynamics and capital struc-
ture,” Working Paper.
19